Relational contract

Last updated

A relational contract is a contract whose effect is based upon a relationship of trust between the parties. The explicit terms of a relational contract are an outline: implicit terms and understandings that determine the behaviour of the parties. Relational contract theory was originally developed in the United States by the legal scholars Ian Roderick Macneil and Stewart Macaulay. Richard Austen-Baker has more recently proposed a developed version of relational contract theory, called "comprehensive contract theory".

Contents

Ian Roderick Macneil's original theory

Relational contract theory was originally developed in the United States by the legal scholars Ian Roderick Macneil and Stewart Macaulay. According to Macneil, the theory offered a response to the so-called "The Death of Contract" school’s nihilistic argument that a contract was not a fit subject for study as a whole; each different type of contract (e.g., sales, employment, negotiable instruments) could be studied individually, but not "contracts-in-gross". [1] [2]

Macneil explains that this is only one of a number of possible relational theories of contracts, and accordingly renamed his own version "essential contract theory". [3]

Relational contract theory is characterized by a view of contracts as relations rather than as discrete transactions (which, Macneil argued, [4] traditional “classical” or "neo-classical contract" theory treats contracts as being). Thus, even a simple transaction can properly be understood as involving a wider social and economic context. For instance, if A purchases a packet of cigarettes from a shop he has never been into before and will never enter again, that seems quite discrete. However, A will almost certainly have a loyalty to a particular brand of cigarettes and expectations about quality about which he would be prepared to complain to the manufacturer, although he has no contractual privity with the manufacturer. There is also an understanding that A will pay for the cigarettes, not simply run off with them, and that if he tenders a £10 note in exchange for the cigarettes which are priced at £6, the paper money will be acceptable and change of £4 will be given. None of this is explicitly stated between the parties, whose conversation is likely limited to "20 Marlboro, please" on A's part and "That'll be £6, please" on the part of the retailer. Thus, even the simplest transaction has a good deal that is unstated and dependent on a wider web of social and economic relations. How far outwards into that web one needs to investigate will depend on the transaction and on the purpose for which it is being examined. [5]

Incentives play a large roll in the efficacy of a relational contract. If there were no relational contract where future compensation, performance or plans are only promised and not guaranteed, then there is very little incentive to honour the deal and perform. However, with a relational contract parties have incentive to provide quality goods/services as part of an ongoing relationship of good faith that will be beneficial to both parties. [6]

Although earlier writings [4] [7] may be taken in places to suggest that the substantive rules of contract law need to be reframed to acknowledge the relational, non-discrete nature of contracts, this has not been subsequently pursued and current scholars have argued that it is neither possible nor necessary to reform the law of contract itself to work effectively with relationally-constituted contracts. [8]

Other characteristics of relational contract theory are that "contract" is understood to cover economic exchange in general, not just contracts that would be recognized as legally enforceable agreements by courts in any given jurisdiction, that relations are mostly held together by their own internal values and wider social/economic factors, and, at least in relational theory in the Macneil mold, that exchange relations are governed by a number of norms. This last is not to say that relational contract theory is normative in nature, setting out what ought to be the case properly, but rather that there are actual observable normal characteristics or factors at play in relations. Macneil’s essential contract theory offers some 14 norms.[ citation needed ] These norms are as follows:

  1. role integrity
  2. reciprocity
  3. implementation of planning
  4. effectuation of consent
  5. flexibility
  6. contractual solidarity
  7. the ‘linking norms’
  8. the power norm
  9. propriety of means
  10. harmonisation with the social matrix
  11. enhancing discreteness and presentation
  12. preservation of the relation
  13. harmonisation of relational conflict
  14. supracontract norms.

Comprehensive contract theory

The English contracts scholar Richard Austen-Baker proposed in 2009 a developed version of relational contract theory, called "comprehensive contract theory", which posits four "comprehensive contract norms" in place of Macneil’s 14, though Austen-Baker does not deny the validity of Macneil’s norms as a complex tool of analysis. [9] While Austen-Baker appreciates Macneil's norms, the four that he proposes aims to eliminate the large amount of overlap seen in Macneil's version of the norms. Here the “comprehensive contract theory” norms have a much wider scope as to not extend over the other norms. These four norms are: [9]

  1. preservation of the relation
  2. harmonisation with the social matrix
  3. satisfying performance expectations
  4. substantial fairness.

