Global silver trade from the 16th to 19th centuries

Last updated
White represents the route of the Manila Galleons in the Pacific and the flota in the Atlantic, which mainly carried silver. (Blue represents Portuguese routes which primarily focused on spices.) 16th century Portuguese Spanish trade routes.png
White represents the route of the Manila Galleons in the Pacific and the flota in the Atlantic, which mainly carried silver. (Blue represents Portuguese routes which primarily focused on spices.)

The global silver trade between the Americas, Europe, and China from the sixteenth to nineteenth centuries was a spillover of the Columbian exchange which had a profound effect on the world economy. Many scholars consider the silver trade to mark the beginning of a genuinely global economy, [1] with one historian noting that silver "went round the world and made the world go round". [2] Although global, much of that silver ended up in the hands of the Chinese, as they accepted it as a form of currency. [3] In addition to the global economic changes the silver trade engendered, it also put into motion a wide array of political transformations in the early modern era. "New World mines", concluded several prominent historians, "supported the Spanish empire", acting as a linchpin of the Spanish economy. [4]

Contents

Spaniards at the time of the Age of Discovery discovered vast amounts of silver, much of which was from the Potosí silver mines, to fuel their trade economy. Potosí's deposits were rich and Spanish American silver mines were the world's cheapest sources of it. The Spanish acquired the silver, minting it into the peso de ocho to then use it as a means of purchase; that currency was so widespread that even the United States accepted it as valid until the Coinage Act of 1857. [5] As the Spanish need for silver increased, new innovations for more efficient extraction of silver were developed, such as the amalgamation method of using mercury to extract silver from ore. [6]

In the two centuries that followed the discovery of Potosí in 1545, the Spanish silver mines in the Americas produced 40,000 tons of silver. [7] Altogether, more than 150,000 tons of silver were shipped from Potosí by the end of the 18th century. [8] [ failed verification ][ better source needed ] From 1500 to 1800, Bolivia and Mexico produced about 80% [9] of the world's silver with 30% of it eventually ending up in China. In the late 16th and early 17th century, Japan was also exporting heavily into China and the foreign trade at large. [9]

As has been demonstrated, China dominated silver imports. China's huge demand of the silver was caused by the failure of making paper money "Hong Wu Tong Bao" and "Da Ming Tong Bao Chao" and the difficulties when making copper coins. After various status changes in China history, silver played a more important role in the market and became a dominant currency in China in the 1540s. [10] The silver flow into China passed through two cycles: the Potosí /Japan Cycle, which lasted from the 1540s to the 1640s, and the Mexican Cycle, which began in the first half of the 1700s. [11] The market value of silver in the Ming territory was double its value elsewhere, which provided great arbitrage profit for the Europeans and Japanese. [9] The room for arbitrage profit was further enlarged because of the silver content difference between silver ingots from Ming and Qing China and New World silver. [12] At the same time, China also made significant arbitrage earnings in the markets for silks, ceramics, and other non-silver goods, which formed a multiple arbitrage system. [11] In addition, the abundance of silver in China made it easy for the country to mint it into coinage and many methods and tools for identifying and measuring silver appeared to solve the problem caused by the difficulty in identifying and measure silver from 16th to 19th century. That process was so widespread that local Chinese government officials would demand taxes to be paid in silver to the point that silver eventually backed all of China's economy.

Silver in the Americas

Silver Peso of Philip V Philip V Coin silver, 8 Reales Mexico.jpg
Silver Peso of Philip V

A major drive of the Spanish colonization of the Americas during the late 15th and 16th centuries was the discovery, production, and trading of precious metals at a time when there was a severe shortage of them. The Spanish, along with other European nations, likewise had a great desire for Chinese goods such as silk and porcelain. [13] Conversely, the Europeans did not have any goods or commodities which China desired, so they traded their newly mined silver from the Americas which was badly needed in China at the time due to long running silver shortages, in order to make up for their trade deficit. [14] The two most important mining colonies of the Spanish Empire were Bolivia and Mexico, who were estimated to have provided one-hundred thousand tons of silver from the mid-16th century to the end of the colonial period in 1824. [15] The richest and most productive mine in the Americas was that of Potosí then located within the Viceroyalty of Peru, in what is now modern day Bolivia. [15] The richest camp in Mexico was in the city of Zacatecas, then a part of the Viceroyalty of New Spain. However, the production of this mine was far less than that of Potosi. [15]

Mining processes in the Americas

Relatively simple mining and processing techniques of the Incas and other indigenous people dominated American silver mining for the early part of the 16th century. [6] However, mining in the Americas became reliant on mercury amalgamation after it was developed and popularized in the mid-16th century. Mercury amalgamation dramatically increased the volume of silver production in the Americas, giving way to silver's central role in American economies and the burgeoning global economy. From 1575 to 1590, the use of amalgamation multiplied the output of Potosí, the most prominent Andean silver mine, by six. The presence of mercury at Huancavelica coupled with the abundance of cheap labor supplied by the rotational labor system mita made this intense production possible. [16] Mercury amalgamation was invented by a Spaniard in central Mexico in the 1550s. [6] Historians dispute which individual was the first to invent the process, but most agree that it was a Spaniard. Mercury represented one of the highest costs of production for the Americas, since much of it had to be shipped [15] from Almadén in Spain. The ratio of mercury to silver produced was about two to one. [15] Furthermore, German miners introduced the stamp mill and lead smelting in the 1530s. [6] Gunpowder was often used to blast large holes to create the mine shafts, although there were not many deep shafts. [6] Potosí had the most ore, however it was lower quality than that of Mexico.

