William Baumol

Last updated

William Baumol
William Baumol.jpg
Born
William Jack Baumol

(1922-02-26)February 26, 1922
DiedMay 4, 2017(2017-05-04) (aged 95)
Institution
Field Microeconomics, industrial organization, entrepreneurship
School or
tradition
Neo-Keynesian economics
Alma mater College of the City of New York (B.Sc. 1942)
London School of Economics (Ph.D. 1949)
Doctoral
advisor
Lionel Robbins
Doctoral
students
Lionel W. McKenzie
William G. Bowen
Burton Malkiel
Harold Tafler Shapiro [1]
Influences Joseph Schumpeter
Arthur Pigou
John Maynard Keynes
Contributions Baumol–Tobin model
Baumol's cost disease
Contestable market theory
Sales revenue maximization model
Information at IDEAS / RePEc

William Jack Baumol (February 26, 1922 – May 4, 2017) was an American economist. He was a professor of economics at New York University, Academic Director of the Berkley Center for Entrepreneurship and Innovation, and Professor Emeritus at Princeton University. He was a prolific author of more than eighty books and several hundred journal articles. [2]

Contents

Baumol wrote extensively about labor market and other economic factors that affect the economy. He also made significant contributions to the theory of entrepreneurship and the history of economic thought. He is among the most influential economists in the world according to IDEAS/RePEc. He was elected a Fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences in 1971. [3]

Baumol was considered a candidate for the Nobel Prize in Economics for 2003, [4] and Thomson Reuters cited him as a potential recipient in 2014, [5] but he died without receiving the prize.

Early life

Baumol was born in the South Bronx. His parents, Solomon and Lillian, were both immigrants from Eastern Europe. [6]

Baumol studied at the City College of New York and was awarded his bachelor's degree in 1942. After college, he served in the U.S. Army in World War II and later worked for the Department of Agriculture as an economist. [6] [7]

Education

He was initially denied entry to the doctoral studies at the London School of Economics and was instead admitted to the Master's program. After witnessing his debating skills at Lord Lionel Robbins' seminars, he was within weeks switched to the doctoral program and also admitted to the faculty as an Assistant Lecturer. [8]

Teaching

While a professor at Princeton University he supervised some graduate students who would eventually become very well-known economists, including Burton Malkiel, William G. Bowen, and Harold Tafler Shapiro. [1]

Research

Precursors in mathematical economics, 1968 Baumol - Precursors in mathematical economics, 1968 - 5895607.tif
Precursors in mathematical economics, 1968

Among his better-known contributions are the theory of contestable markets, the Baumol-Tobin model of transactions demand for money, Baumol's cost disease, which discusses the rising costs associated with service industries, Baumol's sales revenue maximization model [9] and Pigou taxes. [10] [11] His research on environmental economics [12] recognized the fundamental role of non-convexities in causing market failures. [13]

William Baumol also contributed to the transformation of the field of finance, and published contributions to the areas of efficiency of capital markets, portfolio theory, and capital budgeting. [14]

Entrepreneurship

The place of the disruptive innovations and innovative entrepreneurs in traditional economic theory (which describes many efficiency-based ratios assuming uniform outputs) presents theoretic quandaries. Baumol contributed greatly to this area of economic theory. The 2006 Annual Meetings of the American Economic Association held a special session in his name, and honoring his many years of work in the field of entrepreneurship and innovation, [15] where 12 papers on entrepreneurship were presented. [16]

The Baumol Research Centre for Entrepreneurship Studies at Zhejiang Gongshang University is named after William Baumol. [17]

In 2003, Baumol received the Global Award for Entrepreneurship Research [18] "[f]or his persistent effort to give the entrepreneur a key role in mainstream economic theory, for his theoretical and empirical studies of the nature of entrepreneurship, and for his analysis of the importance of institutions and incentives for the allocation of entrepreneurship." [19]

The British news magazine, The Economist published an article about William Baumol and his lifelong work to develop a place in economic theory for the entrepreneur (March 11, 2006, pp 68), much of which owes its genesis to Joseph Schumpeter. They note that traditional microeconomic theory normally holds a place for 'prices' and 'firms' but not for that (seemingly) important engine of innovation, the entrepreneur. Baumol is given credit for helping to remedy this shortcoming: "Thanks to Mr. Baumol's own painstaking efforts, economists now have a bit more room for entrepreneurs in their theories."

