Tournament theory

Last updated

Tournament theory is the theory in personnel economics used to describe certain situations where wage differences are based not on marginal productivity but instead upon relative differences between the individuals. [1] This theory was invented by economists Edward Lazear and Sherwin Rosen. [2]

Contents

The theory has been applied to professional sports and to the practice of law. Tournament theory also was applied to writing - one writer may be fractionally better at writing than another (and therefore have a better book), but because people allocate small amounts of time to reading, the writer with the marginally better book will sell far more copies.

Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimum Labour Contracts

Lazear and Rosen proposed tournament theory in their 1981 paper Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimum Labor Contracts , looking at performance related pay. Under conventional systems workers are paid a piece rate - an amount of money that relates to their output, rather than the time they input. Tournament theory suggests that workers can be rewarded by their rank in an organization, suggesting why large salaries are given to senior executives: to provide a 'prize' to those who put in enough effort to garner one of the top positions.

The paper invites the reader to consider the lifetime output of a worker at a firm. This output is dictated by two things - chance and skill. The worker can control his lifetime output by investing in skills early on in life, like studying hard at school and getting good qualifications, but a part of that output will be determined by chance. Participants in the tournament commit their investment early on in life and are unlikely to know each other previously, within the firm they work in, and may not even know each other within the firm. This prevents collusion or cheating in the tournament.

Looking at the tournament in its simplest form, a two player tournament, where there is a prize for the winner and a smaller consolation for the loser. The incentive to win increases as the difference between the losing and winning prize increases, and therefore the investment of the worker is increased as the difference between the winning and losing prizes is increased. It is in the interest of the firm to increase the spread of prizes. However there is a drawback for the firms. As the workers invest more their costs rise. Competing firms could offer a tournament with a lower spread and attract more workers because they would have to invest less. Therefore, there is an optimal prize spread that firms set, high enough to induce investment but low enough so that the investment is not too expensive for the worker. The prize may take the form of extra cash or a promotion - which means more money, as well as entering a higher level of tournament, where the stakes may be higher.

The idea that the prize may be in the form of a promotion explains why presidents are paid significantly more than vice presidents. In one day a Vice-President may be promoted to President of a company and have his pay tripled. Considering piece rates this seems illogical - his output is unlikely to have tripled in one day. But looking at it using tournament theory it seems logical - he has won the tournament and received his prize - presidency.

Tournament theory is an efficient way of labour compensation when quantifying output is difficult or expensive, but ranking workers is easy. It is also effective as it provides goals for workers and incentivises hard work so that they may one day attain one of the coveted positions at the top. An advantage to workers over a piece rate would be that in the event of a natural disaster they would preserve their wage as their output would go down in absolute terms but stay the same relative to their colleagues. This means that in times of disaster workers could maintain their wage.

[2] Benefits of tournament (+) Motivates workers (+) Offers stability during volatile market conditions (reduce shocks) (+) Selecting workers (observe) (+) Reduce variability in pay (commit & credible) (+) Encourage Long-run behaviour to stay

Foundational Principles

There are two foundational predictions of tournament theory. These predictions can be illustrated by examining a simple two-player contest with identical risk-neutral actors. [3] Let performance (output) be measured by :

Here, represents the effort or investment by a player, while is a random component (e.g. luck or noise). Players are rewarded for performance with one of two prizes, or , where . goes to the player with better performance, while goes to the player with worse performance. Each player's actions have a cost associated, denoted by . The probability that player wins is positively related to that player's action and negatively related to the opponent player's action , as well as the random component . If is the probability of winning, then the contestant can receive the following payoff:

When player chooses to maximise his/her payoff, then:

In a two-player tournament the Nash equilibrium occurs when both players maximise their payoff while assuming the other player's effort is fixed. At this equilibrium the marginal cost of effort is equal to the marginal value of effort , such that:

From this equation, two principles can be derived. The first is that an actor's level of effort increases with the spread between the winning and losing prize. [4] The second is that only the difference between the winning and the losing prize matters to the two contestants, not the absolute size of their winnings. [5] These two testable predictions of tournament theory have been supported by empirical research over the years, especially in the fields of labour economics [6] and sports. [7]

Pros and Cons of Workplace Tournaments

Incentivizing Performance

Tournaments can be very powerful at incentivising performance. Empirical research in economics and managements have shown that tournament-like incentive structure increases the individual performance or workers and managers in the workplace. [8] The distribution of effort for one tournament experiment found that almost 80% of participants exert higher than anticipated levels of efforts, thus suggesting that tournaments provides strong competition incentives. [9] Tournaments also provide powerful non-monetary incentives. Studies show that participants in tournaments value winning itself and placing highly on relative rankings. [10] One experiment found that more than 40% of individuals were willing to exert positive effort with a monetary incentive of $0. [11]

Matching workers and jobs

Tournaments play an important function in matching workers with jobs that are relevant/appropriate. The theoretical prediction in the literature is that higher-skilled individuals would be sorted into jobs that offer higher potential returns. [12] This is well-supported by empirical data. For instance, in the field of competitive running more accomplished competitors with greater capabilities are more likely to choose tournaments with greater prize spreads. [13]

