1967 sterling devaluation

Last updated

The 1967 sterling devaluation (or 1967 sterling crisis) was a devaluation of sterling from $2.80 to $2.40 per pound on 18 November 1967. It ended a long sterling crisis that had started in 1964 with the election of Labour in the 1964 general election, [1] but originated in the balance of payments crises of the preceding Conservative government. [1]

Contents

Historical background

As soon as Harold Wilson's newly elected Labour government took power after winning the 1964 general election, vowing to end the Conservatives' "stop-go" economic policies, [1] sterling came under pressure because the market feared that Labour would devalue the currency so as to be able to implement a looser monetary policy, favouring growth. [2] Upon coming to power, the government was informed that they had inherited an exceptionally large deficit of £800 million [lower-alpha 1] on Britain's external balance of trade, partly caused by the preceding (Conservative) government's expansive fiscal policy in the run-up to the 1964 election. Wilson wrote in his autobiography that the life of his government was "dominated by an inherited balance of payments problem which was nearing a crisis at the moment we took office". [3] Immediately on announcing the trade figures, the pound came under increased pressure. [1] Many economists advocated devaluation of the pound in response, but Wilson resisted, reportedly in part out of concern that Labour, which had previously devalued sterling in 1949, would become tagged as "the party of devaluation". [2] Wilson also believed that a devaluation would disproportionately harm low-income Britons with savings and poorer Commonwealth of Nations countries in the sterling area. The government instead opted to deal with the problem by imposing a temporary surcharge on imports, and a series of deflationary measures designed to reduce demand and therefore the inflow of imports. [4] In the latter half of 1967, an attempt was made to prevent the recession in activity from going too far, in the form of a stimulus to consumer durable spending through an easing of credit, which in turn prevented a rise in unemployment. [5]

International aid is mostly what had helped maintain the $2.80 value of sterling between 1964 and 1967, thanks to "lines of credit from central banks and the IMF and [...] a swap network with the Federal Reserve Bank of New York". [1] These enabled the Bank of England to intervene on the foreign exchange market. Nevertheless, in the absence of improvements to the fundamental economic situation of the United Kingdom, delaying the devaluation only served to reduce the Bank of England's dollar reserves. [6]

Consequences

According to Catherine Schenk, the 1967 devaluation became "emblematic of the inability of the Labour Party to cope effectively with the reduction of sterling's international role". [6] After the devaluation, the IMF sent a mission to London and on 29 November 1967 offered a £1.4 billion loan to the UK. [7] [lower-alpha 2]

While the 1949 devaluation helped the British economy, the 1967 did not improve the United Kingdom's economic position. [8] The devaluation also failed to improve the Bank of England's reserve position. To appear stronger than it was towards the markets after the devaluation, the Bank of England started manipulating or "window dressing" its reserve figures. [9]

Notes

  1. about £13 billion at 2019 prices, using GDP index
  2. about £23 billion at 2019 prices, using GDP index

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economy of Thailand</span>

The economy of Thailand is dependent on exports, which accounted in 2021 for about 58 per cent of the country's gross domestic product (GDP). Thailand itself is a newly industrialized country, with a GDP of 17.367 trillion baht (US$495 billion) in 2022, the 9th largest economy of Asia. As of 2018, Thailand has an average inflation of 1.06% and an account surplus of 7.5% of the country's GDP. Its currency, the Thai Baht, ranked as the tenth most frequently used world payment currency in 2017.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Harold Wilson</span> Prime Minister of the United Kingdom (1964–1970, 1974–1976)

James Harold Wilson, Baron Wilson of Rievaulx, was a British statesman and Labour Party politician who served as Prime Minister of the United Kingdom twice, from October 1964 to June 1970 and again from March 1974 to April 1976. He was the Leader of the Labour Party from 1963 to 1976, and was a Member of Parliament (MP) from 1945 to 1983. Wilson is the only Labour leader to have formed administrations following four general elections.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">James Callaghan</span> Prime Minister of the United Kingdom from 1976 to 1979