Mining production in the Americas largely depended on native Amerindian labor in both Mexico and Bolivia. [6] In Mexico, many of the natives worked as wage laborers by the middle of the 17th century. [17] However, the labor system known as the repartimiento still existed in some places. [17] Silver production in Mexico was relatively cheap when compared to that of Bolivia, and the general trend of Mexican labor systems was that towards waged labor. [15] In Bolivia's mines, the mit'a system was a dominant form of native labor subjection, although waged laborers worked on the mines as well. [15] Natives under the mit'a system were paid much less, and this was necessary for the production of silver to continue in Bolivia where costs were relatively high. [15]

Measurement and identification of silver

Silver was used as money in the silver trade from 16th to 19th centuries. To gain more benefits, deceptive methods were used. Therefore, there are many books, such as Yinpu, Bianyinpu and Xinzenggeguoyinshilunjie on silver identification in this period. In the deceptive method such as wrapping lead or copper in silver were introduced in this book.

At the same time, the amount of silver cannot be quickly and easily identified, so many methods of silver measurements have been studied. For example, Yuanbao, a fixed weight of silver, was used to facilitate trading. Dengtou, a tool for measuring the weight of silver, were also used.

First paper money

The world's first paper money ("flying money") was invented by the Chinese [18] and they needed some commodity to back it. Traditional coins were useful, but the amount of coins needed for large purchases could be bulky and dangerous to transport. That problem was solved when the Chinese created small pieces of paper with pictures of the coin printed on them. [19] By the nature of their geography, China had no real amount of precious metals of their own to back the paper money they invented. Because the Spaniards did not find gold but did find copious amounts of silver in Bolivia and Mexico, the Spaniards and the rest of Europe used this silver to purchase the commodities of choice from China, solving both of their problems. [20]

The status change of silver

From 960 to 1276, the Song dynasty in China's history, the importance of silver kept increasing as a currency in a long period of time.

In 1375, the beginning of the Ming dynasty, the Hongwu Emperor of Ming established Hongwu Tongbao and Da Ming Baochao as the currency of China. At the same time, he banned gold and silver as currency, which led to the decreasing importance of these two precious metals. Baochao was abolished as a currency in 1425. In addition, Ming did not have enough money to make copper coins, which was the first currency in the first dynasty. Therefore, copper coin making was banned in 14 BC. [21]

Great Ming Bao Chao Great Ming Bao Chao.jpg
Great Ming Bao Chao

In the 1540s, because of the failure of making paper money and the difficulties when making copper coins, silver played a more important role in the market and became a dominant currency in China. [10] [21]

Global flow of silver

Into China

The history of global trade in silver with China can be divided into several periods, including the Potosí/Japan Cycle from the 1540s to 1640s and the Mexican Cycle in the first half of the 1700s. [11]

The Potosí/Japan cycle started in the 1540s because of the decline of the paper money system in China during the Ming dynasty resulting from inflation and the prevalence of counterfeit money. [22] In 1571, Spain started the trade directly with China in the Americas. The Manila galleon trade reached its peak in 1597, when the trade quantity surpassed 1.2 million pesos. Although the economy performed poorly in 1632, trade increased by 0.24 million pesos every year. [23] With the increase in silver accumulation in the Americas and Japan and the balancing of the Chinese silver supply and demand market due to the large amount of silver imports, the price of Chinese silver and world silver prices converge and the Potos/Japan Cycle comes to an end in the 1640s. [24] [25]

The Mexican Cycle refers to the first half of the 1700s. During this time, China's population came into a boom because of the importation of hardy American crops, such as sweet potatoes, corn and peanuts. [26] A chain reaction followed swiftly: the development of China's silver market, and growing demand of silver in China. At the same time, the silver industry in Latin America, especially in Mexico came in to a boom and became the main source of silver exports to China. [11]

Global silver trade

The ultimate destination for much of the silver produced in the Americas and Japan was China. [27] Silver from the Americas flowed mostly across the Atlantic and made its way to the Far East. [28] A popular route was around the Cape of Good Hope into the east, and sometimes it came over land. [14] Major outposts for the silver trade were located in Southeast Asian countries, such as the Spanish Philippines. [29] The city of Manila served as a primary outpost of the exchange of goods between the Americas, Japan, India, Indonesia and China. [29] However, a large amount of silver was transported across the vast Pacific Ocean directly from the Americas as well, via the Manila Galleons. [27] There are few records of the amount of silver which crossed the Pacific due to it being discouraged by the Spanish monarchy, so estimates vary greatly. [17]