As Austen-Baker builds his theory, developing Macneil's work a cross-over can be seen from the two lists of norms. This is norm one and two in “comprehensive contract theory”. While they have the same title the meaning changes from Macneil's work. The first norm, preservation of the relation pertains to the advantages gained through better relations. There are seven reasons that Austen-Baker gives, the first being that there is an increased cost in trying to find new customers as opposed to retaining existing ones. The second is that outside of existing relations transaction costs could be higher. Another point offered is that the inconvenience and cognitive effort of changing suppliers incentivises maintaining the relationship. Furthermore Austen-Baker explains the benefit of a long-term and meaningful relationship as parties will be better able to understand and advise each other for their specific needs. Some forms of business require high levels of trust which is hard to establish therefore encouraging relational contracts. Non-economic satisfactions also increase with the use of relational contracts, this could be seen as joy from going to a regular store and speaking with a manager that you know well. Finally, there is much greater stability gained through the longevity of a relationship. The second norm is the harmonisation with the social matrix, this norm seeks to encompass the use of every norm know to man to apply to contracts. It is unclear how much would be possible in a contract with this norm, therefore deters people from trying it. The third norm is satisfying the performance expectations, this explains how adequate or better performance is satisfactory however if you were to fail to meet the requirement you could be obliged to pay for any damages due to the reduced quality of work. Which in turn could tarnish the relationship. The final norm is substantial fairness, which is the equality of the relationship. If something is given then it would be fair for something to be given back in exchange, this does not have to be formal and could be inclusive of something like customary behaviour. [9]

The Japanese scholar Takashi Uchida has proposed a version of relational contract theory inspired by Macneil, relating it to the Japanese situation. [10] Other notable contributions to relational contract theory have been made by Stewart Macaulay (U.S.), [11] Lisa Bernstein (U.S.), [12] David Campbell (England) [13] and John Wightman (England). It is also worth mentioning the distinct approaches of Ronaldo Porto Macedo Jr. (Brazil), who has dealt with the theory in the field of consumer protection law, [14] [15] and Pedro Proscurcin (Brazil), who has introduced the theory of activity contracts in the field of labor law. [16] Still in the field of labor law, the most recent works of Douglas Brodie (Scotland), [17] [18] Hugh Collins (England) [19] and Anthony Davidson Gray (Australia) [20] deserve to be highlighted.

Recent research from World Commerce & Contracting, the University of Tennessee and Cirio law firm takes the relational contracting theories expressed by Macneil, Macaulay and others to make them relevant for contracting practitioners trying to craft strategic, collaborative, win-win relationships with their procurement and outsourced business partners. The white paper, outlines basic tenets that are foundational to relational contracting, including communication, risk allocation, problem-solving, no-blame culture, joint working, gain and pain sharing, mutual objectives, performance measurement and continuous improvement. [21]

In 2019, David Frydlinger, Oliver Hart and Kate Vitasek collaborated on a Harvard Business Review article, "A New Approach to Contracts: How to Build Better long-term strategic partnerships". The authors advocated for a “formal” relational contract, asserting that "a formal relational contract lays a foundation of trust, specifies mutual goals, and establishes governance structures to keep the parties’ expectations and interests aligned over time." [22]

Further research on relational contracting resulted in the 2021 book Contracting in the New Economy: Using Relational Contracts to Boost Trust and Collaboration in Strategic Business Relationships. The book argues for adopting formal relational contracts as an alternative to transactional contracts and suggests formal relational contracts are well suited for strategic, complex and highly dependent contractual relationships. The Nobel laureate Oliver Hart's foreword in the book notes, “…for a long time I have felt that the traditional approach to contracts, where lawyers try to think of all the possible things that can go wrong in a relationship and include contractual provisions to deal with them, is broken.” Hart added that it “never worked that well, and in an increasingly complex and uncertain world it works even worse.” [23]

The book provides a comprehensive review into the history and theory behind relational contracting and provides a practitioner’s perspective that includes a five-step process for developing a relational contract:

Examples of relational contracts

Construction examples

Other examples

See also

Related Research Articles

In economics, a transaction cost is a cost incurred when making an economic trade when participating in a market.

