Kenneth Arrow

Last updated

Kenneth Arrow
Kenneth Arrow, Stanford University.jpg
Arrow in 1996
Born
Kenneth Joseph Arrow

August 23, 1921
New York City, U.S.
DiedFebruary 21, 2017(2017-02-21) (aged 95)
Education
Academic career
Field
Institution Stanford University
University of Chicago
Harvard University
School or
tradition
Neoclassical economics
Doctoral
advisor
Harold Hotelling
Doctoral
students
Influences
Contributions
Awards
Information at IDEAS / RePEc
Website healthpolicy.fsi.stanford.edu/people/kenneth_j_arrow

Kenneth Joseph Arrow (August 23, 1921 – February 21, 2017) was an American economist, mathematician, writer, and political theorist. Along with John Hicks, he won the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1972.

Contents

In economics, Arrow was a major figure in post-World War II neoclassical economic theory. Many of his former graduate students have gone on to win the Nobel Memorial Prize themselves. His contributions to social choice theory, notably "Arrow's impossibility theorem", and his work on general equilibrium analysis are significant. He has also provided foundational work in many other areas of economics, including endogenous growth theory and the economics of information.

Education and early career

Arrow was born on August 23, 1921, in New York City. [3] Arrow's mother, Lilian (Greenberg), was from Iași, Romania, and his father, Harry Arrow, was from nearby Podu Iloaiei. [4] [5] The Arrow family were Romanian Jews. [3] [6] [7] His family was very supportive of his education. [3] Growing up during the Great Depression, he embraced socialism in his youth. He would later move away from socialism, but his views retained a left-leaning philosophy. [8]

He graduated from Townsend Harris High School and then earned a bachelor's degree in mathematics from the City College of New York in 1940, where he was a member of Sigma Phi Epsilon. He then attended Columbia University for graduate studies, obtaining a master's degree in mathematics in June 1941. [9] At Columbia, Arrow studied under Harold Hotelling, who influenced him to switch fields to economics. [8] He served as a weather officer in the United States Army Air Forces from 1942 to 1946. [10] [3]

Academic career

From 1946 to 1949 Arrow spent his time partly as a graduate student at Columbia and partly as a research associate at the Cowles Commission for Research in Economics, then at the University of Chicago. During that time he also held the rank of Assistant Professor in Economics at the University of Chicago and worked at the RAND Corporation in California. He left Chicago to take up the post of Acting Assistant Professor of Economics and Statistics at Stanford University. In 1951, he earned his PhD from Columbia. [9] He served in the government on the staff of the Council of Economic Advisers in the 1960s with Robert Solow. [11] In 1968, he left Stanford for the position of Professor of Economics at Harvard University. It was during his tenure there that he received the Nobel Prize in Economics. [9]

Arrow returned to Stanford in 1979 and became the Joan Kenney Professor of Economics and Professor of Operations Research. He retired in 1991. As a Fulbright Distinguished Chair, in 1995 he taught economics at the University of Siena. He was also a founding member of the Pontifical Academy of Social Sciences and a member of the Science Board of Santa Fe Institute. At various stages in his career he was a Fellow of Churchill College, Cambridge. [9] He was one of the founding editors of the Annual Review of Economics , which was first published in 2009. [12]

Four of his former students have gone on to become Nobel Prize winners, namely John Harsanyi, Eric Maskin, Roger Myerson, and Michael Spence. [13] A collection of Arrow's papers is housed at the Rubenstein Library at Duke University. [14]

Arrow's impossibility theorem

Arrow's monograph Social Choice and Individual Values derives from his 1951 PhD thesis.

If we exclude the possibility of interpersonal comparisons of utility, then the only methods of passing from individual tastes to social preferences which will be satisfactory and which will be defined for a wide range of sets of individual orderings are either imposed or dictatorial. [15]

In what he named the General Impossibility Theorem, he theorized that, unless we accept to compare the levels of utility reached by different individuals, it is impossible to formulate a social preference ordering that satisfies all of the following conditions: [16]

  1. Nondictatorship: The preferences of an individual should not become the group ranking without considering the preferences of others.
  2. Individual Sovereignty: each individual should be able to order the choices in any way and indicate ties
  3. Unanimity: If every individual prefers one choice to another, then the group ranking should do the same
  4. Freedom From Irrelevant Alternatives: If a choice is removed, then the others' order should not change
  5. Uniqueness of Group Rank: The method should yield the same result whenever applied to a set of preferences. The group ranking should be transitive.

