Comparison of the Hare and Droop quotas

Last updated

In elections that use the single transferable vote (STV) method, quotas are used (a) for the determination of candidates considered elected; and (b) for the calculation of surplus votes to be redistributed. [1] Two quotas in common use are the Hare quota and the Droop quota. The largest remainder method of party-list proportional representation can also use Hare quotas or Droop quotas.

Contents

Under most STV systems it is possible to be elected by less than quota (at the end when the field of candidates is thinned to the number of remaining open seats) if not every ballot ranks all candidates, but the quota used (whether Hare or Droop) is the amount that guarantees election. A particular type of STV uses a "uniform quota" where anyone who exceeds that quota is elected. New York City used such a system during its use of STV in city elections. Its set quota was 75,000 and each borough got a number of members that depended on the voter turnout in the borough. One problem with the system was that the size of the city council varied from election to election depending on the voter turnout. (1.7M votes were cast and generally 20 to 27 councillors were elected.) [2]

The quota sets the number of surplus votes held by elected candidates. For fairness it is important that the number of votes held by the early successful candidate after surplus votes are transferred away is not surpassed later by another candidate who is unable to take a seat as they are already filled. That is the reason why the quota needs to be set at a point high enough to prevent more candidates achieving it than the total number of seats. [3]

General comparison

The earliest versions of STV used the Hare quota. The Hare quota is equal to the total valid poll (V) divided by the total number of seats (n), or V / n. The use of the Hare implies either there will not be any exhausted votes or one or more candidates must win with less than quota.

The Droop quota is smaller than the Hare quota, and was first suggested [4] because it is the smallest quota that ensures that the number of candidates who reach the quota will not be greater than the number of seats to be filled. The Hare quota also does this but is larger than it absolutely needs to be. Any quota smaller than the Droop quota carries a real, or at least theoretical, risk of more candidates being eligible for election than there are seats to be filled. The Droop quota is the next integer larger than V / (n+1) or a number just fractionally larger than V / (n+1), depending on the STV variant used.

In a ranked-vote election in which there is only one seat to be filled (in other words an Instant Run-off Voting election) it is possible to use the Hare quota, which will simply be equal to 100% of votes cast. However, likely no candidate will take the Hare quota (due to exhausted votes) and such a target would necessitate vote transfers from eliminated candidates perhaps long after a candidate has a majority of the votes. it is more efficient to use the Droop quota, which will be equal to a simple majority of votes cast, meaning 50% plus one (one more than votes/(seats plus 1)). In single-winner elections, receiving a majority of the votes is considered to be a satisfactory marker of rightful success, and either Hare or Droop would achieve that result.

Election systems that use quota produce what is thought to be more fair results, where the elected member(s) represent the majority of votes cast, whether with a single winner or multiple winners. Systems that do not use quotas do not ensure such fairness - often under First-past-the-post voting and the Single non-transferable vote system the elected candidate(s) do not reflect the majority of votes cast.

In an STV election, where there are multiple winners, quota, not plurality, is used because it ensures that most successful candidates are elected with the same number of votes. If they receive surplus votes above the quota, the surplus votes are re-allocated, if possible. This equality ensure that a high proportion of votes cast are used effectively to elect someone, which in turn ensures that each party receives its due proportion of the seats.

Being of different sizes, the Hare and Droop quota produce different results in some situations.

The Droop quota is today the most popular quota for STV elections – and almost universal for government STV elections – for two reasons.[ citation needed ] First, because it produces more proportional results for large parties and for small parties (although small parties as a whole are denied the over-representation produced by use of the Hare quota). Second, because a majority of votes in a group are more likely to fill a majority of the seats. The possibility under the Hare quota for a group of candidates supported by a majority of voters to receive only a minority of seats is considered undemocratic.[ citation needed ]

Examples of the different outcomes between the Hare and the Droop quotas follow:

Scenario 1

An example of an STV election where compared to the result under Hare, the result under the Droop quota would more closely reflect the support that voters have for a party, irrespective of the support they have for individuals within the party.

Imagine an election in which there are 5 seats to be filled. There are 6 candidates divided between two groups: Andrea, Carter and Brad are members of the Alpha party; Delilah, Scott and Jennifer are members of the Beta party. There are 120 voters and they vote as follows:

Alpha partyBeta party
Slate
  1. Andrea
  2. Carter
  3. Brad
  1. Carter
  2. Andrea
  3. Brad
  1. Brad
  2. Andrea
  3. Carter
  1. Delilah
  2. Scott
  3. Jennifer
  1. Scott
  2. Delilah
  3. Jennifer
  1. Jennifer
  2. Delilah
  3. Scott
Voters31302201918

Voters are voting for full slates. Supporters of the Alpha party all rank all three Alpha party candidates higher than any of the Beta party candidates. Similarly, voters who support the Beta party all give their first three preferences to Beta party candidates. The voters may not have indicated 4th, 5th and 6th preferences, but if they did or had to due to electoral rules, they are not shown above because they will not affect the result of the election.