During the 16th and 17th centuries, a large amount of silver also remained in the Americas, accumulated through the business of local merchants. Royal officials in various parts of Spanish America often protected the activities of local merchants and enacted protectionist policies that encouraged local monopolies. This meant that royal officials were not solely interested in accumulating silver for Spain's economy, but rather, they also had a vested interest in developing the economies of their specific localities. [30] Additionally, much of the silver that was eventually exported still circulated extensively in the Americas before finding its way to port cities for export. For example, the situado , a regular remittance of silver from the mines of Potosí to Buenos Aires by way of mule trains, did not merely result in the transport of silver. Instead, those transporting the situado would also use their access to silver to conduct their own deals along the road, thus regularly injecting silver into the areas along the route of the situado. Even when this exchanged silver eventually ended up in Buenos Aires or another port city where it was exported, it facilitated numerous transactions within the Americas before it got there. [31]

Silver also found its way across other parts of the world as well. India and Europe both received a fair amount of silver. [14] This silver was often locally traded for other commodities, such as gold or crops. In India, silver flowed from the south to the north, and gold flowed the opposite way. [14] Often silver and gold were manufactured into jewelry or hoarded as treasure.

China and the demand for silver

China was the ultimate destination in which silver would flow towards. In exchange, the Chinese traded their popular goods such as silk and porcelain. China had a high demand for silver due to its shift from paper money to coins in the early period of the Ming dynasty. [32] The Ming paper currency eventually failed due to self-imposed inflation along with an inability to stop the production of counterfeit bills. [33] The Ming attempted to produce copper coins as a new form of currency, but production was inconsistent. [32] Hence silver became of high value because it was a valid currency that could be processed abroad. The bimetallic ratio of silver to gold was about two to one, which meant that European and Japanese merchants made a large amount of profit. [34] The difference in silver content between silver ingots from Ming–Qing China and New World silver, ranging from 3% to 8%, further increased the scope for arbitrage in the global flow of silver. [12]

The trade between China, Japan, and Southeast Asian nations in both expensive goods like silk products and inexpensive ones like sugar continues developing in the second half of the 16th century. Gross profits ranging from 100% to 300% in the trade of these commodities can be eared by China, and lower price of the product itself means the greater room for profits. At the same time, European and Japanese traders profited from the price difference between Chinese silver and the rest of the world. Silver-commodities trades between China and other countries are essentially multiple arbitrages. [11]

In the 1640s, the bimetallic ratios in China converged with the rest of the world, before experiencing another population boom. [27] The new population boom was a product of the introduction of New World crops into China, mainly sweet potatoes, which could be more easily grown. [27] By this time, the silver mines in Japan were largely depleted and the New World became China's primary source for silver. [29]

Initially, Japan served as China's primary source for silver in the 16th century. [13] In exchange for silver, China would provide Japan with silk and gold. [29] Japan and China did not directly trade with each other, due to political tensions. [29] This meant that European entities and countries, such as the Dutch and Portuguese served as a middle man between the two countries. [29]

Middlemen in the silver flow: Portuguese

Because of the large demand of silver in China, and the need for money for people in China during the Potosí/Japan flow (1540s–1640s), Portuguese traders partnered with Chinese smugglers, bringing silver from Japan, Britain, and France to China. The role of middlemen connecting the silver flows from Japan to China in the silver trade was highly lucrative and the profits Portuguese made financed Macao, the toehold Portugal established off the southeast coast of China, with tacit Chinese consent. [35] [22] In 1540, Japanese ports became a hotspot for Chinese traders seeking to obtain silver, a precious commodity in China. This influx of Chinese traders coincided with the arrival of Portuguese seafarers in East Asian waters. Portuguese traders quickly partnered with Chinese smugglers to bypass the Ming maritime embargo and transport Japanese silver to the Chinese market. During the period from 1583 to 1591, when the Portuguese sailed from Macau in China to Japan, they transported luxurious items such as white silk, gold, musk, and porcelain, but their return journey from Japan was solely dedicated to carrying silver. [36]

China's silver dominance

In The Wealth of Nations , Adam Smith noted the sheer force and great reach of the global silver trade. He was impressed by its market value but more intrigued with the way this single item of commerce brought together new and old worlds, i.e. the Americas and China. [37] Although China acted as the cog driving the wheel of global trade, Japan's huge contribution of silver exports to China were critical to the world economy and China's liquidity and success with the commodity. Historians posit Europeans would have been left out of world trade, and China may have fallen prey to conquest by settlers of the Americas, if not for Japanese silver mining. Silver was paramount to East Asia's introduction into the global trade market. [38] Under the Ming and Qing dynasties, China hoarded silver to boost its economy and increase its trading power. [39]

Many historians argue that silver was responsible for the birth of global economics and trade. According to this view, global trade commenced in 1571 when Manila was founded and became the first trading post linking America and Asia due to the expansive and profitable silver trade. [40] Scholars find the amount of silver traveling from Manila to China was approximately three million pesos or 94,000 kilograms in the early 1600s. [41]