The theorem has implications for welfare economics and theories of justice, and for voting theory (it extends the Condorcet paradox). Following Arrow's logical framework, Amartya Sen formulated the liberal paradox which argued that given a status of "Minimal Liberty" there was no way to obtain Pareto optimality, nor to avoid the problem of social choice of neutral but unequal results. [16]

General equilibrium theory

Work by Arrow and Gérard Debreu and simultaneous work by Lionel McKenzie offered the first rigorous proofs of the existence of a market clearing equilibrium. [17] For this work and his other contributions, Debreu won the 1983 Nobel Prize in Economics. [18] Arrow went on to extend the model and its analysis to include uncertainty, the stability. His contributions to the general equilibrium theory were influenced by Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations . [3] Written in 1776, The Wealth of Nations is an examination of economic growth brought forward by the division of labor, by ensuring interdependence of individuals within society. [19]

In 1974, The American Economic Association published the paper written by Kenneth Arrow, General Economic Equilibrium: Purpose, Analytic Techniques, Collective Choice, where he states:

From the time of Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations in 1776, one recurrent theme of economic analysis has been the remarkable degree of coherence among the vast numbers of individual and seemingly separate decisions about the buying and selling of commodities. In everyday, normal experience, there is something of a balance between the amounts of goods and services that some individuals want to supply and the amounts that other, different individuals want to sell. Would-be buyers ordinarily count correctly on being able to carry out their intentions, and would-be sellers do not ordinarily find themselves producing great amounts of goods that they cannot sell. This experience of balance is indeed so widespread that it raises no intellectual disquiet among laymen; they take it so much for granted that they are not disposed to understand the mechanism by which it occurs. [20]

Fundamental theorems of welfare economics

In 1951, Arrow presented the first and second fundamental theorems of welfare economics and their proofs without requiring differentiability of utility, consumption, or technology, and including corner solutions. [21]

Endogenous-growth theory

Arrow was one of the precursors of endogenous growth theory, which seeks to explain the source of technical change, which is a key driver of economic growth. Until this theory came to prominence, technical change was assumed to occur exogenously  — that is, it was assumed to occur outside economic activities, and was outside (exogenous) to common economic models. At the same time there was no economic explanation for why it occurred. Endogenous-growth theory provided standard economic reasons for why firms innovate, leading economists to think of innovation and technical change as determined by economic actors, that is endogenously to economic activities, and thus belong inside the model. Endogenous growth theory started with Paul Romer's 1986 paper, [22] borrowing from Arrow's 1962 "learning-by-doing" model which introduced a mechanism to eliminate diminishing returns in aggregate output. [3] [23] A literature on this theory has developed subsequently to Arrow's work. [24]

Information economics

In other pioneering research, Arrow investigated the problems caused by asymmetric information in markets. In many transactions, one party (usually the seller) has more information about the product being sold than the other party. Asymmetric information creates incentives for the party with more information to cheat the party with less information; as a result, a number of market structures have developed, including warranties and third party authentication, which enable markets with asymmetric information to function. Arrow analysed this issue for medical care (a 1963 paper entitled "Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care", in the American Economic Review); [25] later researchers investigated many other markets, particularly second-hand assets, online auctions and insurance.

Awards and honors

Arrow was awarded the John Bates Clark Medal in 1957 [26] and was elected a Fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences in 1959. [27] In 1968, he was elected to both the United States National Academy of Sciences [28] and the American Philosophical Society. [29] He was the joint winner of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics with John Hicks in 1972 and the 1986 recipient of the von Neumann Theory Prize. [9] He was one of the recipients of the 2004 National Medal of Science, the nation's highest scientific honor, presented by President George W. Bush for his contributions to research on the problem of making decisions using imperfect information and his research on bearing risk. [4] [30]

He has received honorary doctorates from the University of Chicago (1967), the University of Vienna (1971) the City University of New York (1972). [9] On 2 June 1995 he received an honorary doctorate from the Faculty of Social Sciences at Uppsala University, Sweden. [31] He was elected a Foreign Member of the Royal Society (ForMemRS) in 2006. [32] He was elected to the 2002 class of Fellows of the Institute for Operations Research and the Management Sciences. [33] In 2007 he was the first Witten Lecturer at the Witten/Herdecke University as the awardee of the Witten Lectures in Economics and Philosophy. [34]