William Baumol's book, The Microtheory of Innovative Entrepreneurship [20] is the first formal theoretical analysis of the role of innovative entrepreneurs.

Textbooks

Baumol wrote several textbooks in economics, including an introductory textbook with Alan Blinder titled Macroeconomics: Principles and Policy. [21] His economics textbook on operations research was internationally well-received:[ citation needed ]

In the 1960s and 1970s, nearly every economics department offered a course in operations research methods in economics, and the usual textbook used was Economic Theory and Operations Analysis by W. J. Baumol. An entire generation of economics students was familiar with this book .... [22]

Professional and philanthropic interests

Baumol was a trustee of Economists for Peace and Security. Baumol was known for his interests in the economics of art, including the economics of the performing arts. [23]

Death

Baumol died on May 4, 2017 at the age of 95. [23] [24]

Major publications

Positions and awards

See also

Related Research Articles

John Hicks British economist

Sir John Hicks was a British economist. He is considered one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. The most familiar of his many contributions in the field of economics were his statement of consumer demand theory in microeconomics, and the IS–LM model (1937), which summarised a Keynesian view of macroeconomics. His book Value and Capital (1939) significantly extended general-equilibrium and value theory. The compensated demand function is named the Hicksian demand function in memory of him.

Frank Hyneman Knight was an American economist who spent most of his career at the University of Chicago, where he became one of the founders of the Chicago School. Nobel laureates Milton Friedman, George Stigler and James M. Buchanan were all students of Knight at Chicago. Ronald Coase said that Knight, without teaching him, was a major influence on his thinking. F.A. Hayek considered Knight to be one of the major figures in preserving and promoting classical liberal thought in the twentieth century. Paul Samuelson named Knight as one of the several "American saints in economics" born after 1860.

Oskar R. Lange Polish economist and diplomat

Oskar Ryszard Lange was a Polish economist and diplomat. He is best known for advocating the use of market pricing tools in socialist systems and providing a model of market socialism. He responded to the economic calculation problem proposed by Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek by claiming that managers in a centrally-planned economy would be able to monitor supply and demand through increases and declines in inventories of goods, and advocated the nationalization of major industries. During his stay in the United States, Lange was an academic teacher and researcher in mathematical economics. Later in socialist Poland, he was a member of the Central Committee of the Polish United Workers' Party.

Fernando Enrique Alvarez is an Argentine macroeconomist. He is professor of economics at the University of Chicago. He received his B.A. in Economics at Universidad Nacional de La Plata in 1989 and his Ph.D. from the University of Minnesota in 1994. He was elected a Fellow of the Econometric Society in 2008. He was named a Fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences in 2018.

Michio Morishima

Michio Morishima was a Japanese heterodox economist and public intellectual who was the Sir John Hicks Professor of Economics at the London School of Economics from 1970–88. He was also professor at Osaka University and member of the British Academy. In 1976 he won the Order of Culture.

Fritz Machlup

Fritz Machlup was an Austrian-American economist who was president of the International Economic Association from 1971–1974. He was one of the first economists to examine knowledge as an economic resource, and is credited with popularizing the concept of the information society.

Entrepreneurial economics is the study of the entrepreneur and entrepreneurship within the economy. The accumulation of factors of production per se does not explain economic development. They are necessary factors of production, but they are not sufficient for economic growth.

Lars Peter Hansen

Lars Peter Hansen is an American economist. He is the David Rockefeller Distinguished Service Professor of economics at the University of Chicago and a 2013 recipient of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics.

IZA Institute of Labor Economics

The IZA - Institute of Labor Economics, until 2016 referred to as the Institute of the Study of Labor (IZA), is a private, independent economic research institute and academic network focused on the analysis of global labor markets and headquartered in Bonn, Germany.