Inequalities in the workplace

Tournaments have the potential to create large inequalities in payoffs. Incentive based tournaments are organised in such a way that some winners are created at the expense of many losers. [14] Thus, by design there are likely to be high inequalities in payoffs in the workplace under a tournament structure. A further potential inequality is gender inequality in the workplace. Field studies have shown that women are less likely to enter tournaments than men and also do not perform as well. [15] Thus, even in cases where women may be more capable or better skilled, tournament-like incentives may discourage women from participating. [16]

Selfish and Unethical Behaviour

A major issue with tournaments is that individuals are incentivised to view others as competitors, thus encouraging selfish behaviour. This means that participants in a tournament structured workplace would be less likely to help each other and are discouraged from knowledge sharing more so than in other incentive schemes. [17] Through such increased opportunistic and selfish behavior, firms with tournament structures and large inequalities in payoffs may harm their customer relationships. [18] Further, tournaments may also encourage unethical behaviour in participants such as cheating or collusion in competitive sports or plagiarism in the academic field. [19]

See also

Notes

  1. • Tor Eriksson, 2009. "tournaments," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online Edition, Abstract.
       • Edward Lazear, 2008. "personnel economics," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition, v. 6, pp. 380-84. Abstract.
  2. 1 2 Edward P. Lazear and Sherwin Rosen, 1981. "Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimum Labor Contracts," Journal of Political Economy, 89(5), pp. 841-864.
  3. Charles R. Knoeber and Walter N. Thurman, 'Testing the Theory of Tournaments: An Empirical Analysis of Broiler Production' (1994) 12(2) Journal of Labor Economics 155, 156-7; Brian L. Connelly et al, 'Tournament Theory: Thirty Years of Contests and Competitions' 40(1) Journal of Management 16, 19-20.
  4. Brian L. Connelly et al, 'Tournament Theory: Thirty Years of Contests and Competitions' 40(1) Journal of Management 16, 20.
  5. Charles R. Knoeber and Walter N. Thurman, 'Testing the Theory of Tournaments: An Empirical Analysis of Broiler Production' (1994) 12(2) Journal of Labor Economics 155, 157.
  6. Andrew Schotter and Keither Weigelt, 'Asymmetric Tournaments, Equal Opportunity Laws, and Affirmative Action: Some Experimental Results' (1992) 107(2) The Quarterly Journal of Economics 511.
  7. Ronald G. Ehrenberg and Michael Bognanna, 'The Incentive Effects of Tournaments Revisited: Evidence from the European PGA Tour' (1990) 43(3) Industrial and Labor Relations Review 74S.
  8. Sheremeta, Roman M. (2016). "The pros and cons of workplace tournaments". IZA World of Labor. doi: 10.15185/izawol.302 . Retrieved 28 October 2020.
  9. Roman M. Sheremeta., 'Impulsive Behavior in Competition: Testing Theories of Overbidding in Rent-seeking Contests' (Working Paper, 2016) [6]
  10. Sheremeta, Roman M. (2016). "The pros and cons of workplace tournaments". IZA World of Labor. doi: 10.15185/izawol.302 . Retrieved 28 October 2020.
  11. Roman M. Sheremeta, 'Experimental comparison of multi-stage and one-stage contests' (2010) 68 Games and Economic Behavior731−747
  12. Sheremeta, Roman M. (2016). "The pros and cons of workplace tournaments". IZA World of Labor. doi: 10.15185/izawol.302 . Retrieved 28 October 2020.
  13. Sheremeta, Roman M. (2016). "The pros and cons of workplace tournaments". IZA World of Labor. doi: 10.15185/izawol.302 . Retrieved 28 October 2020.
  14. Frank, R., and P. Cook. The Winner-Take-All Society. New York: The Free Press, 1996.
  15. Niederle, M., and L. Vesterlund. “Do women shy away from competition? Do men compete too much?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 122 (2007): 1067−1101.
  16. Dechenaux, E., D. Kovenock, and R. M. Sheremeta. “A survey of experimental research on contests, all-pay auctions and tournaments.” Experimental Economics 18 (2015): 609−669.
  17. Drago, R., and G. T. Garvey. “Incentives for helping on the job: Theory and evidence.” Journal of Labor Economics 16 (1998): 1−25.
  18. Bamberger, Boas; Homburg, Christian; Wielgos, Dominik M. (2021). "Wage Inequality: Its Impact on Customer Satisfaction and Firm Performance". Journal of Marketing. 85 (6): 24–43. doi: 10.1177/00222429211026655 .
  19. Sheremeta, Roman M. (2016). "The pros and cons of workplace tournaments". IZA World of Labor. doi: 10.15185/izawol.302 . Retrieved 28 October 2020.

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Labour economics</span> Study of the markets for wage labour

Labour economics, or labor economics, seeks to understand the functioning and dynamics of the markets for wage labour. Labour is a commodity that is supplied by labourers, usually in exchange for a wage paid by demanding firms. Because these labourers exist as parts of a social, institutional, or political system, labour economics must also account for social, cultural and political variables.