Leonard James Callaghan, Baron Callaghan of Cardiff,, commonly known as Jim Callaghan, was a British politician who served as Prime Minister of the United Kingdom from 1976 to 1979 and Leader of the Labour Party from 1976 to 1980. Callaghan is the only person to have held all four Great Offices of State, having served as Chancellor of the Exchequer from 1964 to 1967, Home Secretary from 1967 to 1970 and Foreign Secretary from 1974 to 1976. He was a Member of Parliament (MP) from 1945 to 1987.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Reserve currency</span> Currencies held by monetary authorities as part of their foreign exchange reserves

A reserve currency is a foreign currency that is held in significant quantities by central banks or other monetary authorities as part of their foreign exchange reserves. The reserve currency can be used in international transactions, international investments and all aspects of the global economy. It is often considered a hard currency or safe-haven currency.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Black Wednesday</span> 1992 UK financial crisis

Black Wednesday, or the 1992 sterling crisis, was a financial crisis that occurred on 16 September 1992 when the UK Government was forced to withdraw sterling from the (first) European Exchange Rate Mechanism , following a failed attempt to keep its exchange rate above the lower limit required for ERM participation. At that time, the United Kingdom held the Presidency of the Council of the European Union.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Global financial system</span> Global framework for capital flows

The global financial system is the worldwide framework of legal agreements, institutions, and both formal and informal economic action that together facilitate international flows of financial capital for purposes of investment and trade financing. Since emerging in the late 19th century during the first modern wave of economic globalization, its evolution is marked by the establishment of central banks, multilateral treaties, and intergovernmental organizations aimed at improving the transparency, regulation, and effectiveness of international markets. In the late 1800s, world migration and communication technology facilitated unprecedented growth in international trade and investment. At the onset of World War I, trade contracted as foreign exchange markets became paralyzed by money market illiquidity. Countries sought to defend against external shocks with protectionist policies and trade virtually halted by 1933, worsening the effects of the global Great Depression until a series of reciprocal trade agreements slowly reduced tariffs worldwide. Efforts to revamp the international monetary system after World War II improved exchange rate stability, fostering record growth in global finance.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">1997 Asian financial crisis</span> Financial crisis of many Asian countries during the second half of 1997

The 1997 Asian financial crisis was a period of financial crisis that gripped much of East and Southeast Asia during the late 1990s. The crisis began in Thailand in July 1997 before spreading to several other countries with a ripple effect, raising fears of a worldwide economic meltdown due to financial contagion. However, the recovery in 1998–1999 was rapid, and worries of a meltdown quickly subsided.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Bretton Woods system</span> Financial-economic agreement reached in 1944

The Bretton Woods system of monetary management established the rules for commercial relations among the United States, Canada, Western European countries, and Australia among 44 other countries after the 1944 Bretton Woods Agreement. The Bretton Woods system was the first example of a fully negotiated monetary order intended to govern monetary relations among independent states. The Bretton Woods system required countries to guarantee convertibility of their currencies into U.S. dollars to within 1% of fixed parity rates, with the dollar convertible to gold bullion for foreign governments and central banks at US$35 per troy ounce of fine gold. It also envisioned greater cooperation among countries in order to prevent future competitive devaluations, and thus established the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to monitor exchange rates and lend reserve currencies to nations with balance of payments deficits.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Central Bank of Malaysia</span> Central Bank of Malaysia

The Central Bank of Malaysia is the Malaysian central bank. Established on 26 January 1959 as the Central Bank of Malaya, its main purpose is to issue currency, act as banker and adviser to the government of Malaysia and regulate the country's financial institutions, credit system and monetary policy. Its headquarters is located in Kuala Lumpur, the federal capital of Malaysia.

In macroeconomics and modern monetary policy, a devaluation is an official lowering of the value of a country's currency within a fixed exchange-rate system, in which a monetary authority formally sets a lower exchange rate of the national currency in relation to a foreign reference currency or currency basket. The opposite of devaluation, a change in the exchange rate making the domestic currency more expensive, is called a revaluation. A monetary authority maintains a fixed value of its currency by being ready to buy or sell foreign currency with the domestic currency at a stated rate; a devaluation is an indication that the monetary authority will buy and sell foreign currency at a lower rate.