Personal life and death

Arrow was a brother to the economist Anita Summers, uncle to economist and former Treasury Secretary and Harvard President Larry Summers, and brother-in-law of the late economists Robert Summers and Paul Samuelson. [35] In 1947, he married Selma Schweitzer, graduate in economics at the University of Chicago [36] and psychotherapist, who died in 2015; they had two children, David Michael (b. 1962), an actor, [37] and Andrew Seth (b. 1965), an actor/singer. [9]

Arrow was well known for being a polymath, possessing prodigious knowledge of subjects far removed from economics. On one occasion (recounted by Eric Maskin), in an attempt to artificially test Arrow's knowledge, the junior faculty agreed to closely study the breeding habits of gray whales  — a suitably obscure topic — and discuss it in his presence. To their surprise, Arrow already was familiar with the work they had studied and, in addition, thought it had been refuted by other research. [35]

Arrow died in his Palo Alto, California, home on February 21, 2017, at the age of 95. [35]

Publications

Reprinted as: Arrow, Kenneth J. (1963). Social Choice and Individual Values (2nd ed.). New Haven: Yale University Press. ISBN   9780300013641.
Also available as: Arrow, Kenneth J.; Hurwicz, Leonid (1977). Appendix: An optimality criterion for decision-making under ignorance. Cambridge Books Online. pp. 461–72. doi:10.1017/CBO9780511752940.015. ISBN   9780511752940.
and as: Arrow, Kenneth J.; Hurwicz, Leonid (1977), "Appendix: An optimality criterion for decision-making under ignorance", in Arrow, Kenneth J.; Hurwicz, Leonid (eds.), Studies in resource allocation processes, Cambridge New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 461–72, ISBN   9780521215220.
Including: Arrow, Kenneth J. Price-quantity adjustments in multiple markets with rising demands, pp. 3–15.
Reprinted as: Arrow, Kenneth J. (1983b), "The organization of economic activity: issues pertinent to the choice of market versus non-market allocations", in Arrow, Kenneth J. (ed.), Collected papers of Kenneth J. Arrow, volume 2: general equilibrium, Cambridge, Massachusetts: Belknap Press, pp. 133–55, ISBN   9780674137615.
Also reprinted as a pdf.
Reprinted as: Arrow, Kenneth J. (1983a), "Extended sympathy and the possibility of social choice", in Arrow, Kenneth J. (ed.), Collected papers of Kenneth J. Arrow, volume 1: social Choice and justice, Cambridge, Massachusetts: Belknap Press, ISBN   9780674137608.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1983a). Collected papers of Kenneth J. Arrow, volume 1: social Choice and justice. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Belknap Press. ISBN   9780674137608.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1983b). Collected papers of Kenneth J. Arrow, volume 2: general equilibrium. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Belknap Press. ISBN   9780674137615.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1984a). Collected papers of Kenneth J. Arrow, volume 3: individual choice under certainty and uncertainty. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Belknap Press. ISBN   9780674137622.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1984b). Collected papers of Kenneth J. Arrow, volume 4: the economics of information. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Belknap Press. ISBN   9780674137639.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1985a). Collected papers of Kenneth J. Arrow, volume 5: production and capital. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Belknap Press. ISBN   9780674137776.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1985b). Collected papers of Kenneth J. Arrow, volume 6: applied economics. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Belknap Press. ISBN   9780674137783.
Also available online as: Arrow, Kenneth J. (2008). "Arrow's theorem". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2nd ed.). Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 241–245. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0061. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
Also available online as: Arrow, Kenneth J. (2008). "Hotelling, Harold (1895–1973)". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2nd ed.). Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 73–75. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0747. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.

See also

Related Research Articles

Neoclassical economics is an approach to economics in which the production, consumption, and valuation (pricing) of goods and services are observed as driven by the supply and demand model. According to this line of thought, the value of a good or service is determined through a hypothetical maximization of utility by income-constrained individuals and of profits by firms facing production costs and employing available information and factors of production. This approach has often been justified by appealing to rational choice theory.

In economics, general equilibrium theory attempts to explain the behavior of supply, demand, and prices in a whole economy with several or many interacting markets, by seeking to prove that the interaction of demand and supply will result in an overall general equilibrium. General equilibrium theory contrasts with the theory of partial equilibrium, which analyzes a specific part of an economy while its other factors are held constant. In general equilibrium, constant influences are considered to be noneconomic, or in other words, considered to be beyond the scope of economic analysis. The noneconomic influences may change given changes in the economic factors however, and therefore the prediction accuracy of an equilibrium model may depend on the independence of the economic factors from noneconomic ones.