The rarity of silver production was seen as an opportunity for China to control the currency's value and support its own national currency. Silver was one of the only accepted trade items from Europeans and its value in China was astronomical compared to rest of the world. [38] Between 1600 and 1800 China received 100 tons of silver on average per year.[ citation needed ] A large populace near the Lower Yangtze averaged hundreds of taels of silver per household in the late 16th century. [42]

Later on, the sudden ban on Spanish silver imports to China imposed by the Qing dynasty after defeating the Ming in 1644, [43] along with a long period of economic stagnation and recession due to famines and bad financial policies back in Spain, simultaneously combined with devastating losses sustained towards the end of the Thirty Years' War, all precipitated the significant decline of the Spanish Empire in the second half of the 17th century, and its eclipse by France, and, later, Great Britain. [44] [45]

Silver even played a large role when defending against Toyotomi Hideyoshi's attempted takeover of Joseon Korea. The Ming Ministry of War sent approximately 140,000 liang (approximately 7 tonnes) of silver to its soldiers and required provinces to provide silver as tax for the war effort as well. [46] In the sixteenth century, the daimyos of Southwest Japan hoped for unhinged global trade but were stopped due to Ming China trade policies. Still, Japan became a player in the global economy via frequent Wokou ships arriving to extract Japan's abundance of silver and exchange goods. Japan increased its wealth through successful trilateral trade with Portugal and China as Japan now had Chinese goods to offer the Portuguese who had silver mines of their own. [47] Founder of the Ming dynasty, Hongwu, actually sought to eliminate silver from the market due to his fear of inflation which he previously experienced under the Yuan dynasty. His attempt involved imposing harsh limits on silver mining to stop its flow into the market and subsequently replaced it with baochao or paper money. However, the currency never popularized and silver persisted as a global currency. [48]

Opium imports

Despite some restrictions, silver continued to drive trade through its popularity in Europe. This, combined with a high British demand for Chinese tea, created chronic trade deficits for European governments, which were forced to risk silver deficits to supply merchants in Asia. [49] As supplies of silver decreased in Europe, Europeans had less ability to purchase highly coveted Chinese goods. Merchants were no longer able to sustain the China trade through profits made by selling Chinese goods in the West and were forced to take bullion out of circulation in Europe to buy goods in China. [50]

In the late 18th century, British merchants from the East India Company began to introduce Indian opium to Chinese markets. The demand for opium rose rapidly and was so profitable that Chinese opium dealers began to seek out more suppliers of the drug, thus inaugurating the opium trade; one merchant declared that Opium "is like gold. It can sell any time." [49] From 1804 to 1820, a period when the Qing dynasty needed to finance the suppression of the White Lotus Rebellion, Chinese merchants were soon exporting silver to pay for opium rather than Europeans paying for Chinese goods with the precious metal. [51]

The Qing imperial court debated whether and how to end the opium trade, eventually settling on regulations on consumption. That measure, however, resulted in an increase in drug smuggling by Europeans and Chinese traders. In 1810, the Daoguang Emperor issued an edict concerning the matter, declaring, "Opium has a harm. Opium is a poison, undermining our good customs and morality. Its use is prohibited by law." [52] Following a debate at court in 1836 on whether to legalize the drug or crack down on its use, the emperor decided on the latter. An upright official, Commissioner Lin Zexu led the campaign against opium as a kind of "drug czar". The British, offended by the seizure of their property in opium, sent a large naval expedition to China to end the restrictive conditions under which they had long traded with that country. Thus began the First Opium War, in which Britain's industrialized military might was proven in China's rout. The Treaty of Nanking, which ended the war in 1842 largely on British terms, imposed numerous restrictions on Chinese sovereignty and opened five ports to European traders. [53]

See also

Related Research Articles

The Price Revolution, sometimes known as the Spanish Price Revolution, was a series of economic events that occurred between the second half of the 15th century and the first half of the 17th century, and most specifically linked to the high rate of inflation that occurred during this period across Western Europe. Prices rose on average roughly sixfold over 150 years. This level of inflation amounts to 1.2% per year compounded, a relatively low inflation rate for modern-day standards, but rather high given the monetary policy in place in the 16th century.