From a legal point of view, a contract is an institutional arrangement for the way in which resources flow, which defines the various relationships between the parties to a transaction or limits the rights and obligations of the parties.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Social structure</span> Sociological classification of human societies according to their social characteristics

In the social sciences, social structure is the aggregate of patterned social arrangements in society that are both emergent from and determinant of the actions of individuals. Likewise, society is believed to be grouped into structurally related groups or sets of roles, with different functions, meanings, or purposes. Examples of social structure include family, religion, law, economy, and class. It contrasts with "social system", which refers to the parent structure in which these various structures are embedded. Thus, social structures significantly influence larger systems, such as economic systems, legal systems, political systems, cultural systems, etc. Social structure can also be said to be the framework upon which a society is established. It determines the norms and patterns of relations between the various institutions of the society.

A psychological contract, a concept developed in contemporary research by organizational scholar Denise Rousseau, represents the mutual beliefs, perceptions, and informal obligations between an employer and an employee. It sets the dynamics for the relationship and defines the detailed practicality of the work to be done. It is distinguishable from the formal written contract of employment which, for the most part, only identifies mutual duties and responsibilities in a generalized form.

The theory of the firm consists of a number of economic theories that explain and predict the nature of the firm, company, or corporation, including its existence, behaviour, structure, and relationship to the market. Firms are key drivers in economics, providing goods and services in return for monetary payments and rewards. Organisational structure, incentives, employee productivity, and information all influence the successful operation of a firm in the economy and within itself. As such major economic theories such as transaction cost theory, managerial economics and behavioural theory of the firm will allow for an in-depth analysis on various firm and management types.

In economics, the hold-up problem is central to the theory of incomplete contracts, and shows the difficulty in writing complete contracts. A hold-up problem arises when two factors are present:

  1. Parties to a future transaction must make noncontractible relationship-specific investments before the transaction takes place.
  2. The specific form of the optimal transaction cannot be determined with certainty beforehand.
<span class="mw-page-title-main">Business-to-business</span> Commercial transaction between businesses

Business-to-business is a situation where one business makes a commercial transaction with another. This typically occurs when:

Tortious interference, also known as intentional interference with contractual relations, in the common law of torts, occurs when one person intentionally damages someone else's contractual or business relationships with a third party, causing economic harm. As an example, someone could use blackmail to induce a contractor into breaking a contract; they could threaten a supplier to prevent them from supplying goods or services to another party; or they could obstruct someone's ability to honor a contract with a client by deliberately refusing to deliver necessary goods.

New Institutional Economics (NIE) is an economic perspective that attempts to extend economics by focusing on the institutions that underlie economic activity and with analysis beyond earlier institutional economics and neoclassical economics.

Contract management or contract administration is the management of contracts made with customers, vendors, partners, or employees. Contract management includes negotiating the terms and conditions in contracts and ensuring compliance with the terms and conditions, as well as documenting and agreeing on any changes or amendments that may arise during its implementation or execution. It can be summarized as the process of systematically and efficiently managing contract creation, execution, and analysis for the purpose of maximizing financial and operational performance and minimizing risk.

Precarious work is a term that critics use to describe non-standard or temporary employment that may be poorly paid, insecure, unprotected, and unable to support a household. From this perspective, globalization, the shift from the manufacturing sector to the service sector, and the spread of information technology have created a new economy which demands flexibility in the workplace, resulting in the decline of the standard employment relationship, particularly for women. The characterization of temporary work as "precarious" is disputed by some scholars and entrepreneurs who see these changes as positive for individual workers. Precarious is work is ultimately a result of a profit driven capitalist organization of work in which employment is largely understood as a cost that needs to be reduced. The social and political consequences vary greatly in terms gender, age, race and class and result in varying degrees of inequality and freedom.