Overall, the Alpha party receives 63 votes out of a total of 120 votes. The Alpha party therefore has a majority of about 53%. The Beta party receives a 47% share of the vote. The party's vote tally is spread over the party's three candidates.


Below the election results are shown first under the Hare quota and then under the Droop quota. It can be seen that under the Hare quota, despite receiving 53% of the vote, the Alpha party receives only a minority of seats. (This is caused by hare being so large that two Alpha party winners take up so many votes that not enough are left over for a third Alpha candidate to avoid being eliminated as least-popular candidate. A less-even distribution of votes among the Beta party candidates might have saved Brad from this outcome.)

When the same election is conducted under the Droop quota, however, the Alpha party's majority is rewarded with a majority of seats. (More of the Alpha party winners' votes are seen as surplus and distributed. Brad receives the transfers and they give him quota, letting him win a seat.)

Count under the Hare quota

The Hare quota is calculated as 120/5 = 24.

  1. When first preferences are tallied Andrea and Carter have both reached a quota and are declared elected.
  2. Andrea has a surplus of 7 and Carter has a surplus of 6. Both surpluses are transferred to Brad (the next relevant preference indicated on the ballots) so the tallies become:
    • Brad (Alpha party): 15
    • Delilah (Beta party): 20
    • Scott (Beta party): 19
    • Jennifer (Beta party): 18
  3. No candidate has reached a quota. There are just four candidates remaining and there are only three more seats to be filled. Brad is the candidate with the fewest votes and so he is declared defeated. Only Delilah, Scott and Jennifer remain and they are all declared elected.

Result: The elected candidates are: Andrea and Carter (from the Alpha party), and Delilah, Scott and Jennifer (from the Beta party).

Count under the Droop quota

The Droop quota is calculated as 21 (the next number higher than 120/6).

  1. When first preferences are tallied Andrea and Carter have reached the quota and, as before, are declared elected.
  2. Andrea has a surplus of 10 and Carter a surplus of 9. These surpluses transfer to Brad and the tallies become:
    • Brad (Alpha party): 21
    • Delilah (Beta party): 20
    • Scott (Beta party): 19
    • Jennifer (Beta party): 18
  3. Brad has now reached a quota and is declared elected.
  4. Brad has no surplus so no vote transfer is needed to deal with that. Three candidates remain and two seats remain open. Jennifer, who has the fewest votes, is declared defeated. Delilah and Scott are left in the count, and there are only two seats left to fill, they are both declared elected.

Result: The elected candidates are Andrea, Carter and Brad (from the Alpha party) and Delilah and Scott (from the Beta party). Thus the party with the majority of votes receives a majority of seats.

Scenario 2

An example with a closed list using the largest remainder method.

Imagine an election in which there are 3 seats to be filled. There are 5 candidates divided between 3 groups: Alex, Bobbie and Chris are members of the Alpha party; Jo is candidate for the Beta party; and Kim is candidate for the Gamma party.

There are 99 voters and they vote as follows:

Hare quota scenario 2.jpg
Alpha partyBeta partyGamma party
Slate
  1. Alex
  2. Bobbie
  3. Chris
  1. Jo
  1. Kim
Voters502524

Count under the Hare quota

  1. The Hare quota is calculated as 33.
  2. When votes are tallied Alpha party has more than one full quota so the first candidate on its list, Alex, is declared elected. Alpha party still has 17 not used.
    • Alpha Party (Bobbie and Chris) : 17
    • Beta Party (Jo): 25
    • Gamma Party (Kim): 24
  3. No other candidate has reached the quota. Alpha is the party with the fewest votes and so its remaining candidates (Bobbie and Chris) are excluded. Because just two parties remain and there are only two more seats to be filled, the first (or only) candidate on the party list for each of those two parties, Jo and Kim, are declared elected.

Result: The elected candidates are: Alex (from the Alpha party), Jo (from the Beta party), and Kim (from the Gamma party). The Alpha party won a slight majority of votes but did not win a majority of seats. Taking one more seat would have given it a large amount of over-representation, which would have made the final result more dis-proportional than the equal distribution of seats to the three parties.

