Internalization theory

Last updated

Internalization theory is a branch of economics that is used to analyse international business behaviour. [1]

Contents

Outline

Internalization theory focuses on imperfections in intermediate product markets. [2] Two main kinds of intermediate product are distinguished: knowledge flows linking research and development (R&D) to production, and flows of components and raw materials from an upstream production facility to a downstream one. Most applications of the theory focus on knowledge flow. [3] Proprietary knowledge is easier to appropriate when intellectual property rights such as patents and trademarks are weak. Even with strong protections firms protect their knowledge through secrecy. Instead of licensing their knowledge to independent local producers, firms exploit it themselves in their own production facilities. In effect, they internalise the market in knowledge within the firm. The theory claims the internalization leads to larger, more multinational enterprises, because knowledge is a public good. [4] Development of a new technology is concentrated within the firm and the knowledge then transferred to other facilities.

Refinements

Internalization occurs only when firms perceive the benefits to exceed the costs. When internalization leads to foreign investment the firm may incur political and commercial risks due to unfamiliarity with the foreign environment. These are known as ‘costs of doing business abroad’, [5] arising from the ‘liability of foreignness’. [6] When such costs are high a firm may license or outsource production to an independent firm; or it may produce at home and export to the country instead.

Firms without special knowledge may become multinational to internalise supplies of components or raw materials in order to guarantee quality or continuity of supply, or for tax advantages from transfer pricing.

Variants

Buckley and Casson (1976) [7] was a seminal work. Two Canadian economists, Stephen Hymer [8] and John McManus, [9] independently noted the relevance of internalization, and their contribution is the subject of debate. Alan M. Rugman [10] linked internalization theory to his earlier work on market imperfections, applying it empirically in a North American context. Jean-Francois Hennart [11] subsequently developed a variant of the theory that emphasised the interplay of headquarters authority and local autonomy within the firm. Internalization theory is also closely related to Stephen Magee's appropriability theory. [12]

Controversies

Internalization theory was used by John Harry Dunning as one of the components of his eclectic paradigm or OLI model. [13] Dunning referred to knowledge as an ‘ownership advantage’ and claimed that ownership advantage was necessary for a firm to become a multinational. This was disputed by internalization theorists on the grounds that if quality control and transfer pricing are sufficient, then ownership advantage cannot be necessary. Dunning argued that the firm's ability to internalise could also be described as an ownership advantage, which led internalization theorists to suggest that his concept of ownership advantage had become tautological. [14] Internalization theory is related to transaction cost theory through common dependence on the seminal work of Ronald Coase. [15] They are not the same however. Internalization theory focuses on links between R&D and production whereas transaction cost theory focuses on links between one production facility and another. [16] Transaction cost theory typically attributes market imperfections to bounded rationality and ‘lock in’, whilst internalization theory emphasises asymmetric information and weaknesses in property rights. Transaction cost theory is typically applied in a domestic context, whereas internalization theory was developed specifically for an international context. [17]

Prior to internalization theory, the study of international business was largely focused on the environment, and in particular the economic, financial, political and cultural dimensions of doing business abroad. Internalization theory provided a theory of the international firm and thus augmented the international business field by demonstrating the interaction between the external environmental and the internal knowledge flows between MNE parent firm and subsidiaries. This interaction between external country-specific advantages (CSAs) and internal MNE firm-specific advantages (FSAs) is the nexus for strategic managerial international business decisions. [18]

Policy implications

The view that multinationals transfer technology and not capital provided a major boost to the process of globalisation. The United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) was strongly influenced by internalization theory and the eclectic paradigm. [19] It persuaded political leaders to encourage inward investment as a source of the new technologies required for economic development, thereby reversing their previous attitudes. Multinational profits were increasingly viewed as payments for knowledge and technology rather than as interest paid on capital, and foreign ownership became accepted, in certain cases, as a necessary safeguard for foreign investors’ intellectual property. [20]

Related Research Articles

Internalization is the process of making something internal, with more specific meanings in various fields. It is the opposite of externalization.

A multinational corporation (MNC), also referred to as a multinational enterprise (MNE), a transnational enterprise (TNE), a transnational corporation (TNC), an international corporation or a stateless corporation with subtle but contrasting senses, is a corporate organization that owns and controls the production of goods or services in at least one country other than its home country. Control is considered an important aspect of an MNC, to distinguish it from international portfolio investment organizations, such as some international mutual funds that invest in corporations abroad simply to diversify financial risks. Black's Law Dictionary suggests that a company or group should be considered a multinational corporation "if it derives 25% or more of its revenue from out-of-home-country operations".

