Robert Solow

Last updated

Robert Solow
Robert Solow by Olaf Storbeck.jpg
Solow in 2008
Born
Robert Merton Solow

(1924-08-23)August 23, 1924
DiedDecember 21, 2023(2023-12-21) (aged 99)
Education Harvard University (AB, AM, PhD)
Columbia University
Academic career
Institution Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Field Macroeconomics
School or
tradition
Neo-Keynesian economics
Doctoral
advisor
Wassily Leontief
Doctoral
students
George Akerlof [1]
Mario Baldassarri [2]
Francis M. Bator [3]
Charlie Bean [4]
Alan Blinder [5]
Vittorio Corbo
Peter Diamond [6]
Avinash Dixit [7]
Mario Draghi
Alain Enthoven [8]
Ray Fair [9]
Ronald Findlay [10]
Robert J. Gordon [11]
Robert Hall [12]
Michael Intriligator [13]
Katsuhito Iwai [14]
Ronald W. Jones [15]
Arnold Kling
Meir Kohn  [ cz ]
Glenn Loury [16]
Herbert Mohring [17]
William Nordhaus [18]
George Perry [19]
Robert Pindyck
Arjun Kumar Sengupta [20]
Steven Shavell [21]
Eytan Sheshinski  [ he ] [22]
Jeremy Siegel [23]
Joseph Stiglitz [24]
Harvey M. Wagner [25]
Martin Weitzman [26]
Halbert White [27]
Influences Paul Samuelson
Contributions Solow–Swan model
Awards John Bates Clark Medal (1961)
Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (1987)
National Medal of Science (1999)
Presidential Medal of Freedom (2014)
Information at IDEAS / RePEc

Robert Merton Solow, GCIH ( /ˈsl/ ; August 23, 1924 – December 21, 2023) was an American economist and Nobel laureate whose work on the theory of economic growth culminated in the exogenous growth model named after him. [28] [29]

Contents

He was Institute Professor Emeritus of Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, where he was a professor from 1949 on. [30] He was awarded the John Bates Clark Medal in 1961, [31] the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1987, [32] and the Presidential Medal of Freedom in 2014. [33] Four of his PhD students, George Akerlof, Joseph Stiglitz, Peter Diamond, and William Nordhaus, later received Nobel Memorial Prizes in Economic Sciences in their own right. [34] [35] [36] while an undergraduate student of Solow, H. Robert Horvitz, won in medicine.

Biography

Robert Solow was born in Brooklyn, New York, into a Jewish family on August 23, 1924, the oldest of three children. He regarded his parents as being very intelligent despite their not being able to attend college due to the necessity to work. [37] He was well educated in the neighborhood public schools and excelled academically early in life. [38] In September 1940, Solow went to Harvard College with a scholarship at the age of 16. At Harvard, his first studies were in sociology and anthropology as well as elementary economics. [38]

In 1942, Solow left the university and joined the U.S. Army. Because he was fluent in German, the Army put him on a task force whose primary purpose was to intercept, interpret, and send back German messages to base. [39] He served briefly in North Africa and Sicily, and later in Italy until he was discharged in August 1945. [38] [40] Shortly after returning, he proceeded to marry his girlfriend, Barbara Lewis (died 2014), whom he had been dating for six weeks. [39]

Solow returned to Harvard in 1945, and studied under Wassily Leontief. As Leontief's research assistant he produced the first set of capital-coefficients for the input–output model. Then he became interested in statistics and probability models. From 1949 to 1950, he spent a fellowship year at Columbia University to study statistics more intensively. During that year he also worked on his Ph.D. thesis, an exploratory attempt to model changes in the size distribution of wage income using interacting Markov processes for employment-unemployment and wage rates. [38]

In 1949, just before going off to Columbia, he was offered and accepted an assistant professorship in the Economics Department at Massachusetts Institute of Technology. At MIT he taught courses in statistics and econometrics. Solow's interest gradually changed to macroeconomics. For almost 40 years, Solow and Paul Samuelson worked together on many landmark theories: von Neumann growth theory (1953), theory of capital (1956), linear programming (1958) and the Phillips curve (1960).

Solow also held several government positions, including senior economist for the Council of Economic Advisers (1961–62) and member of the President's Commission on Income Maintenance (1968–70). His studies focused mainly in the fields of employment and growth policies, and the theory of capital.

In 1961 he won the American Economic Association's John Bates Clark Award, given to the best economist under age forty. In 1979 he served as president of that association. In 1987, he won the Nobel Prize for his analysis of economic growth [38] and in 1999, he received the National Medal of Science. In 2011, he received an honorary degree in Doctor of Science from Tufts University. [41]

Solow was the founder of the Cournot Foundation and the Cournot Centre. After the death of his colleague Franco Modigliani, Solow accepted an appointment as new Chairman of the I.S.E.O Institute, an Italian nonprofit cultural association which organizes international conferences and summer schools. He was a founding trustee of the Economists for Peace and Security. [42]

Solow's students include Nobel Prize winners Peter Diamond, George Akerlof, Joseph Stiglitz, and William Nordhaus, as well as Michael Rothschild, Halbert White, Charlie Bean, Michael Woodford, and Harvey Wagner.

Solow was one of the signees of a 2018 amicus curiae brief that expressed support for Harvard University in the Students for Fair Admissions v. President and Fellows of Harvard College lawsuit. Signers of the brief include Alan B. Krueger, George A. Akerlof, Janet Yellen, and Cecilia Rouse. [43]

Solow was one of the supporters of Joe Biden's Inflation Reduction Act of 2022. [44]

Solow died at his home in Lexington, Massachusetts, on December 21, 2023, at the age of 99. [45]

Model of economic growth

Solow's model of economic growth, often known as the Solow–Swan neoclassical growth model as the model was independently discovered by Trevor W. Swan and published in "The Economic Record" in 1956, allows the determinants of economic growth to be separated into increases in inputs (labour and capital) and technical progress. The reason these models are called "exogenous" growth models is the saving rate is taken to be exogenously given. Subsequent work derives savings behavior from an inter-temporal utility-maximizing framework. Using his model, Solow (1957) calculated that about four-fifths of the growth in US output per worker was attributable to technical progress.

Bill Clinton awarding Solow the National Medal of Science in 1999 Solow natmedal.jpg
Bill Clinton awarding Solow the National Medal of Science in 1999

Solow also was the first to develop a growth model with different vintages of capital. [46] The idea behind Solow's vintage capital growth model is that new capital is more valuable than old (vintage) capital because new capital is produced through known technology. He first states that capital must be a finite entity because all of the resources on the earth are indeed limited. [39] Within the confines of Solow's model, this known technology is assumed to be constantly improving. Consequently, the products of this technology (the new capital) are expected to be more productive as well as more valuable. [46]

The idea lay dormant for some time perhaps because Dale W. Jorgenson (1966) argued that it was observationally equivalent with disembodied technological progress, as advanced earlier in Solow (1957). It was successfully advanced in subsequent research by Jeremy Greenwood, Zvi Hercowitz and Per Krusell (1997), who argued that the secular decline in capital goods prices could be used to measure embodied technological progress. They labeled the notion investment-specific technological progress. Solow (2001) approved. Both Paul Romer and Robert Lucas, Jr. subsequently developed alternatives to Solow's neoclassical growth model. [46]

To better communicate the meaning behind his work, Solow used a graphical design to illustrate his concepts. On the x-axis he puts capital per worker and for the y-axis he uses output per worker. The reason for graphing capital and output per worker is due to his assumption that the nation is at full employment. The first (top) curve represents the output produced at each given level of capital. The second (middle) curve shows the depreciating nature of capital which remains constantly positive. The third curve (bottom) conveys savings/investment per worker. As the old machinery wears down and breaks, new capital goods must be bought to replace the old. The point where the two lines meet is known as the steady state level, which means that the nation is producing just enough to be able to replace the old capital. Countries that are closer to the steady state level, on the left side, grow more slowly when compared to countries closer to the vertex of the graph. When countries are to the right of the steady state level, they are not growing because all the returns they create needs to go to replacing and repairing their old capital. [47]

Since Solow's initial work in the 1950s, many more sophisticated models of economic growth have been proposed, leading to varying conclusions about the causes of economic growth. For example, rather than assuming, as Solow did, that people save at a given constant rate, subsequent work applied a consumer-optimization framework to derive savings behavior endogenously, allowing saving rates to vary at different points in time, depending on income flows, for example. In the 1980s efforts have focused on the role of technological progress in the economy, leading to the development of endogenous growth theory (or new growth theory). Today, economists use Solow's sources-of-growth accounting to estimate the separate effects on economic growth of technological change, capital, and labor. [46]

In 2022, Solow was still an emeritus Institute Professor in the MIT economics department.. [48]

Honors

Publications

Books

Book chapters

Journal articles

See also: Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen and Joseph Stiglitz.

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">James Tobin</span> American economist (1918–2002)

James Tobin was an American economist who served on the Council of Economic Advisers and consulted with the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, and taught at Harvard and Yale Universities. He contributed to the development of key ideas in the Keynesian economics of his generation and advocated government intervention in particular to stabilize output and avoid recessions. His academic work included pioneering contributions to the study of investment, monetary and fiscal policy and financial markets. He also proposed an econometric model for censored dependent variables, the well-known tobit model.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Robert C. Merton</span> American economist

Robert Cox Merton is an American economist, Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences laureate, and professor at the MIT Sloan School of Management, known for his pioneering contributions to continuous-time finance, especially the first continuous-time option pricing model, the Black–Scholes–Merton model. In 1997 Merton together with Myron Scholes were awarded the Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel for the method to determine the value of derivatives.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Rudi Dornbusch</span> German economist (1942–2002)

Rüdiger Dornbusch was a German economist who worked in the United States for most of his career.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">George Akerlof</span> American economist (born 1940)

George Arthur Akerlof is an American economist and a university professor at the McCourt School of Public Policy at Georgetown University and Koshland Professor of Economics Emeritus at the University of California, Berkeley. Akerlof was awarded the 2001 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences, jointly with Michael Spence and Joseph Stiglitz, "for their analyses of markets with asymmetric information."

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Paul Samuelson</span> American economist (1915–2009)

Paul Anthony Samuelson was an American economist who was the first American to win the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. When awarding the prize in 1970, the Swedish Royal Academies stated that he "has done more than any other contemporary economist to raise the level of scientific analysis in economic theory".

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Daron Acemoglu</span> Armenian-American economist

Kamer Daron Acemoğlu is an American economist of Armenian descent who has taught at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology since 1993, where he is currently the Elizabeth and James Killian Professor of Economics. He received the John Bates Clark Medal in 2005, and was named an Institute Professor at MIT in 2019.

Karl Shell is an American theoretical economist, specializing in macroeconomics and monetary economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Paul Romer</span> American economist

Paul Michael Romer is an American economist and policy entrepreneur who is a University Professor in Economics at Boston College. Romer is best known as the former Chief Economist of the World Bank and for co-receiving the 2018 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his work in endogenous growth theory. He also coined the term "mathiness," which he describes as misuse of mathematics in economic research.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Oliver Hart (economist)</span> American economist

Sir Oliver Simon D'Arcy Hart is a British-born American economist, currently the Lewis P. and Linda L. Geyser University Professor at Harvard University. Together with Bengt R. Holmström, he received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 2016.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Olivier Blanchard</span> French economist and professor

Olivier Jean Blanchard is a French economist and professor who currently serves as the Robert M. Solow Professor Emeritus of Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, and as the C. Fred Bergsten Senior Fellow at the Peterson Institute for International Economics. He was the chief economist at the International Monetary Fund from September 1, 2008, to September 8, 2015. Blanchard was appointed to the position under the tenure of Dominique Strauss-Kahn; he was succeeded by Maurice Obstfeld. According to IDEAS/RePEc, he is one of the most cited economists in the world.

Evsey David Domar was a Russian-American economist, famous as developer of the Harrod–Domar model.

The MIT Department of Economics is a department of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology in Cambridge, Massachusetts.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Peter Diamond</span> American economist (born 1940)

Peter Arthur Diamond is an American economist known for his analysis of U.S. Social Security policy and his work as an advisor to the Advisory Council on Social Security in the late 1980s and 1990s. He was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 2010, along with Dale T. Mortensen and Christopher A. Pissarides. He is an Institute Professor at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. On June 6, 2011, he withdrew his nomination to serve on the Federal Reserve's board of governors, citing intractable Republican opposition for 14 months.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Dale W. Jorgenson</span> American economist (1933–2022)

Dale Weldeau Jorgenson was an American economist who served as the Samuel W. Morris University Professor at Harvard University. An influential econometric scholar, he was famed for his work on the relationship between productivity and economic growth, the economics of climate change, and the intersection between economics and statistics. Described as a "master" of his field, he received the John Bates Clark Medal in 1971, and was described as a worthy contender for the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences.

James Michael "Jim" Poterba, FBA is an American economist who is the Mitsui Professor of Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, and current National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) president and chief executive officer.

Franklin Marvin Fisher was an American economist. He taught economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology from 1960 to 2004.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">History of macroeconomic thought</span>

Macroeconomic theory has its origins in the study of business cycles and monetary theory. In general, early theorists believed monetary factors could not affect real factors such as real output. John Maynard Keynes attacked some of these "classical" theories and produced a general theory that described the whole economy in terms of aggregates rather than individual, microeconomic parts. Attempting to explain unemployment and recessions, he noticed the tendency for people and businesses to hoard cash and avoid investment during a recession. He argued that this invalidated the assumptions of classical economists who thought that markets always clear, leaving no surplus of goods and no willing labor left idle.

Iván Werning is an Argentine economist who has served as the Robert M. Solow Professor of Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology since 2014.

Ronald Edsel Findlay was an economist and trade theorist. He served as the Ragnar Nurkse Professor of Economics at Columbia University.

The Cambridge capital controversy, sometimes called "the capital controversy" or "the two Cambridges debate", was a dispute between proponents of two differing theoretical and mathematical positions in economics that started in the 1950s and lasted well into the 1960s. The debate concerned the nature and role of capital goods and a critique of the neoclassical vision of aggregate production and distribution. The name arises from the location of the principals involved in the controversy: the debate was largely between economists such as Joan Robinson and Piero Sraffa at the University of Cambridge in England and economists such as Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, in Cambridge, Massachusetts, United States.

References

  1. Akerlof, George A. (1966). Wages and capital (PDF) (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Archived (PDF) from the original on August 19, 2017. Retrieved June 28, 2017.
  2. Baldassarri, Mario (1978). Government investment, inflation and growth in a mixed economy : theoretical aspects and empirical evidence of the experience of Italian government corporation investments (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. hdl:1721.1/99791.
  3. Bator, Francis M. (1956). Capital, Growth and Welfare—Theories of Allocation (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. hdl:1721.1/97306.
  4. Bean, Charles Richard (1982). Essays in unemployment and economic activity (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Archived from the original on May 26, 2020. Retrieved June 30, 2017.
  5. Blinder, Alan S. (1971). Towards an Economic Theory of Income Distribution (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Retrieved July 1, 2017.
  6. Peter A. Diamond – Autobiography – Nobelprize.org Archived April 1, 2012, at the Wayback Machine , PDF page 2
  7. Dixit, Avinash K. (1968). Development Planning in a Dual Economy (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Retrieved July 1, 2017.
  8. Enthoven, Alain C. (1956). Studies in the theory of inflation (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Retrieved June 30, 2017.
  9. Fair, Ray C. (1968). The Short Run Demand for Employment (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. hdl:1721.1/80461.
  10. Findlay, Ronald Edsel (1960). Essays on Some Theoretical Aspects of Economic Growth (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Retrieved June 30, 2017.
  11. Gordon, Robert J. (1967). Problems in the measurement of real investment in the U.S. private economy (Ph.D.). MIT. hdl:1721.1/105586.
  12. Hall, Robert E. (1967). Essays on the Theory of Wealth (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Retrieved July 5, 2017.
  13. Intriligator, Michael D. (1963). Essays on productivity and savings (PhD thesis). MIT. OCLC   33811859.
  14. Iwai, Katsuhito (1972). Essays on Dynamic Economic Theory – Fisherian Theory of Optimal Capital Accumulation and Keynesian Short-run Disequilibrium Dynamics (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Retrieved July 5, 2017.
  15. Jones, Ronald Winthrop (1956). Essays in the Theory of International Trade and the Balance of Payments (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. hdl:1721.1/106042.
  16. Loury, Glenn Cartman (1976). Essays in the Theory of the Distribution of Income (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. hdl:1721.1/27456.
  17. Mohring, Herbert D. (1959). The life insurance industry: a study of price policy and its determinants (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. hdl:1721.1/11790.
  18. Nordhaus, William Dawbney. (1967). A Theory of Endogenous Technological Change (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Retrieved July 1, 2017. 18. Turgay Özkan|Turkish| date 1979| thesis: Rational Expectations- A game theoretic approach
  19. Perry, George (1961). Aggregate wage determination and the problem of inflation (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Retrieved July 4, 2017.
  20. Sengupta, Arjun Kumar (1963). A study in the constant-elasticity-of-substitution production function (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Retrieved July 4, 2017.
  21. Shavell, Steven Mark (1973). Essays in Economic Theory (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Retrieved July 5, 2017.
  22. Sheshinski, Eytan (1966). Essays on the theory of production and technical progress (PDF) (Ph.D.). MIT. Archived (PDF) from the original on August 6, 2020. Retrieved May 26, 2018.
  23. Siegel, Jeremy J. (1971). Stability of a Monetary Economy with Inflationary Expectations (PDF) (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Archived (PDF) from the original on August 20, 2017. Retrieved July 5, 2017.
  24. Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1966). Studies in the Theory of Economic Growth and Income Distribution (PDF) (Ph.D.). MIT. p. 4. Archived (PDF) from the original on August 19, 2017. Retrieved June 29, 2017.
  25. Wagner, Harvey M. (1962). Statistical Management of Inventory Systems (Ph.D.). Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Retrieved June 30, 2017.