Public choice, or public choice theory, is "the use of economic tools to deal with traditional problems of political science." Its content includes the study of political behavior. In political science, it is the subset of positive political theory that studies self-interested agents and their interactions, which can be represented in a number of ways—using standard constrained utility maximization, game theory, or decision theory. It is the origin and intellectual foundation of contemporary work in political economy.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Amartya Sen</span> Indian economist and philosopher (born 1933)

Amartya Kumar Sen is an Indian economist and philosopher. Sen has taught and worked in England and the United States since 1972. In 1998, Sen received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his contributions to welfare economics. He has also made major scholarly contributions to social choice theory, economic and social justice, economic theories of famines, decision theory, development economics, public health, and the measures of well-being of countries.

Arrow's impossibility theorem is a key result in social choice showing that no ranked voting rule can behave rationally. Specifically, any such rule violates independence of irrelevant alternatives, the idea that a choice between and should not depend on the quality of a third, unrelated option . The result is most often cited in election science and voting theory, where is called a spoiler candidate. In this context, Arrow's theorem can be restated as showing that no ranked voting rule can eliminate the spoiler effect.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">John Hicks</span> British economist (1904–1989)

Sir John Richard Hicks was a British economist. He is considered one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. The most familiar of his many contributions in the field of economics were his statement of consumer demand theory in microeconomics, and the IS–LM model (1937), which summarised a Keynesian view of macroeconomics. His book Value and Capital (1939) significantly extended general-equilibrium and value theory. The compensated demand function is named the Hicksian demand function in memory of him.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Paul Samuelson</span> American economist (1915–2009)

Paul Anthony Samuelson was an American economist who was the first American to win the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. When awarding the prize in 1970, the Swedish Royal Academies stated that he "has done more than any other contemporary economist to raise the level of scientific analysis in economic theory".

In the social sciences, methodological individualism is a framework that describes social phenomena as a consequence of subjective personal motivations by individual actors. Class or group dynamics which operate on systemic explanations, are deemed illusory, and, thus, rejected or de-prioritized, however, group dynamics for which there are individual subjective motivations are upheld. With its bottom-up micro-level approach, methodological individualism is often contrasted with methodological holism, a top-down macro-level approach, and methodological pluralism.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">John Harsanyi</span> Hungarian-American economist and philosopher (1920–2000)

John Charles Harsanyi was a Hungarian-American economist who spent most of his career at the University of California, Berkeley. He was the recipient of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1994.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Gérard Debreu</span> French economist and mathematician

Gérard Debreu was a French-born economist and mathematician. Best known as a professor of economics at the University of California, Berkeley, where he began work in 1962, he won the 1983 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Michio Morishima</span>

Michio Morishima was a Japanese heterodox economist and public intellectual who was the Sir John Hicks Professor of Economics at the London School of Economics from 1970 to 1988. He was also professor at Osaka University and member of the British Academy. In 1976 he won the Order of Culture.

Social choice theory is a branch of welfare economics that analyzes methods of combining individual opinions, beliefs, or preferences to reach a collective decision or create measures of social well-being. It contrasts with political science in that it is a normative field that studies how societies should make decisions, whereas political science is descriptive. Social choice incorporates insights from economics, mathematics, philosophy, political science, and game theory to find the best ways to combine individual preferences into a coherent whole, called a social welfare function.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Hirofumi Uzawa</span> Japanese economist (1928–2014)

Hirofumi Uzawa was a Japanese economist.

The Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics is an economic research institute at Yale University. It was created as the Cowles Commission for Research in Economics at Colorado Springs in 1932 by businessman and economist Alfred Cowles. In 1939, the Cowles Commission moved to the University of Chicago under Theodore O. Yntema. Jacob Marschak directed it from 1943 until 1948, when Tjalling C. Koopmans assumed leadership. Increasing opposition to the Cowles Commission from the department of economics of the University of Chicago during the 1950s impelled Koopmans to persuade the Cowles family to move the commission to Yale University in 1955 where it became the Cowles Foundation.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Jacob Marschak</span> American economist (1898-1977)

Jacob Marschak was an American economist.

Lionel Wilfred McKenzie was an American economist. He was the Wilson Professor Emeritus of Economics at the University of Rochester. He was born in Montezuma, Georgia. He completed undergraduate studies at Duke University in 1939 and subsequently moved to Oxford that year as a Rhodes Scholar. McKenzie worked with the Cowles Commission while it was in Chicago and served as an assistant professor at Duke from 1948 to 1957. Having received his Ph.D. at Princeton University in 1956, McKenzie moved to Rochester where he was responsible for the establishment of the graduate program in economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Leonid Hurwicz</span> Polish–American economist and mathematician (1917–2008)

Leonid Hurwicz was a Polish–American economist and mathematician, known for his work in game theory and mechanism design. He originated the concept of incentive compatibility, and showed how desired outcomes can be achieved by using incentive compatible mechanism design. Hurwicz shared the 2007 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his seminal work on mechanism design. Hurwicz was one of the oldest Nobel Laureates, having received the prize at the age of 90.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Roger Myerson</span> American mathematician

Roger Bruce Myerson is an American economist and professor at the University of Chicago. He holds the title of the David L. Pearson Distinguished Service Professor of Global Conflict Studies at The Pearson Institute for the Study and Resolution of Global Conflicts in the Harris School of Public Policy, the Griffin Department of Economics, and the college. Previously, he held the title The Glen A. Lloyd Distinguished Service Professor of Economics. In 2007, he was the winner of the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel with Leonid Hurwicz and Eric Maskin for "having laid the foundations of mechanism design theory." He was elected a Member of the American Philosophical Society in 2019.

Mathematical economics is the application of mathematical methods to represent theories and analyze problems in economics. Often, these applied methods are beyond simple geometry, and may include differential and integral calculus, difference and differential equations, matrix algebra, mathematical programming, or other computational methods. Proponents of this approach claim that it allows the formulation of theoretical relationships with rigor, generality, and simplicity.

Charles Frederick Roos was an American economist who made contributions to mathematical economics. He was one of the founders of the Econometric Society together with American economist Irving Fisher and Norwegian economist Ragnar Frisch in 1930. He served as secretary-treasurer during the first year of the society and was elected as president in 1948. He was director of research of the Cowles Commission from September 1934 to January 1937.

