John R. Commons

Last updated
John R. Commons
John R Commons 001.jpg
From The Independent , Volume 63 (1907)
Born(1862-10-13)October 13, 1862
DiedMay 11, 1945(1945-05-11) (aged 82)
Academic career
Field Institutional economics, labor history
School or
tradition
Institutional economics
Doctoral
advisor
Richard T. Ely
Doctoral
students
Alvin Hansen, Edwin E. Witte
Influences Henry Dunning Macleod

John Rogers Commons (October 13, 1862 – May 11, 1945) was an American institutional economist, Georgist, progressive and labor historian at the University of Wisconsin–Madison. [1]

Contents

Early years

John R. Commons was born in Hollansburg, Ohio on October 13, 1862. Commons had a religious upbringing which led him to be an advocate for social justice early in life. Commons was considered a poor student and suffered from a mental illness while studying. He was allowed to graduate without finishing because of the potential seen in his intense determination and curiosity. At this time, Commons became a follower of Henry George's 'single tax' economics. [2] He carried this 'Georgist' or 'Ricardian' approach to economics, with a focus on land and monopoly rents, throughout the rest of his life, including a proposal for income taxes with higher rates on land rents. [3] [4] [5] [6] [7]

After graduating from Oberlin College, Commons did two years of graduate studies at Johns Hopkins University, where he studied under Richard T. Ely, [8] but left without a degree. [9] [10] After appointments at Oberlin and Indiana University, Commons began teaching at Syracuse University in 1895. [11]

In spring 1899, Syracuse dismissed him as a radical. [12] Eventually Commons re-entered academia at the University of Wisconsin in 1904. [8]

Commons' early work exemplified his desire to unite Christian ideals with the emerging social sciences of sociology and economics. He was a frequent contributor to Kingdom magazine, was a founder of the American Institute for Christian Sociology, and authored a book in 1894 called Social Reform and the Church. [13] He was an advocate of temperance legislation and was active in the national Prohibition Party. [13] By his Wisconsin years, Commons' scholarship had become less moralistic and more empirical, and he moved away from a religious viewpoint in his ethics and sociology. [14]

Career

John R. Commons at his desk at the University of Wisconsin in the 1920s. JohnCommons.jpg
John R. Commons at his desk at the University of Wisconsin in the 1920s.

Commons is best known for developing an analysis of collective action by the state and other institutions, which he saw as essential to understanding economics. Commons believed that carefully crafted legislation could create social change; that view led him to be known as a socialist radical and incrementalist. Contrary to some published accounts, Commons did consider African Americans capable of voting. When he advocated proportional representation, he suggested a "negro party". [15] He even suggested applying the Thirteenth amendment to the Constitution to force Southern States to allow African Americans to vote. [16] He continued the strong American tradition in institutional economics by such figures as the economist and social theorist Thorstein Veblen. His notion of transaction is one of the most important contributions to Institutional Economics. [17] The institutional theory was closely related to his remarkable successes in fact-finding and drafting legislation on a wide range of social issues for the state of Wisconsin. He drafted legislation establishing Wisconsin's worker's compensation program, the first of its kind in the United States.

In 1906, Commons co-founded the American Association for Labor Legislation (AALL) with other economists. [18]

Commons was a contributor to The Pittsburgh Survey, a 1907 sociological investigation of a single American city. His graduate student, John A. Fitch, wrote The Steel Workers, a classic depiction of a key industry in early 20th-century America. It was one of six key texts to come out of the survey. Edwin E. Witte, later known as the "father of social security" also did his PhD at the University of Wisconsin–Madison under Commons.

He was a leading advocate of proportional representation in the United States, writing a book on the subject in 1907 and serving as vice-president of the Proportional Representation League. [19]

Commons undertook two major studies of the history of labor unions in the United States. Beginning in 1910, he edited A Documentary History of American Industrial Society, a large work that preserved many original-source documents of the American labor movement. Almost as soon as that work was complete, Commons began editing History of Labor in the United States, a narrative work which built on the previous 10-volume documentary history.