  26. Weitzman, Martin (1967). Toward a theory of iterative economic planning (Ph.D.). MIT . Retrieved May 26, 2018.
  27. Hausman, Jerry (2013), "Hal White: Time at MIT and Early Life Days of Research", in Chen, Xiaohong; Swanson, Norman R. (eds.), Recent Advances and Future Directions in Causality, Prediction, and Specification Analysis, New York: Springer, pp. 209–218, ISBN   978-1-4614-1652-4.
  28. "Robert M. Solow | American economist". Encyclopedia Britannica. Archived from the original on August 1, 2017. Retrieved June 8, 2017.
  29. "Prospects for growth: An interview with Robert Solow". McKinsey & Company. September 2014. Archived from the original on June 22, 2017. Retrieved June 8, 2017.
  30. "MIT Economics Faculty". Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Archived from the original on August 17, 2017. Retrieved August 27, 2017.
  31. "American Economic Association". www.aeaweb.org. Archived from the original on August 1, 2017. Retrieved June 8, 2017.
  32. Solow, Robert M. "Robert M. Solow – Biographical". www.nobelprize.org. Archived from the original on December 12, 2017. Retrieved June 8, 2017.
  33. Schulman, Kori (November 10, 2014). "President Obama Announces the Presidential Medal of Freedom Recipients". whitehouse.gov. Archived from the original on January 21, 2017. Retrieved June 8, 2017.
  34. Dieterle, David A (2017). Economics: The Definitive Encyclopedia from Theory to Practice. Vol. 4. Greenwood. p. 376. ISBN   978-0313397073.
  35. "MIT Libraries' catalog – Barton – Full Catalog – Full Record". library.mit.edu. Archived from the original on December 21, 2023. Retrieved October 10, 2018.
  36. Ivana Kottasová. "Nobel Prize in economics awarded to William Nordhaus and Paul Romer". CNN. Archived from the original on October 9, 2018. Retrieved October 10, 2018.
  37. Martin, Caine. "Robert Solow". youtube. InfiniteHistoryProjectMIT. Retrieved November 13, 2019.
  38. 1 2 3 4 5 "Robert M. Solow – Autobiography". Nobelprize.org. August 23, 1924. Archived from the original on April 17, 2021. Retrieved April 17, 2021.
  39. 1 2 3 Martin, Caine. "Robert Solow". Youtube. InfiniteHistoryProjectMIT. Archived from the original on November 18, 2021. Retrieved November 13, 2019.
  40. "Robert M Solow – Middlesex Massachusetts – Army of the United States". wwii-army.mooseroots.com. Retrieved June 8, 2017.[ permanent dead link ]
  41. "Honorary Degree Recipients 2011". Commencement. Archived from the original on December 22, 2023. Retrieved December 22, 2023.
  42. "Economists for Peace & Security". Archived from the original on January 27, 2020. Retrieved January 21, 2021.
  43. "Economists amended brief" (PDF). admissionscase.harvard.edu. Archived from the original (PDF) on October 22, 2018. Retrieved December 30, 2018.
  44. "DocumentCloud". Archived from the original on August 9, 2022. Retrieved August 9, 2022.
  45. Hershey, Robert; Weinstein, Michael (December 21, 2023). "Robert M. Solow, Groundbreaking Economist and Nobelist, Dies at 99". The New York Times. Archived from the original on December 21, 2023. Retrieved December 21, 2023.
  46. 1 2 3 4 Haines, Joel D.; Sharif, Nawaz M. (2006). "A framework for managing the sophistication of the components of technology for global competition". Competitiveness Review. 16 (2): 106–21. doi:10.1108/cr.2006.16.2.106.
  47. Martin, Caine (February 1956). "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth" (PDF). The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 70 (1): 65–94. doi:10.2307/1884513. hdl:10338.dmlcz/143862. JSTOR   1884513. Archived (PDF) from the original on July 31, 2020. Retrieved November 13, 2019.
  48. "Faculty | MIT Economics". Archived from the original on October 29, 2022. Retrieved October 29, 2022.
  49. "Cidadãos Nacionais Agraciados com Ordens Portuguesas". Página Oficial das Ordens Honoríficas Portuguesas. Archived from the original on February 8, 2012. Retrieved July 31, 2017.
  50. "Robert Merton Solow". American Academy of Arts & Sciences. Archived from the original on June 21, 2022. Retrieved June 21, 2022.
  51. "Robert M. Solow". nasonline.org. Archived from the original on August 14, 2022. Retrieved June 21, 2022.
  52. "APS Member History". search.amphilsoc.org. Archived from the original on June 21, 2022. Retrieved June 21, 2022.

Sources

Awards
Preceded by Laureate of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics
1987
Succeeded by