Count under the Droop quota

  1. The Droop quota is calculated as 25.
  2. When first preferences are tallied, Alpha party has two full quotas so Alex and Bobbie are declared elected, and Beta party has one full quota so Jo is declared elected.
  3. With three candidates elected there are no more seats to fill.

Result: The elected candidates are Alex and Bobbie (from the Alpha party) and Jo (from the Beta party). The Gamma party is excluded from representation despite getting 24% of the votes. (This is an unusual case where one party did not have any un-used votes, and one party came up just one vote short of a full quota)

Scenario 3

October 2012 City of Melbourne, Australia municipal election

As a real life example of the implementation of the two quota systems and the impact it has on the outcome of the election results, we will re-run the Melbourne eleciton as if it was conducted using largest remainder method (LRM).

The City of Melbourne council elections were held in October 2012, under the rules of STV, using the Droop quota, with 9 vacancies to be elected from 40 candidates representing 11 teams plus three independents. The system of vote counting was STV with a Gregory-style method used for transfer of surplus votes. [5]

For 9 seats, the Droop quota was 10% of votes, whilst the Hare quota would have been 11.11%. 63,674 votes were cast, so the Droop quota was 6,368, and the Hare quota would have been 7,075. The following table shows the percentage of first-preference votes received by each party's slate of candidates as a whole and the number of quotas this represents, under each quota, as if the largest-remainder system was in use. To calculate the final result under STV, back-up preferences must be taken into account as well. (They sometimes cross party lines.)

First-preference votes
TeamNo. of votesVote %Droop quotasHare quotas
Our Melbourne39536.21%0.620.56
Stephen Mayne38286.01%0.600.54
Residents First: Stop the Rates Rip-off!19293.03%0.300.27
Shanahan Chamberlin for Melbourne36865.79%0.580.52
Community and Business Leadership12671.99%0.200.18
Forward Together5280.83%0.080.07
The Greens994215.61%1.561.41
Team Doyle2386437.48%3.753.37
Morgan Elliott – Prosperity for Liveability61149.60%0.960.86
Gary Singer – John So Melbourne Living831413.06%1.311.18
Ungrouped2490.39%0.040.04
Total formal63674100.00%10.009.00

Winning candidates (in the order of their winning in real life through STV in 2012):

Team2012 Droop quota STV resultHare quota result (LRM)Droop quota result (LRM)
Team DoyleLouey, KevinLouey, KevinLouey, Kevin
The GreensOke, CathyOke, CathyOke, Cathy
Gary Singer – John So Melbourne LivingOng, KenOng, KenOng, Ken
Team DoyleWood, ArronWood, ArronWood, Arron
Team DoylePinder-Mortimer, BeverleyPinder-Mortimer, BeverleyPinder-Mortimer, Beverley
Morgan Elliott – Prosperity for LiveabilityWatts, JackieWatts, JackieWatts, Jackie
Our MelbourneFoster, RichardFoster, RichardFoster, Richard
Stephen MayneMayne, StephenMayne, StephenMayne, Stephen
Shanahan Chamberlin for MelbourneChamberlin, Kevin
The GreensLeppert, Rohan
Team DoyleJetter, Carl

Five seats are allocated based on full quotas (3 Team Doyle, Gary Singer, Green) under both Hare and Droop. Three of the remaining seats, filled through vote transfers under STV or by largest remainders, are filled the same under both Droop and Hare.

One seat switches from Greens to Shanahan Chamberlin if Hare is used in largest remainder method versus STV.

Team Doyle (headed by Melbourne Lord Mayor Robert Doyle) received 37.5% of first-preference votes. Under Hare quota, they would elect three representatives, comprising 33.3% of the seats. Its remainder is not enough to give it a fourth seat under Hare but under Droop, the .75 quota left over is larger than almost every other fraction. so under Droop, it would take four seats.

The Greens, who received 15.1% of first-preference votes, elect two under STV but only one representative under largest remainder method, if either Droop quota or the Hare quota is used.

Kevin Chamberlin, who received 5.8% of votes, would have been elected if Hare LRM was used. Shanahan Chamberlin for Melbourne did not have enough first-preference votes to make quota under either system. But its fraction is enough to elect one candidate under Hare but not under Droop. (Under Droop, Team Doyle takes four seats, denying the seat to Chamberlin.)

Under the largest-remainder system, votes left over after full quotas fill seats may result in the winning of an additional seat. Seats are filled by comparing fractions and declaring elected the larger until seats are filled.) (This reflects how votes are transferred from a successful candidate to other candidates of the same party slate under STV.)

