Richard Kahn, Baron Kahn

Last updated

Richard Ferdinand Kahn
Born(1905-08-10)10 August 1905
Hampstead, England, UK
Died6 June 1989(1989-06-06) (aged 83)
Cambridge, England, UK
NationalityBritish
Field Political economy
School or
tradition
Keynesian economics
Influences Gerald Shove, John Maynard Keynes
Contributions Economic multiplier

Richard Ferdinand Kahn, Baron Kahn, CBE, FBA (10 August 1905 – 6 June 1989) was a British economist.

Kahn was born in Hampstead into the orthodox Jewish family of Augustus Kahn, inspector of schools and former German schoolmaster, and Regina Schoyer. He was brought up in England and educated at St Paul's School, London. He attended King's College, Cambridge. [1] Kahn took a 1st in Mathematics, Part I, at Cambridge, followed in 1927 by a 2nd in Physics in the Natural Sciences tripos. Taught economics by Gerald Shove and John Maynard Keynes from 1927 to 1928, he gained a 1st in Economics, Part II, in 1928. In 1930, he was elected a Fellow of King's College. [2]

Kahn worked in the Faculty of Economics and Politics from 1933. He became Director of Studies for economics students at King's College in 1947, a post he held for four years. Kahn was appointed professor of Economics in 1951, and succeeded Keynes as Bursar of King's College. [3] He served in numerous other government and agency positions, such as the research and planning division of the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe in 1955 and the UK National Coal Board in 1967. [1] Kahn retired from Cambridge in 1972, but continued to live at King's College.

Kahn's most notable contribution to economics was his principle of the multiplier. The multiplier is the relation between the increase in aggregate expenditure and the increase in net national product (output). [2] It is the increase in aggregate expenditure (for example government spending) that causes the increase in output (or income). [4] His findings on the multiplier were first published in his 1931 article, "The Relation of Home Investment to Unemployment". [5] There has been extensive debate on whether Kahn's thinking on the multiplier was foreshadowed or aided by the work of other economists such as Lyndhurst Giblin. [6]

Kahn was one of the five members of Keynes' Cambridge Circus. Kahn was also one of Keynes' closest collaborators on the creation of Keynes' General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. [7]

Kahn was made a Commander of the Order of the British Empire (CBE) in 1946 [8] and became a Fellow of the British Academy in 1960, and was created a life peer with the title Baron Kahn, of Hampstead in the London Borough of Camden on 6 July 1965. [9] [10]

Related Research Articles

Economics Social science that analyzes the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services

Economics is the social science that studies how people interact with value; in particular, the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services.

Keynesian economics

Keynesian economics are various macroeconomic theories about how economic output is strongly influenced by aggregate demand. In the Keynesian view, aggregate demand does not necessarily equal the productive capacity of the economy. Instead, it is influenced by a host of factors. According to Keynes, the productive capacity of the economy sometimes behaves erratically, affecting production, employment, and inflation.

Macroeconomics Branch of economics that studies aggregated indicators

Macroeconomics is a branch of economics dealing with the performance, structure, behavior, and decision-making of an economy as a whole. For example, using interest rates, taxes and government spending to regulate an economy’s growth and stability. This includes regional, national, and global economies.

John Maynard Keynes English economist

John Maynard Keynes, 1st Baron Keynes, was an English economist, whose ideas fundamentally changed the theory and practice of macroeconomics and the economic policies of governments. Originally trained in mathematics, he built on and greatly refined earlier work on the causes of business cycles, and was one of the most influential economists of the 20th century. His ideas are the basis for the school of thought known as Keynesian economics, and its various offshoots.

In economics, the fiscal multiplier is the ratio of change in national income arising from a change in government spending. More generally, the exogenous spending multiplier is the ratio of change in national income arising from any autonomous change in spending. When this multiplier exceeds one, the enhanced effect on national income may be called the multiplier effect. The mechanism that can give rise to a multiplier effect is that an initial incremental amount of spending can lead to increased income and hence increased consumption spending, increasing income further and hence further increasing consumption, etc., resulting in an overall increase in national income greater than the initial incremental amount of spending. In other words, an initial change in aggregate demand may cause a change in aggregate output that is a multiple of the initial change.

Nicholas Kaldor

Nicholas Kaldor, Baron Kaldor, born Káldor Miklós, was a Cambridge economist in the post-war period. He developed the "compensation" criteria called Kaldor–Hicks efficiency for welfare comparisons (1939), derived the cobweb model, and argued for certain regularities observable in economic growth, which are called Kaldor's growth laws. Kaldor worked alongside Gunnar Myrdal to develop the key concept Circular Cumulative Causation, a multicausal approach where the core variables and their linkages are delineated. Both Myrdal and Kaldor examine circular relationships, where the interdependencies between factors are relatively strong, and where variables interlink in the determination of major processes. Gunnar Myrdal got the concept from Knut Wicksell and developed it alongside Nicholas Kaldor when they worked together at the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe. Myrdal concentrated on the social provisioning aspect of development, while Kaldor concentrated on demand-supply relationships to the manufacturing sector. Kaldor also coined the term "convenience yield" related to commodity markets and the so-called theory of storage, which was initially developed by Holbrook Working.

John Hicks

Sir John Hicks was a British economist. He is considered one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. The most familiar of his many contributions in the field of economics were his statement of consumer demand theory in microeconomics, and the IS–LM model (1937), which summarised a Keynesian view of macroeconomics. His book Value and Capital (1939) significantly extended general-equilibrium and value theory. The compensated demand function is named the Hicksian demand function in memory of him.

Arthur Cecil Pigou

Arthur Cecil Pigou was an English economist. As a teacher and builder of the School of Economics at the University of Cambridge, he trained and influenced many Cambridge economists who went on to take chairs of economics around the world. His work covered various fields of economics, particularly welfare economics, but also included Business cycle theory, unemployment, public finance, index numbers, and measurement of national output. His reputation was affected adversely by influential economic writers who used his work as the basis on which to define their own opposing views. He reluctantly served on several public committees, including the Cunliffe Committee and the 1919 Royal Commission on Income tax.

<i>The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money</i>

The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money of 1936 is the last book by the English economist John Maynard Keynes. It created a profound shift in economic thought, giving macroeconomics a central place in economic theory and contributing much of its terminology – the "Keynesian Revolution". It had equally powerful consequences in economic policy, being interpreted as providing theoretical support for government spending in general, and for budgetary deficits, monetary intervention and counter-cyclical policies in particular. It is pervaded with an air of mistrust for the rationality of free-market decision making.

Richard Stone

Sir John Richard Nicholas Stone was an eminent British economist, educated at Westminster School and Cambridge University. In 1984 he received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for developing an accounting model that could be used to track economic activities on a national and, later, an international scale.

Positive economics is the branch of economics that concerns the description, quantification and explanation of economic phenomena. It focuses on facts and cause-and-effect behavioral relationships and notes that economic theories must be consistent with existing observations. Positive economics as science, concerns analysis of economic behavior, to determine what is. Positive economics was once known as value-free economics. Examples of positive economic statements are "the unemployment rate in France is higher than that in the United States," or “an increase in government spending would lower the unemployment rate.” Either of these is potentially falsifiable, and may be contradicted by evidence. Positive economics as such avoids economic value judgements. For example, a positive economic theory might describe how money supply growth affects inflation, but it does not provide any instruction on what policy ought to be followed. This contrasts normative economic statements in which an opinion is given. For example, “Government spending should be increased” is a normative statement.

R. G. D. Allen

Sir Roy George Douglas Allen, CBE, FBA was an English economist, mathematician and statistician, also member of the International Statistical Institute.

Lyndhurst Falkiner Giblin, was an Australian statistician and economist. He was an unsuccessful gold prospector, played rugby union for England, and fought in the First World War.

Stephen Nickell

Sir Stephen John Nickell, is a British economist and former Warden of Nuffield College, Oxford, noted for his work in labour economics with Richard Layard and Richard Jackman. Nickell and Layard hypothesised the tendency for reduced unemployment to lead to inflation resulted from its effect on competitive bargaining in the labour market He is currently a member of the Office for Budget Responsibility's Budget Responsibility Committee.