From a legal point of view, a contract is an institutional arrangement for the way in which resources flow, which defines the various relationships between the parties to a transaction or limits the rights and obligations of the parties.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Incentive</span> Something that motivates individuals to perform

In general, incentives are anything that persuade a person to alter their behaviour in the desired manner. It is emphasised that incentives matter by the basic law of economists and the laws of behaviour, which state that higher incentives amount to greater levels of effort and therefore higher levels of performance.

Managerial economics is a branch of economics involving the application of economic methods in the organizational decision-making process. Economics is the study of the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. Managerial economics involves the use of economic theories and principles to make decisions regarding the allocation of scarce resources. It guides managers in making decisions relating to the company's customers, competitors, suppliers, and internal operations.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Principal–agent problem</span> Conflict of interest when one agent makes decisions on anothers behalf

The principal–agent problem refers to the conflict in interests and priorities that arises when one person or entity takes actions on behalf of another person or entity. The problem worsens when there is a greater discrepancy of interests and information between the principal and agent, as well as when the principal lacks the means to punish the agent. The deviation from the principal's interest by the agent is called "agency costs".


The term efficiency wages was introduced by Alfred Marshall to denote the wage per efficiency unit of labor. Marshallian efficiency wages are those calculated with efficiency or ability exerted being the unit of measure rather than time. That is, the more efficient worker will be paid more than a less efficient worker for the same amount of hours worked.

In mathematics, a function

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Signaling game</span> Game class in game theory

In game theory, a signaling game is a simple type of a dynamic Bayesian game.

Personnel economics has been defined as "the application of economic and mathematical approaches and econometric and statistical methods to traditional questions in human resources management". It is an area of applied micro labor economics, but there are a few key distinctions. One distinction, not always clearcut, is that studies in personnel economics deal with the personnel management within firms, and thus internal labor markets, while those in labor economics deal with labor markets as such, whether external or internal. In addition, personnel economics deals with issues related to both managerial-supervisory and non-supervisory workers.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Edward Lazear</span> American economist and academic (1948–2020)

Edward Paul Lazear was an American economist, the Morris Arnold and Nona Jean Cox Senior Fellow at the Hoover Institution at Stanford University and the Davies Family Professor of Economics at Stanford Graduate School of Business.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Richard Blundell</span> British economist

Sir Richard William Blundell CBE FBA is a British economist and econometrician.

Employment protection legislation (EPL) includes all types of employment protection measures, whether grounded primarily in legislation, court rulings, collectively bargained conditions of employment, or customary practice. The term is common among circles of economists. Employment protection refers both to regulations concerning hiring and firing.

In microeconomics, search theory studies buyers or sellers who cannot instantly find a trading partner, and must therefore search for a partner prior to transacting. It involves determining the best approach to use when looking for a specific item or person in a sizable, uncharted environment. The goal of the theory is to determine the best search strategy, one that maximises the chance of finding the target while minimising search-related expenses.

David Neumark is an American economist and a Chancellor's Professor of Economics at the University of California, Irvine, where he also directs the Economic Self-Sufficiency Policy Research Institute.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Armin Falk</span> German economist (born 1968)

Armin Falk is a German economist. He has held a chair at the University of Bonn since 2003.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">David Autor</span> American economist

David H. Autor is an American economist, public policy scholar, and professor of economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT), where he also acts as co-director of the School Effectiveness and Inequality Initiative. Although Autor has contributed to a variety of fields in economics his research generally focuses on topics from labor economics.

Gary Sheldon Fields is an American economist, the John P. Windmuller Professor of International and Comparative Labor and Professor of Economics at Cornell University. Fields has performed extensive research in labor economics and development economics, in particular labor mobility, which was rewarded with the IZA Prize in Labor Economics in 2014.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Oriana Bandiera</span> Italian economist

Oriana Bandiera, FBA is an Italian economist and academic, specialising in development economics. She has been Professor of Economics at the London School of Economics since 2009. She is currently the Sir Anthony Atkinson Professor of Economics at the London School of Economics, and co-editor of Econometrica. Her area of study primarily concerns organizations and labor markets, and their relationship with the process of economic development.

Patrick McGraw Kline is an U.S. American economist and Professor of Economics of the University of California at Berkeley. In 2018, his research was awarded the Sherwin Rosen Prize by the Society of Labor Economists for "outstanding contributions in the field of labor economics". In 2020, he was awarded the prestigious IZA Young Labor Economist Award.

The gift-exchange game, also commonly known as the gift exchange dilemma, is a common economic game introduced by George Akerlof and Janet Yellen to model reciprocacy in labor relations. The gift-exchange game simulates a labor-management relationship execution problem in the principal-agent problem in labor economics. The simplest form of the game involves two players – an employee and an employer. The employer first decides whether they should award a higher salary to the employee. The employee then decides whether to reciprocate with a higher level of effort due to the salary increase or not. Like trust games, gift-exchange games are used to study reciprocity for human subject research in social psychology and economics. If the employer pays extra salary and the employee puts in extra effort, then both players are better off than otherwise. The relationship between an investor and an investee has been investigated as the same type of a game.

References

Chronological order: