Garett Jones

Last updated

Garett Jones
NationalityAmerican
Academic career
Field Economics
Website mason.gmu.edu/~gjonesb/

Garett Jones is an American economist and author. His research pertains to the fields of macroeconomics, monetary policy, IQ in relation to productivity, [1] short-term business cycles, and economic development. He is an associate professor at George Mason University and the BB&T Professor for the Study of Capitalism at the Mercatus Center. [2] [3]

Contents

Early life and education

Jones was raised as a Mormon but left the church as a young adult. [4] His grandmother was Jewish. [5] He completed a B.A. in history with a minor in sociology from Brigham Young University in 1992. He did an M.P.A. in public affairs at Cornell University in 1993, followed by an M.A. in political science at the University of California, Berkeley in 1994. Jones completed a Ph.D. in economics at the University of California, San Diego in 2000.

Academic career

After holding a number of visiting scholar and other academic positions, Jones joined the faculty of George Mason University in 2007. [6]

He is on the editorial board of the Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics.

Research on IQ and its role in productivity and economic growth

Jones started his research on IQ in a paper with Joel Schneider in 2006 that argued that IQ is a statistically significant explanatory variable of economic growth, [7] thus agreeing broadly with the thesis advanced by Richard Lynn and Tatu Vanhanen in their book IQ and the Wealth of Nations. The chief observation that Jones made, and popularized, is that national IQs have much greater predictive power for individual earnings than individual IQ.

Jones' further research has been on identifying the causal mechanisms by which IQ might affect productivity and economic growth at a national level. [2] One mechanism posited by Jones is that smarter groups tend to be better at arriving at and enforcing norms of cooperation. Jones has used laboratory experiments involving repeated prisoner's dilemma, combined with the SAT scores of participants, to offer support for this hypothesis. [8] He has also suggested that patience and delayed gratification might offer an explanation. [9]

Jones has argued that certain sectors requiring very high quality work and with very low error-tolerance can only exist and thrive given access to a high-IQ population, because in such sectors, it is not possible to replace a single high-IQ worker by multiple low-IQ workers and achieve the same output. Jones informally dubs such sectors "O-Ring sectors", in contrast to "foolproof sectors", where a larger workforce of people with lower productivity can produce the same output as a smaller workforce of people with high productivity. [10]

Jones offers a summary of his and others' research on the relationship between IQ and national productivity in an article for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics . [11]

Research on money

Some of Jones' research has focused on the role of money, monetary policy, and mechanisms to reduce the risk of financial crisis. [2] [12] [13] [14]

Books

Jones wrote the book Hive Mind: How Your Nation's IQ Matters So Much More Than Your Own , which builds on his research on the relationship between IQ and national productivity. [15] It was released in November 2015 by Stanford University Press. [16]

He was the editor of the book Banking Crises (2016), produced for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics . [17]

His book 10% Less Democracy: How Less Voting Could Mean Better Governance was published on February 7, 2020. It is based on a 2015 presentation. [18]

On November 15, 2022, Jones published The Culture Transplant: How Migrants Make the Economies They Move to a Lot Like the Ones They Left. [19]

Media appearances

Jones was a guest blogger for EconLog from September 2012 to April 2013. [2] He has given his opinion on macroeconomic policy and financial crises on CNBC and in various media clippings. [20] [21]

Related Research Articles

Economics is a social science that studies the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Vernon L. Smith</span> American economist and Nobel laureate (born 1927)

Vernon Lomax Smith is an American economist and professor of business economics and law at Chapman University. He was formerly a professor of economics at the University of Arizona, professor of economics and law at George Mason University, and a board member of the Mercatus Center. Along with Daniel Kahneman, Smith shared the 2002 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his contributions to behavioral economics and his work in the field of experimental economics. He worked to establish 'laboratory experiments as a tool in empirical economic analysis, especially in the study of alternative market mechanisms'.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economies of agglomeration</span> Urban development in locations generating cost savings

One of the major subfields of urban economics, economies of agglomeration, explains, in broad terms, how urban agglomeration occurs in locations where cost savings can naturally arise. This term is most often discussed in terms of economic firm productivity. However, agglomeration effects also explain some social phenomena, such as large proportions of the population being clustered in cities and major urban centers. Similar to economies of scale, the costs and benefits of agglomerating increase the larger the agglomerated urban cluster becomes. Several prominent examples of where agglomeration has brought together firms of a specific industry are: Silicon Valley and Los Angeles being hubs of technology and entertainment, respectively, in California, United States; and London, United Kingdom, being a hub of finance.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Veblen good</span> Luxury good for which the demand increases as the price increases

A Veblen good is a type of luxury good, named after American economist Thorstein Veblen, for which the demand increases as the price increases, in apparent contradiction of the law of demand, resulting in an upward-sloping demand curve. The higher prices of Veblen goods may make them desirable as a status symbol in the practices of conspicuous consumption and conspicuous leisure. A product may be a Veblen good because it is a positional good, something few others can own.

