Condorcet efficiency

Last updated
Efficiency of several voting systems with a spatial model and candidates distributed similarly to the 201 voters Merrill 1984 Fig2c Condorcet Efficiency under Spatial-Model Assumptions (relative dispersion = 1.0).svg
Efficiency of several voting systems with a spatial model and candidates distributed similarly to the 201 voters
As candidates become more ideologically clustered relative to the voter distribution, some voting methods perform more poorly at finding the Condorcet winner. Merrill 1984 Fig2d Condorcet Efficiency under Spatial-Model Assumptions (relative dispersion = 0.5).svg
As candidates become more ideologically clustered relative to the voter distribution, some voting methods perform more poorly at finding the Condorcet winner.

Condorcet efficiency is a measurement of the performance of voting methods. It is defined as the percentage of elections for which the Condorcet winner (the candidate who is preferred over all others in head-to-head races) is elected, provided there is one. [2] [3] [4]

A voting method with 100% efficiency would always pick the Condorcet winner, when one exists, and a method that never chose the Condorcet winner would have 0% efficiency.

Efficiency is not only affected by the voting method, but is a function of the number of voters, number of candidates, and of any strategies used by the voters. [1]

It was initially developed in 1984 by Samuel Merrill III, along with social utility efficiency. [1]

A related, generalized measure is Smith efficiency, which measures how often a voting method elects a candidate in the Smith set.[ citation needed ] Smith efficiency can be used to differentiate between voting methods across all elections, because unlike the Condorcet winner, the Smith set always exists. A 100% Smith-efficient method is guaranteed to be 100% Condorcet-efficient, and likewise with 0%.

See also

References

  1. 1 2 3 4 Merrill, Samuel (1984). "A Comparison of Efficiency of Multicandidate Electoral Systems". American Journal of Political Science. 28 (1): 23–48. doi:10.2307/2110786. ISSN   0092-5853. JSTOR   2110786.
  2. Gehrlein, William V.; Valognes, Fabrice (2001-01-01). "Condorcet efficiency: A preference for indifference". Social Choice and Welfare. 18 (1): 193–205. doi:10.1007/s003550000071. ISSN   1432-217X. S2CID   10493112.
  3. Merrill, Samuel (1985). "A statistical model for Condorcet efficiency based on simulation under spatial model assumptions" . Public Choice. 47 (2): 389–403. doi:10.1007/BF00127534. ISSN   0048-5829. S2CID   153922166.
  4. Gehrlein, William V. (2011). Voting paradoxes and group coherence : the condorcet efficiency of voting rules. Lepelley, Dominique. Berlin: Springer. ISBN   978-3-642-03107-6. OCLC   695387286.