The Haijin (海禁) or sea ban was a series of related isolationist policies in China restricting private maritime trading and coastal settlement during most of the Ming dynasty and early Qing dynasty. The policy introduced by the Ming founder Zhu Yuanzhang significantly hampered the growth of China's domestic trade, although the Ming was not able to enforce the policy in full despite official proclamations, and trade continued in forms like smuggling until the late Ming government opened the port of Yuegang for trade. Later, the early Qing dynasty's anti-insurgent "Great Clearance" (1661-1683) also caused considerable devastating effects on communities along the coast, until the Qing seized control of Taiwan and opened coastal ports to foreign trade.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Reserve currency</span> Currencies held by monetary authorities as part of their foreign exchange reserves

A reserve currency is a foreign currency that is held in significant quantities by central banks or other monetary authorities as part of their foreign exchange reserves. The reserve currency can be used in international transactions, international investments and all aspects of the global economy. It is often considered a hard currency or safe-haven currency.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Spanish dollar</span> Coin of the Spanish Empire

The Spanish dollar, also known as the piece of eight, is a silver coin of approximately 38 mm (1.5 in) diameter worth eight Spanish reales. It was minted in the Spanish Empire following a monetary reform in 1497 with content 25.563 g (0.8219 ozt) fine silver. It was widely used as the first international currency because of its uniformity in standard and milling characteristics. Some countries countermarked the Spanish dollar so it could be used as their local currency.

The Manila galleon, originally known as La Nao de China, and Galeón de Acapulco, refers to the Spanish trading ships that linked the Spanish Crown's Viceroyalty of New Spain, based in Mexico City, with its Asian territories, collectively known as the Spanish East Indies, across the Pacific Ocean. The ships made one or two round-trip voyages per year between the ports of Acapulco and Manila from the late 16th to early 19th century. The name of the galleon changed to reflect from which city the ship sailed, setting sail from Cavite, in Manila Bay, at the end of June or first week of July, starting the return journey (tornaviaje) from Acapulco in March–April of the next calendar year, and returning to Manila in June–July.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Columbian exchange</span> Transfers between the Old and New Worlds

The Columbian exchange, also known as the Columbian interchange, was the widespread transfer of plants, animals, precious metals, commodities, culture, human populations, technology, diseases, and ideas between the New World in the Western Hemisphere, and the Old World (Afro-Eurasia) in the Eastern Hemisphere, in the late 15th and following centuries. It is named after the Italian explorer Christopher Columbus and is related to the European colonization and global trade following his 1492 voyage. Some of the exchanges were purposeful; some were accidental or unintended. Communicable diseases of Old World origin resulted in an 80 to 95 percent reduction in the number of Indigenous peoples of the Americas from the 15th century onwards, most severely in the Caribbean. The cultures of both hemispheres were significantly impacted by the migration of people from the Old World to the New. European colonists and African slaves replaced Indigenous populations across the Americas, to varying degrees. The number of Africans taken to the New World was far greater than the number of Europeans moving to the New World in the first three centuries after Columbus.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Potosí</span> City in Bolivia

Potosí, known as Villa Imperial de Potosí in the colonial period, is the capital city and a municipality of the Department of Potosí in Bolivia. It is one of the highest cities in the world at a nominal 4,090 m (13,420 ft). For centuries, it was the location of the Spanish colonial silver mint. A considerable amount of the city's colonial architecture has been preserved in the historic center of the city, which—along with the globally important Cerro Rico de Potosí—are part of a designated UNESCO World Heritage Site.

Trade dollars were silver coins minted as trade coins by various countries to facilitate trade with countries in East Asia, especially China and Japan. They all approximated in weight and fineness to the Spanish dollar, which had set the standard for a de facto common currency for trade in the Far East.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Patio process</span> Metallurgical process: extraction of silver by amalgamation

The patio process is a process for extracting silver from ore. Smelting, or refining, is most often necessary because silver is only infrequently found as a native element like some metals nobler than the redox couple 2 H+ + 2 eH
2
(gold, mercury, ...). Instead, it is made up of a larger ore body. Thus, smelting, or refining, is necessary to reduce the compound containing the Ag+ cation into metallic Ag and to remove other byproducts to get at pure silver. The process, which uses mercury amalgamation to recover silver from ore, was first used at scale by Bartolomé de Medina in Pachuca, Mexico, in 1554. It replaced smelting as the primary method of extracting silver from ore at Spanish colonies in the Americas. Although some knowledge of amalgamation techniques were likely known since the classical era, it was in the New World that it was first used on a large industrial scale. Other amalgamation processes were later developed, importantly the pan amalgamation process, and its variant, the Washoe process. The silver separation process generally differed from gold parting and gold extraction, although amalgamation with mercury is also sometimes used to extract gold. While gold was often found in the Americas as a native metal or alloy, silver was often found as a compound such as silver chloride and silver sulfide, and therefore required mercury amalgamation for refinement.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Silver standard</span> Monetary system

The silver standard is a monetary system in which the standard economic unit of account is a fixed weight of silver. Silver was far more widespread than gold as the monetary standard worldwide, from the Sumerians c. 3000 BC until 1873. Following the discovery in the 16th century of large deposits of silver at the Cerro Rico in Potosí, Bolivia, an international silver standard came into existence in conjunction with the Spanish pieces of eight. These silver dollar coins played the role of an international trading currency for nearly four hundred years.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Silver mining</span> Extraction silver from the ground

Silver mining is the extraction of silver from minerals, starting with mining. Because silver is often found in intimate combination with other metals, its extraction requires elaborate technologies. In 2008, ca. 25,900 metric tons were consumed worldwide, most of which came from mining.