In the European Union, harmonisation of law is the process of creating common standards across the internal market. Though each EU member state has primary responsibility for the regulation of most matters within their jurisdiction, and consequently each has its own laws, harmonisation aims to:

The social norm of reciprocity is the expectation that people will respond to each other in similar ways—responding to gifts and kindnesses from others with similar benevolence of their own, and responding to harmful, hurtful acts from others with either indifference or some form of retaliation. Such norms can be crude and mechanical, such as a literal reading of the eye-for-an-eye rule lex talionis, or they can be complex and sophisticated, such as a subtle understanding of how anonymous donations to an international organization can be a form of reciprocity for the receipt of very personal benefits, such as the love of a parent.

Ian Roderick Macneil of Barra, The Macneil of Barra, Chief of Clan MacNeil, also known as Clan Niall and 26th of Barra, also Baron of Barra) was a Scottish American legal scholar.

Inequality of bargaining power in law, economics and social sciences refers to a situation where one party to a bargain, contract or agreement, has more and better alternatives than the other party. This results in one party having greater power than the other to choose not to take the deal and makes it more likely that this party will gain more favourable terms and grant them more negotiating power. Inequality of bargaining power is generally thought to undermine the freedom of contract, resulting in a disproportionate level of freedom between parties, and that it represents a place at which markets fail.

Vested outsourcing is a hybrid business model in which contracting parties create a formal relational contract using shared values and goals and outcome-based economics to create an agreement that is mutually beneficial for each party. The model was developed out of research by the University of Tennessee led by Kate Vitasek.

Economic opportunism is a term related to the subversion of morality to profit. There exists no agreed general, scientific definition or theory of economic opportunism; the literature usually considers only specific cases and contexts.

In economic theory, the field of contract theory can be subdivided in the theory of complete contracts and the theory of incomplete contracts.

Kate Vitasek is an American author and educator. She is a faculty member for Graduate and Executive Education at the University of Tennessee Haslam College of Business Her research focuses on the Vested outsourcing business model, sourcing business model theory, the relational contract, and collaborative win-win business relationships.

A legal relationship, jural relationship, or legal relation is a connection between two persons or other entities that is governed by law. A legal relationship may exist, for example, between two individuals or between an individual and a government. Legal relationships often imply rights and obligations. Examples of legal relationships include contracts, marriage, and citizenship. As with other fundamental legal concepts, many different ways of defining and classifying legal relationships have been put forward.

References

  1. I.R. Macneil, "Whither Contracts?" (1969) 21 Journal of Legal Education 403.
  2. John Kay (March 16, 2010), Think before you tear up an unwritten contract, Financial Times
  3. Macneil, I. R., "Contracting Worlds and Essential Contract Theory" (2000), Social & Legal Studies 9, 431.
  4. 1 2 Macneil, Ian R. (May 1974). "The Many Futures of Contract". Southern California Law Review. 47: 691–816.
  5. Macneil, I.R. (2003). "Reflections on Relational Contract Theory After a Neoclassical Seminar". In Collins, H.; Campbell, D.; Wightman, J. (eds.). The Implicit Dimensions of Contract. Oxford: Hart.[ ISBN missing ][ page needed ]
  6. Levin, Jonathan (1 May 2003). "Relational Incentive Contracts". American Economic Review. 93 (3): 835–857. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.295.8311 . doi:10.1257/000282803322157115. ProQuest   233027509.
  7. Macneil, Ian R. (1978). "Contracts: Adjustment of Long-Term Economic Relations under Classical, Neoclassical, and Relational Contract Law". Northwestern University Law Review. 72 (6): 854–905.
  8. Eisenberg, Melvin A. (Spring 2000). "Why there is no law of relational contracts". Northwestern University Law Review. 94 (3): 805–821.
  9. 1 2 3 Austen-Baker, R. (2009). "Comprehensive Contract Theory: A Four Norm Model of Contract Relations". Journal of Contract Law. 25 (3): 216–243.
  10. Uchida, T. (1993). "The New Development of Contract Law and General Clauses – A Japanese Perspective". Proceedings of the Symposium: Japanese and Dutch Laws Compared. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Centre for Comparative Law and Politics Institute of Comparative Law.[ ISBN missing ][ page needed ]
  11. Macaulay, Stewart (2000). "Relational Contracts Floating on a Sea of Custom? Thoughts About the Ideas of Ian Macneil and Lisa Bernstein". Northwestern University Law Review . 94: 775–804.
  12. Bernstein, Lisa (2015). "Beyond Relational Contracts: Social Capital and Network Governance in Procurement Contracts". Journal of Legal Analysis . 7 (2): 561–621. doi: 10.1093/jla/law001 .
  13. Campbell, David (May 2014). "Good Faith and the Ubiquity of the 'Relational' Contract". The Modern Law Review . 77 (3): 475–492. doi:10.1111/1468-2230.12075. ISSN   0026-7961.
  14. Macedo Jr., Ronaldo Porto (1998). Contratos relacionais e Defesa do Consumidor[RELATIONAL CONTRACTS AND CONSUMER DEFENSE] (1st ed.). Sao Paulo: Max Limonad. ISBN   9788520329764.
  15. Macedo Jr., Ronaldo (2003). "Relational Consumer Contracts: New Challenges for Brazilian Consumer Law". Social & Legal Studies. 12: 27–53. doi:10.1177/096466390301200102.
  16. Proscurcin, Pedro (2003). Do Contrato de Trabalho ao Contrato de Atividade: Nova Forma de Regulação das Atividades do Mercado de Trabalho[From Employment Contract to Activity Contract; A New Way of Regulating Labor Market Activities]. Sao Paulo: LTr editora. ISBN   978-8536104508.
  17. Brodie, Douglas (2011). "How Relational is the Employment Contract?". Industrial Law Journal . 40 (3): 232–253. doi:10.1093/indlaw/dwr009.
  18. Brodie, Douglas (2016). Relational contracts. In M. Freedland, A. Bogg, D. Cabrelli, H. Collins, N. Countouris, A. C. L. Davies, S. Deakin, & J. Prassl (Eds.), The Contract of Employment. Oxford University Press. ISBN   9780198783169.
  19. Collins, Hugh (2021). "Employment as a relational contract". Law Quarterly Review . 137.
  20. Gray, Anthony Davidson (September 2023). "Relational contract theory, the relevance of actual performance in contractual interpretation and its application to employment contracts in the United Kingdom and Australia". Common Law World Review. 52 (2–3): 61–100. doi: 10.1177/14737795231188384 . ISSN   1473-7795.
  21. Frydlinger, David; Cummins, Tim; Vitasek, Kate; Bergman, Jim (October 2016). Unpacking Relational Contracts: The Practitioner's Go-To Guide for Understanding Relational Contracts (PDF).
  22. Frydlinger, David; Hart, Oliver; Vitasek, Kate (1 September 2019). "A New Approach to Contracts". Harvard Business Review.
  23. 1 2 Frydlinger, David; Vitasek, Kate; Bergman, Jim; Cummins, Tim (2021). Contracting in the New Economy: Using Relational Contracts to Boost Trust and Collaboration in Strategic Business Relationships. Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN   978-3-030-65098-8.[ page needed ]
  24. Vitasek, Kate; et al. (2012). Vested: How P&G, McDonald's, and Microsoft are Redefining Winning in Business Relationships (1st ed.). New York: Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN   978-0230341708.
  25. Gerrard, R., Relational Contracts - NEC in Perspective, Lean Construction Journal, vol 2, #1, April 2015, archived 3 August 2019, accessed 6 February 2024
  26. Davies, G. and McQueen, N., High Court rules on key contractual issues in Post Office Group Litigation, Walker Morris, published 19 March 2019, accessed 6 February 2024