In economics, internationalization or internationalisation is the process of increasing involvement of enterprises in international markets, although there is no agreed definition of internationalization. Internationalization is a crucial strategy not only for companies that seek horizontal integration globally but also for countries that addresses the sustainability of its development in different manufacturing as well as service sectors especially in higher education which is a very important context that needs internationalization to bridge the gap between different cultures and countries. There are several internationalization theories which try to explain why there are international activities.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Export</span> Goods produced in one country that are sold to another country

An export in international trade is a good produced in one country that is sold into another country or a service provided in one country for a national or resident of another country. The seller of such goods or the service provider is an exporter; the foreign buyers is an importer. Services that figure in international trade include financial, accounting and other professional services, tourism, education as well as intellectual property rights.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Foreign direct investment</span> Purchase of an asset

A foreign direct investment (FDI) refers to purchase of an asset in another country, such that it gives direct control to the purchaser over the asset. In other words, it is an investment in the form of a controlling ownership in a business, in real estate or in productive assets such as factories in one country by an entity based in another country. It is thus distinguished from a foreign portfolio investment or foreign indirect investment by a notion of direct control.

The theory of the firm consists of a number of economic theories that explain and predict the nature of the firm, company, or corporation, including its existence, behaviour, structure, and relationship to the market. Firms are key drivers in economics, providing goods and services in return for monetary payments and rewards. Organisational structure, incentives, employee productivity, and information all influence the successful operation of a firm in the economy and within itself. As such major economic theories such as Transaction cost theory, Managerial economics and Behavioural theory of the firm will allow for an in-depth analysis on various firm and management types.

International business refers to the trade of goods, services, technology, capital and/or knowledge across national borders and at a global or transnational scale.

Stephen Herbert Hymer was a Canadian economist. His research focused on the activities of multinational firms, which was the subject of his PhD dissertation The International Operations of National Firms: A Study of Direct Foreign Investment, presented in 1960, but published posthumously in 1976, by the Department of Economics from Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Charles P. Kindleberger, his thesis supervisor, submitted it for publication, as mentioned by him on the introduction of Hymer's thesis dissertation.

In international economics, international factor movements are movements of labor, capital, and other factors of production between countries. International factor movements occur in three ways: immigration/emigration, capital transfers through international borrowing and lending, and foreign direct investment. International factor movements also raise political and social issues not present in trade in goods and services. Nations frequently restrict immigration, capital flows, and foreign direct investment.

Mark Casson is a British economist and academic. He is a professor of economics at the University of Reading in England. He was Head of Department (1987–94) and is the institution's current Director of the Centre for Institutional Performance.

<i>Journal of International Business Studies</i> Academic journal

The Journal of International Business Studies is a double blind peer-reviewed academic journal and the official publication of the Academy of International Business. It is published by Palgrave Macmillan and covers research on international business. The journal was established in 1970 and is edited by Alain Verbeke. According to the Journal Citation Reports its 2020 impact factor is 11.382.

The eclectic paradigm, also known as the OLI Model or OLI Framework, is a theory in economics. It is a further development of the internalization theory and published by John H. Dunning in 1979. Modern Trade Theory incorporates this paradigm using the Grossman-Hart-Moore Theory of the firm

John Harry Dunning was a British economist and is widely recognised as the father of the field of international business. He researched the economics of international direct investment and the multinational enterprise from the 1950s until his death. In the 1980s, he published the eclectic paradigm or OLI-Model/Framework as further development on Internalization theory. OLI remains the predominant theoretical perspective to study international business activities, notably foreign direct investment and multinational enterprises. His first book, American Investment in British Manufacturing Industry (1958), is the first seminal work in the international business field.

Peter Jennings Buckley is Professor of International Business at the University of Leeds and director of the Centre for International Business at the University of Leeds (CIBUL).

Rajneesh Narula, is an economist and academic. He is Professor of International Business Regulation and Director of the John H. Dunning Center for International Business at Henley Business School, University of Reading in Reading, UK.

Alan M. Rugman (1945-2014) was a leading scholar in the field of international business. In his last academic role, he served as Head of International Business and Strategy at Henley Business School, University of Reading in Reading, UK.

The Reading School of International Business is widely understood in the field of international business (IB), management and economics to embody a stream of conceptual, and theoretically-driven empirical research, and consists of a group ofpoxkkdkforovhhlfl

a common approach to analyzing multinational enterprise and foreign direct investment. Some are based in the Department of Economics and in Henley Business School at the University of Reading, England, but membership is international. The Reading School builds upon the pathbreaking theoretical work of Peter Buckley and Mark Casson on internalization theory. This was complemented by simultaneous work by John Dunning as he developed the eclectic paradigm of international business as an envelope explanation containing three principal drivers of foreign direct investment, comprising ownership (O); location (L); and internalization (I). The Reading School approach continues through the work of its academic disciples around the world, as well as through The John Dunning Centre at Henley Business School, University of Reading, under the directorship of Rajneesh Narula.

Geoffrey G. Jones is a British-born business historian. He became a US citizen in 2010. He is currently Isidor Straus Professor of Business History at the Harvard Business School. The previous holders of this Chair, which was the first in the world in business history being founded in 1927, included Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. and Thomas K. McCraw.

Raymond Vernon was an American economist. He was a member of the group that developed the Marshall Plan after World War II and later played a role in the development of the International Monetary Fund and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade. He was the Clarence Dillon Professor of International Affairs at Harvard Kennedy School, becoming emeritus on his retirement. His formulation of the Product life-cycle theory of US exports, first published in 1966, in turn influenced the behavior of companies.

The springboard theory or springboard perspective is an international business theory that elucidates the unique motives, processes and behaviors of international expansion of emerging market multinational enterprises. Springboard theory was developed by Luo and Tung (2007), and has since been used to examine EM MNEs. At the core of this theory is the argument that EM MNEs systematically and recursively use international expansion as a springboard to acquire critical resources needed to compete more effectively against their global rivals at home and abroad and to reduce their vulnerability to institutional and market constraints at home. These efforts are systematic in the sense that “springboard” steps are deliberately designed as a grand plan to facilitate firm growth and as a long-range strategy to establish more solidly their competitive positions in the global marketplace. They are also recursive because such “springboard” activities are recurrent and revolving.

References

  1. Rugman, Alan M.; Collinson, Simon (2012). International Business. Pearson. ISBN   978-0-273-76097-9.
  2. M. Rugman, Alan (1981). Inside the Multinationals: The Economics of Internal Markets. Columbia University Press. ISBN   978-0-231-05384-6.
  3. Markusen, J. R. (1995). "The Boundaries of Multinational Enterprises and the Theory of International Trade". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 9 (2): 169–189. doi: 10.1257/jep.9.2.169 .
  4. Buckley, Peter J (2009). "The internalisation theory of the multinational enterprise: A review of the progress of a research agenda after 30 years". Journal of International Business Studies. 40 (9): 1563–1580. doi:10.1057/jibs.2009.49.
  5. Hymer, Stephen H. (1976) The International Operations of National Firms: A Study of Direct Foreign Investment, [MIT PhD dissertation, 1960] Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, xxii + 253pp.; Stephen H.
  6. Zaheer, S. (1995). "Overcoming the Liability of Foreignness". Academy of Management Journal. 38 (2): 341–363. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.477.3477 . doi:10.2307/256683. JSTOR   256683.
  7. Buckley, Peter J. and Mark C. Casson (1976) The Future of the Multinational Enterprise, London: Macmillan [Basingstoke, Hants: Palgrave Macmillan, 25th Anniversary ed. 2001], 112pp.
  8. Hymer, Stephen H. (1990) The large multinational corporation: An analysis of some motives for the international integration of business, (trans. N. Vacherot, intro. M.C. Casson), in Mark Casson (ed.) Multinational Corporations, Aldershot: Edward Elgar, 1990, 3-31 [originally published in French in Revue Economique, 19 (6), 1968, 949-73].
  9. McManus, John (1972). Paquet, Gilles (ed.). The theory of the international firm. pp. 32–59.{{cite book}}: |work= ignored (help)
  10. Rugman, A. M. (1986). "New Theories of the Multxnational Enterprise: An Assessment of Internalization Theory". Bulletin of Economic Research. 38 (2): 101–118. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8586.1986.tb00208.x.
  11. Hennart, Jean François (1982). A Theory of Multinational Enterprise. University of Michigan Press. ISBN   978-0-472-10017-0.
  12. Magee, Stephen P. (1977) Multinational corporation, industry technology cycle and development, Journal of World Trade Law, 11, 297-321.
  13. Dunning, John H. (1977). "Trade, location of economic activity and the multinational enterprise: a search for an eclectic approach". In Ohlin, Bertil Gotthard; Hesselborn, Per Ove; Wijkman, Per Magnus (eds.). The International Allocation of Economic Activity: Proceedings of a Nobel Symposium Held at Stockholm. Palgrave Macmillan Limited. pp.  395–418. ISBN   978-0-333-21423-7.
  14. Williams, B. (1997). "Positive Theories of Multinational Banking: Eclectic Theory Versus Internalisation Theory". Journal of Economic Surveys. 11: 71–100. doi:10.1111/1467-6419.00024.
  15. Coase, Ronald H. (1937) The nature of the firm, Economica (New series), 4, 387–405
  16. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Simon and Schuster. 1985. ISBN   978-0-684-86374-0.
  17. Buckley, Peter J.; Casson, Mark (15 January 2010). The Multinational Enterprise Revisited: The Essential Buckley and Casson. Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN   978-0-230-51599-4.
  18. Rugman, A. M.; Verbeke, A. (1992). "A Note on the Transnational Solution and the Transaction Cost Theory of Multinational Strategic Management". Journal of International Business Studies. 23 (4): 761. doi:10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8490287.Rugman, Alan M (2003). "Extending the theory of the multinational enterprise: internalization and strategic management perspectives". Journal of International Business Studies. 34 (2): 125–137. doi:10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400012.Rugman, Alan M. (2011). "Fifty Years of International Business Theory and Beyond". Management International Review. 51 (6): 755–786. doi:10.1007/s11575-011-0102-3.
  19. UNCTAD World Investment Report, Geneva: United Nations [annual, various issues]
  20. Dicken, Peter (January 2011). Global Shift: Mapping the Changing Contours of the World Economy. Guilford Press. ISBN   978-1-60918-006-5.