Agricultural economics is an applied field of economics concerned with the application of economic theory in optimizing the production and distribution of food and fiber products. Agricultural economics began as a branch of economics that specifically dealt with land usage. It focused on maximizing the crop yield while maintaining a good soil ecosystem. Throughout the 20th century the discipline expanded and the current scope of the discipline is much broader. Agricultural economics today includes a variety of applied areas, having considerable overlap with conventional economics. Agricultural economists have made substantial contributions to research in economics, econometrics, development economics, and environmental economics. Agricultural economics influences food policy, agricultural policy, and environmental policy.

International economics is concerned with the effects upon economic activity from international differences in productive resources and consumer preferences and the international institutions that affect them. It seeks to explain the patterns and consequences of transactions and interactions between the inhabitants of different countries, including trade, investment and transaction.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Tyler Cowen</span> American economist (born 1962)

Tyler Cowen is an American economist, columnist and blogger. He is a professor at George Mason University, where he holds the Holbert L. Harris chair in the economics department. He hosts the economics blog Marginal Revolution, together with co-author Alex Tabarrok. Cowen and Tabarrok also maintain the website Marginal Revolution University, a venture in online education.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Baumol effect</span> Rise of salaries in jobs that have seen little rise of productivity

In economics, the Baumol effect, also known as Baumol's cost disease, first described by William J. Baumol and William G. Bowen in the 1960s, is the tendency for wages in jobs that have experienced little or no increase in labor productivity to rise in response to rising wages in other jobs that did experience high productivity growth. In turn, these sectors of the economy become more expensive over time, because their input costs have increased while productivity has not. Typically, this affects services more than manufactured goods, and in particular health, education, arts and culture.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Edward Lazear</span> American economist and academic (1948–2020)

Edward Paul Lazear was an American economist, the Morris Arnold and Nona Jean Cox Senior Fellow at the Hoover Institution at Stanford University and the Davies Family Professor of Economics at Stanford Graduate School of Business.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Michael Kremer</span> American economist and Nobel laureate (born 1964)

Michael Robert Kremer is an American development economist currently serving as University Professor in Economics at the University of Chicago and Director of the Development Innovation Lab at the Becker Friedman Institute for Research in Economics. Kremer formerly served as the Gates Professor of Developing Societies at Harvard University, a role he held from 2003 to 2020. In 2019, Kremer was jointly awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences, together with Esther Duflo and Abhijit Banerjee, "for their experimental approach to alleviating global poverty."

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Deindustrialization</span> Process of reduction of industrial activity

Deindustrialization is a process of social and economic change caused by the removal or reduction of industrial capacity or activity in a country or region, especially of heavy industry or manufacturing industry.

The O-ring theory of economic development is a model of economic development put forward by Michael Kremer in 1993, which proposes that tasks of production must be executed proficiently together in order for any of them to be of high value. The key feature of this model is positive assortative matching, whereby people with similar skill levels work together.

The Easterlin paradox is a finding in happiness economics formulated in 1974 by Richard Easterlin, then professor of economics at the University of Pennsylvania, and the first economist to study happiness data. The paradox states that at a point in time happiness varies directly with income both among and within nations, but over time happiness does not trend upward as income continues to grow: while people on higher incomes are typically happier than their lower-income counterparts at a given point in time, higher incomes don't produce greater happiness over time. One explanation is that my happiness depends on a comparison between my income and my perceptions of the average standard of living. If everyone's income increases, my increased income gives a short boost to my happiness, since I do not realize that the average standard of living has gone up. Some time later, I realize that the average standard of living has also gone up, so the happiness boost produced by my increased income disappears. It is the contradiction between the point-of-time and time series findings that is the root of the paradox: while there is a correlation at a fixed point, there is no trend over multiple points. That is, in the short run, everyone perceives increases in income to be correlated with happiness and tries to increase their incomes. However, in the long run, this proves to be an illusion, since everyone's efforts to raise standards of living lead to increasing averages, leaving everyone in the same place in terms of relative income. Various theories have been advanced to explain the Paradox, but the Paradox itself is solely an empirical generalization. The existence of the paradox has been strongly disputed by other researchers.

Cultural economics is the branch of economics that studies the relation of culture to economic outcomes. Here, 'culture' is defined by shared beliefs and preferences of respective groups. Programmatic issues include whether and how much culture matters as to economic outcomes and what its relation is to institutions. As a growing field in behavioral economics, the role of culture in economic behavior is increasingly being demonstrated to cause significant differentials in decision-making and the management and valuation of assets.