Under STV, under the Droop quota, the second Green candidate (Rohan Leppert) accumulated enough votes from transfers to win a seat, over either the first Chamberlin candidate or the fourth Doyle candidate. And so the Green party took a second seat under STV. [6]

But under the largest remainder method (with no transfers), using Droop, Team Doyle had enough votes to win a fourth seat.

The Hare quota requires a larger number of votes to elect a member, so reduces the number of votes available for the fourth Doyle member, putting Kevin Chamberlin ahead.

For awarding the final seat, the Droop quota is more favorable to the larger Team Doyle party, while the Hare quota is more favorable to the less-popular Shanahan Chamberlin slate. The Greens benefited from vote transfers when STV was used so took a second seat under STV. In addition, though, we see that the Hare quota, being larger than Droop, put the winning of a seat even farther out of reach for Residents First, Forward Together and other small parties.

Notes

  1. Hill, I.D. (1987). "Algorithm 123 — Single Transferable Vote by Meek’s method".
  2. "Proportional Representation in New York City, 1936-1947".
  3. Harris, Practical Working of Proportional Representation (1930) https://babel.hathitrust.org/cgi/pt?id=mdp.39015030803426&view=1up&seq=7
  4. Henry Richmond Droop, "On methods of electing representatives" in the Journal of the Statistical Society of London Vol. 44 No. 2 (June 1881) pp.141-196 [Discussion, 197-202], reprinted in Voting matters Issue 24 (October 2007) pp.7–46.
  5. "2012 council election results". Victorian Electoral Commission. Archived from the original on 2023-03-22. Retrieved 17 April 2023. Follow the link on this page to "Melbourne City Council". Archived 17 April 2023 at the Wayback Machine . For detailed results, follow the link on the previous page to the "Distribution Report" (Microsoft Excel spreadsheet), 28 October 2012. Archived 17 April 2023 at the Wayback Machine
  6. Victorian Electoral Commission https://www.vec.vic.gov.au/results/general/MelbourneCouncillors2012.xls . Retrieved 18 May 2015.{{cite web}}: Missing or empty |title= (help)

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Proportional representation</span> Voting system that makes outcomes proportional to vote totals

Proportional representation (PR) refers to any type of electoral system under which subgroups of an electorate are reflected proportionately in the elected body. The concept applies mainly to political divisions among voters. The essence of such systems is that all votes cast – or almost all votes cast – contribute to the result and are effectively used to help elect someone – not just a bare plurality or (exclusively) the majority – and that the system produces mixed, balanced representation reflecting how votes are cast.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Single transferable vote</span> Multi-winner electoral system

The single transferable vote (STV), sometimes known as proportional ranked choice voting (P-RCV), is a multi-winner electoral system in which each voter casts a single vote in the form of a ranked-choice ballot. Voters have the option to rank candidates, and their vote may be transferred according to alternate preferences if their preferred candidate is eliminated or elected with surplus votes, so that their vote is used to elect someone they prefer over others in the running. STV aims to approach proportional representation based on votes cast in the district where it is used, so that each vote is worth about the same as another.

Single non-transferable vote or SNTV is an electoral system used to elect multiple winners. It is a generalization of first-past-the-post, applied to multi-member districts with each voter casting just one vote. Unlike FPTP, which is a single-winner system, in SNTV multiple winners are elected, typically in electoral districts; additionally, unlike FPTP, SNTV produces mixed representation and makes it unlikely for a single party to take all the seats in a city or a set area, which can happen under FPTP.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Voting</span> Method to make collective decisions

Voting is a method by which a group, such as a meeting or an electorate, convenes together for the purpose of making a collective decision or expressing an opinion usually following discussions, debates or election campaigns. Democracies elect holders of high office by voting. Residents of a jurisdiction represented by an elected official are called "constituents", and the constituents who choose to cast a ballot for their chosen candidate are called "voters." There are different systems for collecting votes, but while many of the systems used in decision-making can also be used as electoral systems, any which cater to proportional representation can only be used in elections.

In the study of electoral systems, the Droop quota is the minimum number of votes needed for a party or candidate to guarantee they will win at least one seat in a legislature.

The Imperiali quota or pseudoquota is an inadmissible electoral quota used to calculate the number of votes needed to earn a seat in single transferable vote or largest remainder elections. It is named after Belgian senator Pierre Imperiali.