The Mexican peso crisis was a currency crisis sparked by the Mexican government's sudden devaluation of the peso against the U.S. dollar in December 1994, which became one of the first international financial crises ignited by capital flight.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Great Depression in Australia</span> Effects of the Great Depression in Australia

Australia suffered badly during the period of the Great Depression of the 1930s. The Depression began with the Wall Street Crash of 1929 and rapidly spread worldwide. As in other nations, Australia suffered years of high unemployment, poverty, low profits, deflation, plunging incomes, and lost opportunities for economic growth and personal advancement.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Sterling area</span> Currencies linked to the pound sterling

The sterling area was a group of countries that either pegged their currencies to sterling, or actually used sterling as their own currency.

The 1991 Indian economic crisis was an economic crisis in India resulting from a balance of payments deficit due to excess reliance on imports and other external factors. India's economic problems started worsening in 1985 as imports swelled, leaving the country in a twin deficit : the Indian trade balance was in deficit at a time when the government was running on a huge fiscal deficit.

The London Gold Pool was the pooling of gold reserves by a group of eight central banks in the United States and seven European countries that agreed on 1 November 1961 to cooperate in maintaining the Bretton Woods System of fixed-rate convertible currencies and defending a gold price of US$35 per troy ounce by interventions in the London gold market.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Currency war</span> Competition between nations to gain competitive advantage by manipulating monetary supply

Currency war, also known as competitive devaluations, is a condition in international affairs where countries seek to gain a trade advantage over other countries by causing the exchange rate of their currency to fall in relation to other currencies. As the exchange rate of a country's currency falls, exports become more competitive in other countries, and imports into the country become more and more expensive. Both effects benefit the domestic industry, and thus employment, which receives a boost in demand from both domestic and foreign markets. However, the price increases for import goods are unpopular as they harm citizens' purchasing power; and when all countries adopt a similar strategy, it can lead to a general decline in international trade, harming all countries.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Green pound</span> Exchange rate

In the United Kingdom, the green pound was the common name for an exchange rate that was used to calculate the value of financial support within the European Union's Common Agricultural Policy until 1999.

Momtaz El-Saeed is an Egyptian civil servant who once served in the government of Egypt as minister of finance from 2011 to 2013.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">1976 sterling crisis</span> Situation of prolonged doubt in the strength of Britains currency

The 1976 sterling crisis was a currency crisis in the United Kingdom. Inflation, a balance of payments deficit, a public spending deficit, and the 1973 oil crisis were contributors.

The devaluation of sterling in 1949 was a major currency crisis in the United Kingdom that led to a 30.5% devaluation of sterling from $4.04 per pound to $2.80 on 18 September 1949. Although the devaluation was made in the United Kingdom, over 19 countries had currencies pegged to sterling and also devalued.

References

  1. 1 2 3 4 5 Bordo, Michael; MacDonald, Ronald; Oliver, Michael (2009). "Sterling in crisis: 1964-1967". European Economic History Review. Cambridge, MA. doi: 10.3386/w14657 .
  2. 1 2 Cairncross, Alec; Eichengreen, Barry (2003). Sterling in Decline, The Devaluations of 1931, 1949 and 1967 (2nd ed.). Springer. doi:10.1057/9780230596306. ISBN   978-0-230-59630-6.
  3. Harold, Wilson (1974). The labour government, 1964-70 : a personal record. Penguin Books. ISBN   0-14-021762-2. OCLC   1321981339.
  4. Thorpe, Andrew (1997). A History of the British Labour Party. London: Macmillan Education UK. pp. 125–145. doi:10.1007/978-1-349-25305-0. ISBN   978-0-333-56081-5.
  5. Townsend, Peter (1972). Bosanquet, Nicholas (ed.). Labour and inequality: Sixteen Fabian Essays. Fabian Society. ISBN   978-0-7163-4004-1.
  6. 1 2 Schenk, Catherine R. (2013). The decline of sterling : managing the retreat of an international currency, 1945-1992. Cambridge Univ. Press. p. 155. ISBN   978-0-521-87697-1. OCLC   934197928.
  7. Duncan, Needham (2014). UK monetary policy from devaluation to Thatcher, 1967-82. Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN   978-1-137-36954-3. OCLC   964759941.
  8. Forrest, Capie (2012). The Bank of England : 1950s to 1979. Cambridge University Press. p. 372. ISBN   978-1-107-62169-5. OCLC   816047261.
  9. Naef, Alain (2021). "Dirty float or clean intervention? The Bank of England in the foreign exchange market". European Economic History Review. 25 (1): 180–201. doi:10.1093/ereh/heaa011.

See also