Japanese currency has a history covering the period from the 8th century AD to the present. After the traditional usage of rice as a currency medium, Japan adopted currency systems and designs from China before developing a separate system of its own.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Iwami Ginzan Silver Mine</span> UNESCO World Heritage Site in Shimane Prefecture, Japan

The Iwami Ginzan (石見銀山) was an underground silver mine in the city of Ōda, in Shimane Prefecture on the main island of Honshu, Japan. It was the largest silver mine in Japanese history. It was active for almost four hundred years, from its discovery in 1526 to its closing in 1923.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economy of East Asia</span>

The economy of East Asia comprises 1.6 billion people living in six different countries and regions. The region includes several of the world's largest and most prosperous economies: Taiwan, Japan, South Korea, China, Hong Kong, and Macau. It is home to some of the most economically dynamic places in the world, being the site of some of the world's most extended modern economic booms, including the Taiwan miracle (1950–present) in Taiwan, Miracle on the Han River (1974–present) in South Korea, Japanese economic miracle (1950–1990) and the Chinese economic miracle (1983–2010) in China.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economy of the Ming dynasty</span> Economy of China in from the 14th through 17th centuries

The economy of the Ming dynasty (1368–1644) of China was one of the largest in the world during that period. It is regarded as one of China's three major golden ages. The period was marked by the increasing political influence of the merchants, the gradual weakening of imperial rule, and technological advances.

The Single whip law or the "Single whip reform" was a fiscal law first instituted during the middle Ming dynasty, in the early 16th century, and then promulgated throughout the empire in 1580 by Zhang Juzheng.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Silver Dragon (coin)</span> East Asian silver coins

Silver Dragon coins, also sometimes known as Dragon dollars, are silver coins issued by China, Japan and later Korea for general circulation in their own countries. Featuring a dragon on the obverse of Japanese and Korean issues and on the reverse of Chinese issues, all were inspired by the silver Spanish dollar which following its introduction into the region in the 16th Century had set the standard for a de facto common currency for trade in the Far East, this specification being a weight of 27.22 grams and a fineness of .900; the coin thus contained 24.5 g of silver.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Great Bullion Famine</span> Shortage of gold and silver in 15th century Europe

The Great Bullion Famine was a shortage of precious metals that struck Europe in the 15th century, with the worst years of the famine lasting from 1457 to 1464. During the Middle Ages, gold and silver coins saw widespread use as currency in Europe, and facilitated trade with the Middle East and Asia; the shortage of these metals therefore became a problem for European economies. The main cause for the bullion famine was outflow of silver to the East unequaled by European mining output, although 15th century contemporaries believed the bullion famine to be caused by hoarding.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Qing dynasty coinage</span> Historical coinage of China

Qing dynasty coinage was based on a bimetallic standard of copper and silver coinage. The Manchu-led Qing dynasty was established in 1636 and ruled over China proper from 1644 until it was overthrown by the Xinhai Revolution in 1912. The Qing dynasty saw the transformation of a traditional cash coin based cast coinage monetary system into a modern currency system with machine-struck coins, while the old traditional silver ingots would slowly be replaced by silver coins based on those of the Mexican peso. After the Qing dynasty was abolished its currency was replaced by the Chinese yuan of the Republic of China.

The economy in the Indian Subcontinent during the Mughal Empire era performed just as it did in ancient times, though now it would face the stress of extensive regional tensions. It was described as large and prosperous. India producing about 28% of the world's industrial output up until the 18th century. While at the start of 17th century, the economic expansion within Mughal territories become the largest and surpassed Qing dynasty and Europe, where from Bengal Subah alone, the province statistically has contributed to 12% of Gross domestic product. by 1700s, Mughals had approximately 24 percent share of world's economy. They grew from 22.7% in 1600, which at the end of 16th century, has surpassed China to become the world's largest GDP.