References

  1. Dewar, Diane M. (2017). Essentials of Health Economics. Jones & Bartlett Publishers. ISBN   978-1-284-05462-0.
  2. Arrow, Kenneth Joseph (2017). On Ethics and Economics: Conversations with Kenneth J. Arrow. Routledge. pp. 12, 33. ISBN   978-1-138-67606-0.
  3. 1 2 3 4 5 6 Maskin, Eric S. (August 2, 2019). "The Economics of Kenneth J. Arrow: A Selective Review". Annual Review of Economics. 11 (1): 1–26. doi: 10.1146/annurev-economics-080218-030323 . ISSN   1941-1383. S2CID   164272068.
  4. 1 2 Velupillai, K. Vela (December 2019). "Kenneth Joseph Arrow. 23 August 1921—21 February 2017". Biographical Memoirs of Fellows of the Royal Society. 67: 9–28. doi: 10.1098/rsbm.2019.0002 . ISSN   0080-4606. S2CID   186214334.
  5. Feiwel, George R., ed. (January 1, 2016). Arrow and the Foundations of the Theory of Economic Policy. Springer. ISBN   978-1-349-07357-3.
  6. Wahid, Abu N.M. (2002). Frontiers of Economics: Nobel Laureates of the Twentieth Century. Greenwood Publishing. p. 5. ISBN   0-313-32073-X.
  7. Pressman, Steven (1999). Fifty major economists: Business & Economics. Routledge Publishing. p. 177. ISBN   0-415-13480-3.
  8. 1 2 Klein, Daniel B. (2013). "Kenneth J. Arrow [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates]" (PDF). Econ Journal Watch. 10 (3): 268–281. Retrieved March 28, 2023.
  9. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Kenneth Arrow on Nobelprize.org OOjs UI icon edit-ltr-progressive.svg
  10. "Kenneth J. Arrow, MA, PhD". Stanford University. Retrieved November 1, 2014.
  11. D., S. (February 25, 2010). "The best since the 1960s?". The Economist. Retrieved March 28, 2023.
  12. Arrow, Kenneth J.; Bresnahan, Timothy (2009). "Preface". Annual Review of Economics. 1. doi: 10.1146/annurev.ec.1.081709.100001 .
  13. Stefancic, Mitja (July 2021). "Review of J. Maesse et al. (2022) "Power and Influence of Economists: Contributions to the Social Studies of Economics" | World Economics Association". WEA Commentaries. 11 (2): 11–12. Retrieved March 28, 2023.
  14. "Kenneth J. Arrow Papers, 1939–2009". Rubenstein Library, Duke University.
  15. Arrow, Kenneth J. (1950). "A Difficulty in the Concept of Social Welfare". Journal of Political Economy. 58 (4): 328–346. doi:10.1086/256963. ISSN   0022-3808. JSTOR   1828886. S2CID   13923619.
  16. 1 2 Morreau, Michael (January 1, 2016). "Arrow's Theorem". The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. Metaphysics Research Lab, Stanford University. Retrieved February 25, 2017.
  17. Mas-Colell, Andreu; Whinston, Michael D.; Green, Jerry R. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 691–93. ISBN   0-19-507340-1.
  18. "Gerard Debreu – Biographical". nobelprize.org. Retrieved February 25, 2017.
  19. Smith, Adam, and Andrew S. Skinner. The wealth of nations. London: Penguin Books, 1999. Print.
  20. Arrow, Kenneth (1974). "General Economic Equilibrium: Purpose, Analytic Techniques, Collective Choice". American Economic Review . 64 (3): 253–72. JSTOR   1808881.
  21. "Kenneth Arrow (1921– )". Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Liberty Fund. 2008. Retrieved June 18, 2017.
  22. Romer, Paul M. (1986). "Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth" (PDF). Journal of Political Economy . 94 (5): 1002–37. doi:10.1086/261420. JSTOR   1833190. S2CID   6818002.
  23. Arrow, Kenneth J. (1962). "The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing". The Review of Economic Studies . 29 (3): 155–73. doi:10.2307/2295952. JSTOR   2295952. S2CID   155029478.
  24. Barro, Robert J.; Sala-i-Martin, Xavier (2004). Economic Growth (2nd ed.). Cambridge: MIT Press. pp. 212–20. ISBN   0-262-02553-1.
  25. Savedoff, William D. (February 2004). "Kenneth Arrow and the birth of health economics". Bulletin of the World Health Organization. 82 (2): 139–140. hdl:10665/269064. ISSN   0042-9686. PMC   2585899 . PMID   15042237 . Retrieved March 27, 2023.
  26. "John Bates Clark Medal". American Economic Association. Retrieved February 25, 2017.
  27. "Kenneth Joseph Arrow". American Academy of Arts and Sciences. Retrieved April 25, 2011.
  28. "Kenneth J. Arrow". National Academy of Sciences. Retrieved September 16, 2022.
  29. "Dr. Kenneth J. Arrow". American Philosophical Society Member History. Retrieved September 16, 2022.
  30. "The President's National Medal of Science: Recipient Details". National Science Foundation. Retrieved March 28, 2023.
  31. "Honorary Doctors of the Faculty of Social Sciences - Uppsala University, Sweden". Uppsala University. Retrieved March 27, 2023.
  32. "Central Secretariat and Library and Information Services List of Fellows of the Royal Society 1660 - 201" (PDF). The Royal Society. February 2020. Retrieved March 28, 2023.
  33. "INFORMS Fellows: Class of 2002". INFORMS. Retrieved March 27, 2023.
  34. "Witten Lectures in Economics and Philosophy". wittenlectures.org. 2007. Retrieved August 19, 2024.
  35. 1 2 3 Weinstein, Michael M. (February 21, 2017). "Kenneth Arrow, Nobel-Winning Economist Whose Influence Spanned Decades, Dies at 95". The New York Times . Retrieved February 21, 2017.
  36. Heller, Walter P.; Starr, Ross M.; Starrett, David A., eds. (1986). "Kenneth J. Arrow". Social Choice and Public Decision Making: Essays in Honor of Kenneth J. Arrow, Volume I. Cambridge University Press. p. xiv. ISBN   0-521-30454-7.
  37. David Arrow at IMDb
  38. See page 236 in Düppe, T., & Weintraub, E. R. (2014). Finding equilibrium: Arrow, Debreu, McKenzie and the problem of scientific credit. Princeton University Press.
Awards
Preceded by Laureate of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics
1972
Served alongside: John R. Hicks
Succeeded by