The first national honor society in economics, Omicron Delta Gamma (ODG), was formed on May 7, 1915, by the merger of Harvard University's Undergraduate Society of Economics with the University of Wisconsin's Order of Artus, an economics student society modeled on King Arthur's Knights of the Roundtable; Wisconsin's group was advised by Commons.

In 1934, Commons published Institutional Economics, which laid out his view that institutions were made up of collective actions that, along with conflict of interests, defined the economy. He believed that institutional economics added collective control of individual transactions to existing economic theory. [20] Commons considered the Scottish economist Henry Dunning Macleod to be the "originator" of Institutional economics. [21]

Commons was elected to the American Philosophical Society in 1936. [22]

Death and legacy

The John R. and Nell Commons House Landmark Designation Sign Hocheera.jpg
The John R. and Nell Commons House Landmark Designation Sign

He died on May 11, 1945.

Today, Commons's contribution to labor history is considered equal to his contributions to the theory of institutional economics. He also made valuable contributions to the history of economic thought, especially with regard to collective action. He is honored at the University of Wisconsin in Madison with rooms and clubs named for him. [23]

Commons was the mentor of many outstanding economists and has been credited with originating the "Wisconsin Idea," in which university faculty serve as advisors to state government. [24]

His former home, The John R. and Nell Commons House, is listed on the National Register of Historic Places. [25] [26]

The John R. Commons Award is awarded biennially to an outstanding economist in recognition of academic achievements and for service both to the economics profession and to Omicron Delta Epsilon. [27] [28] The award is given at American Economic Association conference where the honoree presents a "Commons Lecture" which is later published in The American Economist. Over the years, the Commons Award has served as an indicator of recipients of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. Nine Commons Award winners have won the Nobel Prize; most recently, Claudia Goldin (2009) won the Nobel in 2023. [29] [30] [31]