References

  1. China and the Birth of Globalization in the 16th Century, by Dennis O. Flynn and Arturo Giráldez
  2. Frank 1998, p. 131.
  3. von Glahn, Richard (1996). "Myth and Reality of China's Seventeenth Century Monetary Crisis". Journal of Economic History. 2: 132. ... silver wanders throughout all the world ... before flocking to China, where it remains as if at its natural center.
  4. Flynn, Dennis O.; Giraldez, Arturo (1995). "Born with a 'Silver Spoon'". Journal of World History. 2: 210.
  5. "A Century of Lawmaking". Library of Congress. Retrieved May 23, 2018.
  6. 1 2 3 4 5 6 Brading, D. A.; Cross, Harry E. (1972). "Colonial Silver Mining: Mexico and Peru". The Hispanic American Historical Review. 52 (4): 545–579. doi:10.2307/2512781. JSTOR   2512781.
  7. Stein, Stanley J.; Stein, Barbara H. (2000). Silver, Trade, and War: Spain and America in the Making of Early Modern Europe . Johns Hopkins University Press. pp.  21.
  8. "Potosí Silver Mines". Atlas Obscura. Retrieved 2016-05-08.
  9. 1 2 3 Flynn, Dennis O. (1995). "Born with a 'Silver Spoon': The Origin of World Trade in 1571" (PDF). Journal of World History. University of Hawaii Press. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2018-04-23.
  10. 1 2 Wei, Yuan (1900). Qing Jing Shi Wen Bian清經世文編 (in Chinese (Taiwan)) (3rd ed.). p. 657.
  11. 1 2 3 4 5 Flynn, Dennis O.; Giráldez, Arturo (2002). "Cycles of Silver: Global Economic Unity through the Mid-Eighteenth Century". Journal of World History. 13 (2): 391–427. ISSN   1045-6007. JSTOR   20078977.
  12. 1 2 Sun, L.; Yang, G.; Liu, R.; Pollard, A. M.; Zhu, T.; Liu, C. (2021). "Global circulation of silver between Ming–Qing China and the Americas: Combining historical texts and scientific analyses". Archaeometry. 63 (3): 627–640. doi: 10.1111/arcm.12617 . ISSN   0003-813X.
  13. 1 2 Flynn, Dennis O.; Giráldez, Arturo (1995). "Born with a 'Silver Spoon': The Origin of World Trade in 1571". Journal of World History. 6 (2): 201–221. JSTOR   20078638.
  14. 1 2 3 4 Frank, Andre (July 1998). Reorient . Berkeley: University of California Press. ISBN   9780520214743.
  15. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Garner, Richard L. (1988). "Long-Term Silver Mining Trends in Spanish America: A Comparative Analysis of Peru and Mexico". The American Historical Review. 93 (4): 898–935. doi:10.2307/1863529. JSTOR   1863529.
  16. Bakewell, Peter (1984), "Mining in colonial Spanish America", in Bethell, Leslie (ed.), 2: Colonial Latin America, The Cambridge History of Latin America, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 105–152, doi:10.1017/chol9780521245166.005, ISBN   978-0-521-24516-6 , retrieved 2020-12-08
  17. 1 2 3 Knight, Alan (2002). Mexico: from the beginning to the Spanish Conquest . Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. ISBN   978-0521814744. OCLC   48249030.
  18. Moshenskyi, Sergii (2008). History of the Weksel: Bill of Exchange and Promissory Note. Xlibris. pp.  50.
  19. Weatherford, Jack (1997). The History of Money. Crown Business. pp. 125–26.
  20. "China and Europe, 1500–2000 and Beyond: What is Modern?". Asia for Educators. Columbia University. Retrieved 2015-03-30.
  21. 1 2 Glahn, Richard von (23 July 2019). "The Changing Significance of Latin American Silver in the chinese economy, 16th–19th Centuries". Revista de Historia Economica – Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History. 38 (Special Issue 3): 553–585.
  22. 1 2 Chen, Chau-Nan; Chang, Pin-Tsun; Chen, Shikuan (1995). "The Sung and Ming paper monies: Currency competition and currency bubbles". Journal of Macroeconomics. 17 (2): 273–288. doi:10.1016/0164-0704(95)80101-4. ISSN   0164-0704.
  23. Zhang, Yi. "1550-1830 年中国白银流入及其影响" ["Silver Inflows to China and Their Effects, 1550-1830"]. November 2020, pp. 3–7.
  24. Smith, Adam (1776-01-01). "An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations". In Todd, William B. (ed.). The Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, Vol. 2: An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Vol. 1 (The Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, Vol. 2: An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Vol. 1 ed.). Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/oseo/instance.00043218. ISBN   978-0-19-926956-3 . Retrieved 2023-04-25.
  25. Tepaske, John Jay (1988). "Artur Attman. American Bullion in the European World Trade, 1600–1800". The American Historical Review (book review). doi:10.1086/ahr/93.3.680. ISSN   1937-5239.
  26. Flynn, Dennis O.; Giráldez, Arturo (2004). "Path dependence, time lags and the birth of globalisation: A critique of O'Rourke and Williamson". European Review of Economic History. 8 (1): 81–108. doi:10.1017/S1361491604001066. ISSN   1361-4916. JSTOR   41377950.
  27. 1 2 3 4 Flynn, Dennis O.; Giráldez, Arturo (2002). "Cycles of Silver: Global Economic Unity through the Mid-Eighteenth Century". Journal of World History. 13 (2): 391–427. doi:10.1353/jwh.2002.0035. JSTOR   20078977. S2CID   145805906.