In the study of apportionment, the Harequota is the number of voters represented by each legislator under a system of proportional representation. In these voting systems, the quota is the number of votes that guarantees a candidate, or a party in some cases, captures a seat. The Hare quota is the total number of votes divided by the number of seats to be filled.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">1926 Alberta general election</span>

The 1926 Alberta general election was held on June 28, 1926, to elect members of the Legislative Assembly of Alberta. The United Farmers of Alberta government that had first been elected in 1921 was re-elected, taking a majority of the seats in the Alberta Legislature. Herbert Greenfield had resigned as United Farmers leader and premier, and John E. Brownlee led the UFA to this second election victory, increasing the UFA's number of seats.

BC-STV is the proposed voting system recommended by the Citizens' Assembly on Electoral Reform in October 2004 for use in British Columbia, and belongs to the single transferable vote family of voting systems. BC-STV was supported by a majority of the voters in a referendum held in 2005 but the government had legislated that it would not be bound by any vote lower than 60 percent in favour. Because of the strong majority support for BC-STV, the government elected to stage a second referendum in 2009, but with increased public funding for information campaigns to better inform the electorate about the differences between the existing and proposed systems. The leadership of both the "yes" side and the "no" side were assigned by the government. The proposal was rejected with 60.9 percent voting against, vs. 39.1 percent in favour, in the 2009 vote.

The single transferable vote (STV) is a semi-proportional representation system that elects multiple winners. It is one of several ways of choosing winners from ballots that rank candidates by preference. Under STV, an elector's vote is initially allocated to their first-ranked candidate. Candidates are elected (winners) if their vote tally reaches quota. After this first count, if seats are still open, surplus votes—those in excess of an electoral quota—are transferred from winners to the remaining candidates (hopefuls) according to the surplus ballots' next usable back-up preference.

The Edmonton provincial electoral district also known as Edmonton City from 1905 to 1909, was a provincial electoral district in Alberta, Canada mandated to return members to the Legislative Assembly of Alberta from 1905 to 1917 and again from 1921 to 1959.

CPO-STV, or the Comparison of Pairs of Outcomes by the Single Transferable Vote, is a ranked voting system designed to achieve proportional representation. It is a more sophisticated variant of the Single Transferable Vote (STV) system, designed to overcome some of that system's perceived shortcomings. It does this by incorporating some of the features of Condorcet's method, a voting system designed for single-winner elections, into STV. As in other forms of STV, in a CPO-STV election more than one candidate is elected and voters must rank candidates in order of preference. As of February 2021, it has not been used for a public election.

Historically, the single transferable vote (STV) electoral system has seen a series of relatively modest periods of usage and disusage throughout the world; however, today it is seeing increasing popularity and proposed implementation as a method of proportional representation and a goal of electoral reform. STV has been used in many different local, regional and national electoral systems, as well as in various other types of bodies, around the world.

There are a number of complications and issues surrounding the application and use of single transferable vote proportional representation that form the basis of discussions between its advocates and detractors.

The 1923 municipal election was held December 10, 1923 to elect a mayor and six aldermen to sit on Edmonton City Council and four trustees to sit on the public school board. Robert Crossland, Paul Jenvrin, Thomas Magee, and Joseph Henri Picard were acclaimed to two-year terms on the separate school board.

In proportional representation systems, an electoral quota is the number of votes a candidate needs to be guaranteed election.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Wright system</span> Single transferable vote counting rule

The Wright system is a refinement of rules associated with proportional representation by means of the single transferable vote (PR-STV) electoral system. It was developed and written by Anthony van der Craats, a system analyst and life member of the Proportional Representation Society of Australia. It is described in a submission into a parliamentary review of the 2007 Australian federal election.

Schulze STV is a draft single transferable vote (STV) ranked voting system designed to achieve proportional representation. It was invented by Markus Schulze, who developed the Schulze method for resolving ties using a Condorcet method. Schulze STV is similar to CPO-STV in that it compares possible winning candidate pairs and selects the Condorcet winner. It is not used in parliamentary elections.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Electoral system</span> Method by which voters make a choice between options

An electoral system or voting system is a set of rules that determine how elections and referendums are conducted and how their results are determined. Electoral systems are used in politics to elect governments, while non-political elections may take place in business, non-profit organisations and informal organisations. These rules govern all aspects of the voting process: when elections occur, who is allowed to vote, who can stand as a candidate, how ballots are marked and cast, how the ballots are counted, how votes translate into the election outcome, limits on campaign spending, and other factors that can affect the result. Political electoral systems are defined by constitutions and electoral laws, are typically conducted by election commissions, and can use multiple types of elections for different offices.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Hare–Clark electoral system</span> Proportional-representation voting system

Hare-Clark is a type of single transferable vote electoral system of proportional representation used for elections in Tasmania and the Australian Capital Territory. The method for the distribution of preferences is similar to other voting systems in Australia, such as for the Australian Senate.