Evsey David Domar was a Russian American economist, famous as developer of the Harrod–Domar model.

Richard Blundell British economist

Sir Richard William Blundell CBE FBA is a British economist and econometrician.

Susan Athey American economist

Susan Carleton Athey is an American microeconomist. She is the Economics of Technology Professor in the School of Humanities and Sciences at the Stanford Graduate School of Business. Prior to joining Stanford, she has been a professor at Harvard University and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. She is the first female winner of the John Bates Clark Medal. She served as the consulting chief economist for Microsoft for six years and was a consulting researcher to Microsoft Research. She is currently on the boards of Expedia, Lending Club, Rover, Turo, Ripple, and non-profit Innovations for Poverty Action. She also serves as the senior fellow at Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research. She is an associate director for the Stanford Institute for Human-Centered Artificial Intelligence and the director of Golub Capital Social Impact Lab.

Roger Myerson American mathematician

Roger Bruce Myerson is an American economist and professor at the University of Chicago. He holds the title of the David L. Pearson Distinguished Service Professor of Global Conflict Studies at The Pearson Institute for the Study and Resolution of Global Conflicts in the Harris School of Public Policy, the Griffin Department of Economics, and the College. Previously, he held the title The Glen A. Lloyd Distinguished Service Professor of Economics. In 2007, he was the winner of the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel with Leonid Hurwicz and Eric Maskin for "having laid the foundations of mechanism design theory." He was elected a Member of the American Philosophical Society in 2019.

Paul David Klemperer FBA is an economist and the Edgeworth Professor of Economics at the Department of Economics, Oxford University. He is a member of the Klemperer family. He works on industrial economics, competition policy, auction theory, and climate change economics and policy.

Don Patinkin was an American-born Israeli monetary economist, and the President of the Hebrew University of Jerusalem.

In economics, non-convexity refers to violations of the convexity assumptions of elementary economics. Basic economics textbooks concentrate on consumers with convex preferences and convex budget sets and on producers with convex production sets; for convex models, the predicted economic behavior is well understood. When convexity assumptions are violated, then many of the good properties of competitive markets need not hold: Thus, non-convexity is associated with market failures, where supply and demand differ or where market equilibria can be inefficient. Non-convex economies are studied with nonsmooth analysis, which is a generalization of convex analysis.

Parag A. Pathak is Professor of Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology and is affiliated with the National Bureau of Economic Research where he co-founded and directs the working group on market design.

Fuhito Kojima is a Japanese economist and a professor at the University of Tokyo.

Dave Donaldson is a Canadian economist and a professor of economics at Massachusetts Institute of Technology. He was awarded the 2017 John Bates Clark Medal and elected fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences in 2020.

Stefanie Stantcheva is a French economist who is a professor of economics at Harvard University. She is a member of the French Council of Economic Analysis. Her research focuses on public finance—in particular questions of optimal taxation. In 2018, she was selected by The Economist as one of the 8 best young economists of the decade. In 2020, she was awarded the Elaine Bennett Research Prize.