  28. Frank 1998, p. 178.
  29. 1 2 3 4 5 6 Flynn, Dennis O.; Giraldez, Arturo (1996). "Silk for Silver: Manila–Macao Trade in the 17th Century". Philippine Studies. 44 (1): 52–68. JSTOR   42634185.
  30. Seijas, Tatiana (2016-01-02). "Inns, mules, and hardtack for the voyage: the local economy of the Manila Galleon in Mexico". Colonial Latin American Review. 25 (1): 56–76. doi:10.1080/10609164.2016.1180787. ISSN   1060-9164. S2CID   163214741.
  31. Moutoukias, Zacarias (1988). "Power, Corruption, and Commerce: The Making of the Local Administrative Structure in Seventeenth-Century Buenos Aires". The Hispanic American Historical Review. 68 (4): 771–801. doi:10.2307/2515681. ISSN   0018-2168. JSTOR   2515681.
  32. 1 2 von Glahn, Richard (1996). "Myth and Reality of China's Seventeenth-Century Monetary Crisis". The Journal of Economic History. 56 (2): 429–454. doi:10.1017/S0022050700016508. JSTOR   2123972. S2CID   154126073.
  33. Chen, Shikuan. "The Sung and Ming Paper Monies: Currency Competition and Currency Bubbles". National Taiwan University.
  34. Atwell, William S. (2005). "Another Look at Silver Imports into China, ca. 1635–1644". Journal of World History. 16 (4): 467–489. doi:10.1353/jwh.2006.0013. JSTOR   20079347. S2CID   162090282.
  35. Waley-Cohen, Joanna (1999). The sextants of Beijing: global currents in Chinese history (1st ed.). New York: W. W. Norton. pp. 40–44. ISBN   9780393046939.
  36. Glahn, Richard von (23 July 2019). "The Changing Significance of Latin American Silver in the Chinese Economy, 16th–19th Centuries". Revista de Historia Economica – Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History. 38 (Special Issue 3): 553–585 via Cambridge University Press.
  37. Smith, Adam (2003). Cannan, Edwin (ed.). The Wealth of Nations (Bantam classic ed.). New York: Bantam Classic. ISBN   978-0553585971. OCLC   53006965.
  38. 1 2 Flynn, Dennis Owen; Giraldez, Arturo (2002). "Cycles of Silver: Global Economic Unity through the Mid-Eighteenth Century". Journal of World History. 13 (2): 391–427. doi:10.1353/jwh.2002.0035. ISSN   1527-8050. S2CID   145805906.
  39. Reid, Anthony J. S. (1993). Southeast Asia in the Early Modern Era Trade, Power, and Belief. Cornell University Press.
  40. Flynn, Dennis; Giraldez, Arturo (1995-01-01). "Arbitrage, China, and World Trade in the Early Modern Period". Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient. 38 (4): 429–448. doi:10.1163/1568520952600308. ISSN   0022-4995.
  41. Atwell, William S.; Wen-t'i, Ch'ing-shih (December 1977). "Notes on Silver, Foreign Trade, and the Late Ming Economy". 3. 3 (8): 1–33.
  42. Huang, Ray (1975), "Financial management", Taxation and Governmental Finance in Sixteenth-Century Ming China, Cambridge University Press, pp. 266–305, doi:10.1017/cbo9780511735400.011, ISBN   9780511735400
  43. von Glahn, Richard. "The Changing Significance of Latin American Silver in the Chinese Economy, 16th–19th Centuries". Cambridge Core. Cambridge University Press. p. 3 Hiatus: The Kangxi Depression (1660–1690). Retrieved July 10, 2021.
  44. Casado Alonso, Hilario; Ruiz, Teofilo F. (28 August 2019). "Economic Life in Late Medieval and Early Modern Spain, 1085–1815". Oxford Research Encyclopedias. Oxford University Press. pp. The Crisis of the 17th Century. Retrieved 14 July 2021.
  45. Storrs, Christopher. "The 'Decline' of Spain in the Seventeenth Century" (PDF). State Papers Online 1509-1714. Cengage Learning. p. 5. Retrieved 14 July 2021.
  46. Swope, Kenneth (2009). A dragon's head and a serpent's tail : Ming China and the first great East Asian war, 1592–1598. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press. ISBN   9780806185026. OCLC   843883049.
  47. Kobata, A. (1965). "The Production and Uses of Gold and Silver in Sixteenth- and Seventeenth-Century Japan". The Economic History Review. 18 (2): 245–266. doi:10.2307/2592093. ISSN   0013-0117. JSTOR   2592093.
  48. McDermott, Joseph P.; Brook, Timothy (1999). "The Confusions of Pleasure: Commerce and Culture in Ming China". Pacific Affairs. 72 (2): 267. doi:10.2307/2672136. ISSN   0030-851X. JSTOR   2672136.
  49. 1 2 Peyrefitte, Alain (1992). The Immobile Empire—The first great collision of East and West—the astonishing history of Britain's grand, ill-fated expedition to open China to Western Trade, 1792–94. Alfred A. Knopf.
  50. Gray, Jack (2002). Rebellions and Revolutions: China from the 1800s to 2000 . New York: Oxford University Press. pp.  22–3.
  51. Yangwen Zheng, "The Social Life of Opium in China, 1483–1999", Modern Asian Studies (2003) 37#1, pp 1–39.
  52. Fu, Lo-shu (1966). A Documentary Chronicle of Sino-Western relations. Vol. 1. p. 380.
  53. Hoe, Susanna; Roebuck, Derek (1999). The Taking of Hong Kong: Charles and Clara Elliot in China Waters. Routledge. p. 203.

Further reading