The economics of religion concerns both the application of the techniques of economics to the study of religion and the relationship between economic and religious behaviours. Contemporary writers on the subject trace it back to Adam Smith (1776).

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Peter Blair Henry</span> American economist

Peter Blair Henry, an economist, was the ninth Dean of New York University's Leonard N. Stern School of Business, and William R. Berkley Professor of Economics and Business, and author of TURNAROUND: Third World Lessons for First World Growth. Previously, he was the Konosuke Matsushita Professor of International Economics at Stanford University.

Stock-flow consistent models (SFC) are a family of macroeconomic models based on a rigorous accounting framework, that seeks to guarantee a correct and comprehensive integration of all the flows and the stocks of an economy. These models were first developed in the mid-20th century but have recently become popular, particularly within the post-Keynesian school of thought. Stock-flow consistent models are in contrast to dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models, which are used in mainstream economics.

James Donald Feyrer is a Professor of Economics at Dartmouth College, and the vice-chair of Dartmouth's Department of Economics. His research focuses on economic growth, macroeconomics and productivity.

Donald Jasper Harris is a Jamaican-American economist and professor emeritus at Stanford University, known for applying post-Keynesian ideas to development economics. He is the father of the 49th and current vice president of the United States, Kamala Harris, as well as of her sister, lawyer and political commentator Maya Harris.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Tobias Thomas</span> German economist

Tobias Thomas is a German economist and Director General of Statistics Austria.

References

  1. "Garett Jones: A Very Intelligent Economist on Economics and Intelligence". The Economist. June 22, 2007.
  2. 1 2 3 4 "Garett Jones" . Retrieved January 30, 2013.
  3. "Garett Jones". August 15, 2008.
  4. "He Now Refers to Himself as a Post-Mormon".
  5. Jones, Garett (2023). The Culture Transplant: How Migrants Make the Economies They Move to a Lot Like the Ones They Left. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press. p. 11. ISBN   978-1-5036-3294-3.
  6. Jones, Garett. "Curriculum Vitae" (PDF). Retrieved January 30, 2013.
  7. Jones, Garett; Schneider, W. Joel (2006). "Intelligence, Human Capital, and Economic Growth: A Bayesian Averaging of Classical Estimates (BACE) Approach" (pdf). Journal of Economic Growth. 11 (1): 71–93. doi:10.1007/s10887-006-7407-2. ISSN   1381-4338. JSTOR   40216088. S2CID   14646928.
  8. Jones, Garett (2008). "Are smarter groups more cooperative? Evidence from prisoner's dilemma experiments, 1959–2003". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 68 (3–4): 489–497. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2008.06.010. ISSN   0167-2681.
  9. Al-Ubaydli, Omar; Jones, Garett; Weel, Jaap (2013). "Patience, cognitive skill, and coordination in the repeated stag hunt". Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics. 6 (2): 71–96. doi:10.1037/npe0000005. ISSN   2151-318X. SSRN   1764272.
  10. Jones, Garett (2013). "The O-ring sector and the Foolproof sector: An explanation for skill externalities" (PDF). Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 85: 1–10. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2012.10.014. ISSN   0167-2681.
  11. Jones, Garett (2008). "IQ and national productivity" (PDF). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. p. 1. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.3866. ISBN   9780333786765.
  12. Jones, Garett. "On Money and Output: Is money redundant?".
  13. Jones, Garett. "Dynamic IS Curves With and Without Money: An international comparison".
  14. Jones, Garett. "Speed Bankruptcy: A Firewall to Future Crises" (PDF).
  15. Jones, Garett (2015). Hive Mind: How Your Nation's IQ Matters So Much More Than Your Own. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press. ISBN   978-0-8047-8596-9.
  16. "Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics".
  17. Jones, Garett, ed. (2016). Banking Crises. Palgrave Macmillan UK. doi:10.1057/9781137553799. ISBN   978-1-349-55412-6.
  18. Jones, Garett (February 24, 2015). "10% Less Democracy: How Less Voting Could Mean Better Governance" (PDF). George Mason University . Retrieved April 6, 2017.
  19. "The Culture Transplant: How Migrants Make the Economies They Move to a Lot Like the Ones They Left". scholar.google.com.
  20. "Garett Jones discusses the Financial Crisis in Europe on CNBC Asia". Mercatus Center. June 26, 2012. Retrieved January 30, 2013.
  21. "Media Clippings by Garett Jones". Mercatus Center. Archived from the original on March 29, 2013. Retrieved January 30, 2013.