Quotes

Publications

Solely authored works

Co-authored works

Edited works

See also

Notes

  1. Rutherford, Malcolm (2006). "Wisconsin Institutionalism: John R. Commons and His Students". Labor History . 47 (2): 161–188. doi:10.1080/00236560600583123. S2CID   145626020.
  2. Brue S. and Grant R. (2012). The Evolution of Economic Thought (PDF) (Supplemental Biography of John Rogers Commons for chapter 19 of the online edition of The Evolution of Economic Thought ed.). Cengage Learning. Retrieved 1 September 2014.
  3. Commons, John Rogers (1893). The Distribution of Wealth. Macmillan and Company.
  4. Commons, John Rogers. Institutional Economics. Vol. II: Its Place in Political Economy. Transaction Publishers. ISBN   978-1-4128-2633-4.
  5. Henry George's Resurrection of the Science of Political Economy (Part Three) Edward J. Dodson http://cooperative-individualism.org/dodson-edward_henry-george-resurrection-of-political-economy-1996-03.htm Archived 2017-02-16 at the Wayback Machine
  6. Harter (Jr.), Lafayette G.; Harter, Lafayette G. (1962). John R. Commons, His Assault on Laissez-faire. Oregon State University Press.
  7. "Two Centuries of Economic Thought on Taxation of Land Rents." In Richard Lindholm and Arthur Lynn, Jr., (eds.), Land Value Taxation in Thought and Practice. Madison: Univ. of Wisconsin Press, 1982, pp. 151-96. http://www.masongaffney.org/publications/K142_Centuries_Thought_Land_Taxation.CV.pdf
  8. 1 2 J. David Hoeveler, Jr., "John R. Commons," Historical Dictionary of the Progressive Era, 1890–1920. Revised Edition. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1988; pp. 85–86.
  9. Harter, Lafayette G. (1962). John R. Commons: His Assault on Laissez-Faire . Corvallis: Oregon State University Press. pp.  19–20.
  10. Lampman, Robert J., ed. (1993). Economists at Wisconsin, 1892–1992. p. 22.
  11. "John R. Commons at the Wisconsin Historical Society". Archived from the original on 2006-05-24.
  12. Richard A. Gonce (2002), "John R. Commons's "Five Big Years": 1899–1904", The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 61, No. 4 (Oct., 2002), pp. i+755–777, p. 756
  13. 1 2 Hoeveler, "John R. Commons," pg. 85.
  14. Gonce, Richard A. “John R. Commons's 'Five Big Years': 1899-1904.” The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, vol. 61, no. 4, 2002, pp. 760-i. JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/3487977.
  15. Commons,John, R. 1900. Representative Democracy. New York: American Bureau of Economic Research, 1900, 20.
  16. Chasse, John Dennis. A Workers' Economist: John R. Commons and His Legacy from Progressivism to the War on Poverty. New York: Transactions Press, pp.120-122.
  17. Nicita A. and M. Vatiero (2007), "The Contract and the Market: Towards a Broader Notion of Transaction?". Studi e Note di Economia, 1:7–22. Link Archived 2011-09-27 at the Wayback Machine
  18. Moss, David A. (1994). "Kindling a flame under federalism: Progressive reformers, corporate elites, and the phosphorus match campaign of 1909-1912". Business History Review. 68 (2): 244–275. doi:10.2307/3117443. JSTOR   3117443. S2CID   155436193 . Retrieved 2 May 2022.
  19. "Proportional Representation Review". 1921.
  20. Vatiero, Massimiliano. "From W. N. Hohfeld to J. R. Commons, and Beyond? A "Law and Economics" Enquiry on Jural Relations", American Journal of Economics and Sociology , 69(2): 840–866, 2010.
  21. Commons, John Rogers (1990). Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy. New Brunswick, N.J., U.S.A: Transaction Publishers. p. 399. ISBN   978-0-88738-797-5.
  22. "APS Member History". search.amphilsoc.org. Retrieved 2023-05-31.
  23. The John R. Commons Room on the 8th floor of the Sociology building, and the John R. Commons Club in the Economics department
  24. The John R. and Nell Commons House Landmark Designation Sign Hocheera.jpg
    The John R. and Nell Commons House Landmark Designation Sign
  25. "View Summary/Photo Page". Archived from the original on 2011-06-11.
  26. "John R. Commons House".
  27. Grimes, Paul W. (2014-09-22). "The John R. Commons Award". American Economist. 59 (2): 118. ISSN   0569-4345.
  28. Mankiw, N. Gregory (January 2020). "The Past and Future of Econ 101: The John R. Commons Award Lecture". Working Paper Series. doi:10.3386/w26702. S2CID   213085383.{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  29. "The John R. Commons Award". The American Economist. 66 (1): 8–8. March 17, 2021. doi:10.1177/0569434520980962 via CrossRef.
  30. "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2023". NobelPrize.org.
  31. N/A (2018). "The John R. Commons Award". The American Economist. 63 (2): 131. doi:10.1177/0569434518783387. S2CID   166179554.

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Joseph Schumpeter</span> Austrian political economist (1883–1950)

Joseph Alois Schumpeter was an Austrian political economist. He served briefly as Finance Minister of Austria in 1919. In 1932, he emigrated to the United States to become a professor at Harvard University, where he remained until the end of his career, and in 1939 obtained American citizenship.

An economist is a professional and practitioner in the social science discipline of economics.

In economics and related disciplines, a transaction cost is a cost in making any economic trade when participating in a market. The idea that transactions form the basis of economic thinking was introduced by the institutional economist John R. Commons in 1931, and Oliver E. Williamson's Transaction Cost Economics article, published in 2008, popularized the concept of transaction costs. Douglass C. North argues that institutions, understood as the set of rules in a society, are key in the determination of transaction costs. In this sense, institutions that facilitate low transaction costs, boost economic growth.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Thorstein Veblen</span> American economist and sociologist (1857–1929)

Thorstein Bunde Veblen was an American economist and sociologist who, during his lifetime, emerged as a well-known critic of capitalism.

The historical school of economics was an approach to academic economics and to public administration that emerged in the 19th century in Germany, and held sway there until well into the 20th century. The professors involved compiled massive economic histories of Germany and Europe. Numerous Americans were their students. The school was opposed by theoretical economists. Prominent leaders included Gustav von Schmoller (1838–1917), and Max Weber (1864–1920) in Germany, and Joseph Schumpeter (1883–1950) in Austria and the United States.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Douglass North</span> American economist and Nobel laureate (1920–2015)

Douglass Cecil North was an American economist known for his work in economic history. Along with Robert Fogel, he received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1993. In the words of the Nobel Committee, North and Fogel "renewed research in economic history by applying economic theory and quantitative methods in order to explain economic and institutional change."