References

  1. 1 2 Krueger, Alan (2001). "An Interview with William J. Baumol". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 15. pp. 211–231 [215]. doi:10.1257/jep.15.3.211.
  2. "Guide to the William J. Baumol Papers" . Retrieved February 3, 2013.
  3. "Book of Members, 1780–2010: Chapter B" (PDF). American Academy of Arts and Sciences. Retrieved May 28, 2011.
  4. "Nobel Prize Winners in Economics Profiles Index" . Retrieved February 3, 2013.
  5. "Thomson Reuters Predicts 2014 Nobel Laureates, Researchers Forecast for Nobel Recognition" . Retrieved April 13, 2016.
  6. 1 2 Cohen, Patricia (May 10, 2017). "William J. Baumol, 95, 'One of the Great Economists of His Generation,' Dies". The New York Times.
  7. Krueger, Alan (2001). "An Interview With William J Baumol" (PDF). Journal of Economic Perspectives. 15 (3): 211–231. doi: 10.1257/jep.15.3.211 .
  8. Krueger, Alan (2001). "An Interview with William J. Baumol". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 15. pp. 211–231 [214]. doi:10.1257/jep.15.3.211.
  9. Baumol, William J. (1959). "7" . Business Behavior, Value and Growth. New York: Macmillan.
  10. Baumol, W. J. (1972). "On Taxation and the Control of Externalities". American Economic Review. 62 (3): 307–322. JSTOR   1803378.
  11. Eliasson, Gunnar & Magnus Henrekson (2004). "William J. Baumol: An Entrepreneurial Economist on the Economics of Entrepreneurship". Small Business Economics. 23 (1): 1–7. doi:10.1023/b:sbej.0000026049.86377.df. S2CID   154386348 . Retrieved October 14, 2013.
  12. Baumol, William J.; Oates, Wallace E.; with contributions by V. S. Bawa and David F. Bradford (1988). "8 Detrimental externalities and nonconvexities in the production set". The Theory of environmental policy (Second ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. pp. x+299. doi:10.2277/0521311128. ISBN   978-0-521-31112-0.
  13. Guesnerie, Roger (1975). "Pareto optimality in non-convex economies". Econometrica. 43. pp. 1–29 [2]. doi:10.2307/1913410. JSTOR   1913410. MR   0443877. with Econometrica. 43 (5–6). 1975. p. 1010. doi:10.2307/1911353. JSTOR   1911353. MR   0443878.Missing or empty |title= (help)

    Page 73 (and for other contributions of Baumol pages 42, 68, and 155): Starrett, David A. (1988). Foundations of public economics. Cambridge economic handbooks. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN   978-0-521-34801-0.

    Non-convexities also appear in Baumol's theory of contestable markets: Pages 179–181: Salanié, Bernard (2000). Microeconomics of market failures (English translation of the (1998) French Microéconomie: Les défaillances du marché (Economica, Paris) ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. ISBN   978-0-262-19443-3.

    page 88: Laffont, Jean-Jacques (1988). "3 Nonconvexities" . Fundamentals of public economics. MIT. ISBN   978-0-262-12127-9.

  14. Malkiel, Burton (1986). "11". Chapter 11, William Baumol and the Development of the Field of Finance, in Prices, Competition and Equilibrium: Essays in Honour of William J Baumol. Oxford. ISBN   9780860030690.
  15. "Searching for the invisible man". The Economist. March 9, 2006. p. 67. Retrieved December 23, 2012.
  16. "Annual meeting allied social science associations". 2006 ASSA Conference. The American Economic Association. January 8, 2006. Retrieved August 5, 2011.
  17. Baumol Research Centre for Entrepreneurship Studies in ZJGSU
  18. Magnus Henrekson; Anders Lundstrom (2009). "The Global Award for Entrepreneurship Research" (PDF). Small Bus Econ. 32 (1): 1–14. doi: 10.1007/s11187-008-9141-y . S2CID   10265169.
  19. "2003 Award Winner William J. Baumol". Global Award for Entrepreneurship Research. May 2003. Retrieved August 5, 2011.
  20. The Microtheory of Innovative Entrepreneurship. Princeton University Press. May 2010. ISBN   9780691145846.
  21. "Macroeconomics: Principles and Policy". Cengage. 2012.
  22. Thompson, Gerald L.; Thore, Sten (1992). Computational Economics: Economic Modeling with Optimization Software. South San Francisco, California: Scientific Press. pp. xii+352 [vii]. ISBN   0894262017.
  23. 1 2 Timothy B. Lee (May 4, 2017). "William Baumol, whose famous economic theory explains the modern world, has died". Vox . Retrieved May 4, 2017.
  24. https://www.washingtonpost.com/national/william-baumol-economist-who-found-logic-in-rising-health-care-prices-dies-at-95/2017/05/05/25439850-3108-11e7-9534-00e4656c22aa_story.html