Ralph George Hawtrey

Sir Ralph George Hawtrey was a British economist, and a close friend of John Maynard Keynes. He was a member of the Cambridge Apostles, the University of Cambridge intellectual secret society.

Multiplier (economics)

In macroeconomics, a multiplier is a factor of proportionality that measures how much a n endogenous variable changes in response to a change in some exogenous variable.

History of macroeconomic thought

Macroeconomic theory has its origins in the study of business cycles and monetary theory. In general, early theorists believed monetary factors could not affect real factors such as real output. John Maynard Keynes attacked some of these "classical" theories and produced a general theory that described the whole economy in terms of aggregates rather than individual, microeconomic parts. Attempting to explain unemployment and recessions, he noticed the tendency for people and businesses to hoard cash and avoid investment during a recession. He argued that this invalidated the assumptions of classical economists who thought that markets always clear, leaving no surplus of goods and no willing labor left idle.

Wynne Godley

Wynne Godley was an economist famous for his pessimism about the British economy and his criticism of the British government. In 2007, he and Marc Lavoie wrote a book about the "Stock-Flow Consistent" model, an analysis that predicted the global financial crisis of 2008.

The Cambridge Circus or Keynes's Circus was a group of young Cambridge economists closely associated with John Maynard Keynes. The group consisted of Richard Kahn, James Meade, Joan Robinson, Austin Robinson, and Piero Sraffa. The Circus formed immediately following the 31 October 1930 publication of Keynes's A Treatise on Money. The group met to read and discuss the Treatise and to provide feedback on Keynes's continuing theoretical work that would lead to his General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. Sraffa initiated the group, which met in Kahn's rooms of the Gibb's Building at King's College. The Circus met among themselves and in a seminar, which included some undergraduates, during the 1930-1931 academic year. The seminar convened in the Old Combination Room of Trinity College.

Demand-side economics is a term used to describe the position that economic growth and full employment are most effectively created by high demand for products and services. According to demand-side economics, output is determined by effective demand. High consumer spending leads to business expansion, resulting in greater employment opportunities. Higher levels of employment create a multiplier effect that further stimulates aggregate demand, leading to greater economic growth.

References

  1. 1 2 John M. Shaftesley (2008). "Encyclopaedia Judaica: Kahn, Richard Ferdinand, Lord". The Gale Group. Retrieved 27 October 2012.
  2. 1 2 Luigi L. Pasinetti (2008). Durlauf, Steven N.; Blume, Lawrence E. (eds.). "Kahn, Richard Ferdinand (1905–1989)". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics . Palgrave Macmillan: 660–662. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0879. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5 . Retrieved 30 October 2012.
  3. "The Papers of Richard Ferdinand Kahn, RFK". Cambridge: King's College Archive Centre. Retrieved 27 October 2012.
  4. Richard Goodwin (1994). "Kahn and Economic Dynamics". Cambridge Journal of Economics. UK: Oxford University Press. 18 (1): 73–76. Retrieved 27 October 2012.
  5. R. F. Kahn (June 1931). "The Relation of Home Investment to Unemployment". The Economic Journal. Wyley-Blackwell. 41 (162): 173–198. doi:10.2307/2223697. JSTOR   2223697.
  6. See, e.g., Donald Markwell, Keynes and Australia, Reserve Bank of Australia, 2000, pages 34–7. http://www.rba.gov.au/publications/rdp/2000/pdf/rdp2000-04.pdf
  7. Kahn, Richard F. (2011). The making of Keynes' general theory (Reprint of 1984 first ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN   9780521189750 . Retrieved 30 October 2012. Peter Clarke, The Keynesian Revolution in the Making, 1924–1936, Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1990. http://ukcatalogue.oup.com/product/9780198202196.do
  8. "No. 37598". The London Gazette (Supplement). 13 June 1946. p. 2784.
  9. "No. 43708". The London Gazette . 9 July 1965. pp. 6519–6520.
  10. "The Peerage – Persons". ThePeerage.com. 21 May 2006. p. 191477. Retrieved 27 October 2012. Richard Ferdinand Cahn, Baron Kahn was invested as a Commander, Order of the British Empire (C.B.E.). He was created Baron Kahn of Hampstead in the London Borough of Camden, U.K. Life Peer. on 6 July 1965

Further reading