The Chicago school of economics is a neoclassical school of economic thought associated with the work of the faculty at the University of Chicago, some of whom have constructed and popularized its principles. Milton Friedman, and George Stigler are considered the leading scholars of the Chicago school.

Max Otto Lorenz was an American economist who developed the Lorenz curve in an undergraduate essay. He published a paper on this when he was a doctoral student at the University of Wisconsin–Madison. His doctoral thesis (1906) was on 'The Economic Theory of Railroad Rates' and made no reference to perhaps his most famous paper. The term "Lorenz curve" for the measure Lorenz invented was coined by Willford I. King in 1912.

Institutional economics focuses on understanding the role of the evolutionary process and the role of institutions in shaping economic behavior. Its original focus lay in Thorstein Veblen's instinct-oriented dichotomy between technology on the one side and the "ceremonial" sphere of society on the other. Its name and core elements trace back to a 1919 American Economic Review article by Walton H. Hamilton. Institutional economics emphasizes a broader study of institutions and views markets as a result of the complex interaction of these various institutions. The earlier tradition continues today as a leading heterodox approach to economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Edwin E. Witte</span> American economist

Edwin Emil Witte was an economist who focused on social insurance issues for the state of Wisconsin and for the Committee on Economic Security. While the executive director of the President's Committee on Economic Security under U.S. President Franklin D. Roosevelt, he developed during 1934 the policies and the legislation that became the Social Security Act of 1935. Because of this he is sometimes called "the father of Social Security".

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Arthur J. Altmeyer</span>

Arthur Joseph Altmeyer was the United States Commissioner for Social Security from 1946 to 1953, and chairman of the Social Security Board from 1937 to 1946. He was a key figure in the design and implementation of the U.S. Social Security system.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Richard T. Ely</span> American economist (1854–1943)

Richard Theodore Ely was an American economist, author, and leader of the Progressive movement who called for more government intervention to reform what they perceived as the injustices of capitalism, especially regarding factory conditions, compulsory education, child labor, and labor unions.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Edward Alsworth Ross</span> American sociologist

Edward Alsworth Ross was a progressive American sociologist, eugenicist, economist, and major figure of early criminology.

The history of economic thought is the study of the philosophies of the different thinkers and theories in the subjects that later became political economy and economics, from the ancient world to the present day.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Selig Perlman</span> American historian

Selig Perlman was an economist and labor historian at the University of Wisconsin–Madison.

Kenneth Herald Parsons (1903–1998) was a professor of agricultural economics at the University of Wisconsin–Madison.

Sumner Huber Slichter was an American economist and the first Lamont University Professor at Harvard University. He was considered by many to be the pre-eminent labor economist of the 1940s and 1950s. He was adamantly opposed to the labor movement, and called repeatedly for legislation against unionization. He was also a critic of the New Deal."

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Daniel Bromley</span> American economist

Daniel W. Bromley is an economist, the former Anderson-Bascom Professor of applied economics at the University of Wisconsin–Madison, and since 2009, Emeritus Professor. His research in institutional economics explains the foundations of property rights, natural resources and the environment; and economic development. He has been editor of the journal Land Economics since 1974.

Constitutional economics is a research program in economics and constitutionalism that has been described as explaining the choice "of alternative sets of legal-institutional-constitutional rules that constrain the choices and activities of economic and political agents". This extends beyond the definition of "the economic analysis of constitutional law" and is distinct from explaining the choices of economic and political agents within those rules, a subject of orthodox economics. Instead, constitutional economics takes into account the impacts of political economic decisions as opposed to limiting its analysis to economic relationships as functions of the dynamics of distribution of marketable goods and services.

Helen Laura Sumner Woodbury was an American economist, academic, historian and public official.

References

Commons, John, R. 1900. Representative Democracy. New York: American Bureau of Economic Research, 1900. Available at https://babel.hathitrust.org/cgi/pt?id=coo.31924032462842&view=1up&seq=18