Untradable assets

Last updated

Untradable assets (or nontraded assets, nonmarketable assets, or perfectly nonliquid assets) are assets that are not traded on the market. [1] Human capital is the most important nontraded assets. [2] Other important nontraded asset classes are private businesses, claims to government transfer payments and claims on trust income. [3]

Contents

Human capital and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

Human capital is the stock of knowledge, habits and social and personality attributes. Its market value (discounted value) of future labour income (a measure of human capital) is greater than the total market value of traded assets. Human capital is also the nontraded asset that is most importable across time. Humans can only hedge their human capital using traded assets by borrowing against labour income (via home mortgages) and by reducing uncertainty via life insurance. However, these hedges are imperfect. Therefore, human capital pressures security prices and thus causes deviations from the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). [4]

Privately held businesses

The market value of privately held corporations and businesses is of a similar magnitude as the market value of human capital. However, privately held businesses can more easily hedged using marketable securities and thus are a lesser source of deviations from the CAPM. Privately held businesses have similar risk characteristics as traded assets. Therefore, individuals can partly offset the diversification problems caused by nontraded private businesses by altering their demands for similar, traded assets. [5]

However, the risks of private businesses do differ from those of traded securities. Therefore, a portfolio of traded assets that best hedges the risk of typical private businesses will enjoy excess demand from private business owners. This will cause the price of the assets in this portfolio to be bid up relative to the price predicted by the CAPM, causing a lower expected return in relation to systematic risk. Conversely, securities with risks highly correlated to the risks of private businesses will have high equilibrium risk premiums, causing a higher expected return in relation to systematic risk; or positive alphas. [6] This has been confirmed by empirical tests by Heaton and Lucas (2000). [7] Thus, private businesses can only be imperfectly hedged using traded securities and therefore still cause deviations from the CAPM. [8]

The Capital Asset Pricing Model adjusted for human capital

The original CAPM equation is [9]

Where is the expectations operator, is the end-of-period random yield on the jth asset, is the end-of-period random yield on the market portfolio and is one plus the riskless rate of return.

Mayers’ adjusted Capital Asset Pricing Model

Mayers (1972) has derived a CAPM for an economy in which nontraded assets exist; specifically, an economy in which individuals are endowed with human capital: labor income of varying size relative to their nonlabor income. [10] This model assumes riskless borrowing and lending, thus implying a linear form of the risk expected return relationship, as does the original CAPM. [11] The adjusted CAPM equation becomes, [12]

Where is the expectations operator, is the excess rate of return of the jth asset (), is the excess rate of return on the market, is the excess rate of return on aggregate human capital, is the value of aggregate human capital and is the market value of traded assets (the market portfolio).

In the adjusted CAPM, the beta – the measure of systematic risk – is replaced by an adjusted beta that also accounts for covariance with the portfolio of aggregate human capital. Thus, the model creates a wedge between betas measured against the traded, index portfolio and betas measured against the true market portfolio; the latter also includes human capital (as measured by aggregate labor income). This causes the results to differ in two respects.

First, if the is positive (as is expected), the adjusted beta is greater when the CAPM beta is smaller than 1 and vice versa. Thus, it is expected that the risk premium will be greater than predicted by the CAPM for securities with a beta less than one and smaller for securities with a beta greater than 1. This results in a less steep security market line (SML). The ratio of may be greater than one and thus likely has a significant economic effect. This may be an explanation for the average negative alpha of high-beta securities and positive alpha of low-beta securities that have been empirically found. [13]

Second, in the adjusted CAPM, the portfolios of maximizing investors are not all identical, as is the case in the original CAPM. [14]

Jagannathan and Wang’s adjusted Capital Asset Pricing Model

Jagannathan and Wang derived an adjusted CAPM where in addition to the beta of the value-weighted stock market index (), they also estimated the betas of assets with respect to labor income growth (). As a proxy for changes in the value of human capital they used the rate of change in aggregate labor income. [15] The resulting adjusted CAPM equation becomes

where is the market value of the firm's total equity

(Note: Jagannathan and Wang also added a beta reflecting the effect of business cycles on asset returns ().)

Related Research Articles

Financial economics is the branch of economics characterized by a "concentration on monetary activities", in which "money of one type or another is likely to appear on both sides of a trade". Its concern is thus the interrelation of financial variables, such as share prices, interest rates and exchange rates, as opposed to those concerning the real economy. It has two main areas of focus: asset pricing and corporate finance; the first being the perspective of providers of capital, i.e. investors, and the second of users of capital. It thus provides the theoretical underpinning for much of finance.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Capital asset pricing model</span> Model used in finance

In finance, the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) is a model used to determine a theoretically appropriate required rate of return of an asset, to make decisions about adding assets to a well-diversified portfolio.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Risk premium</span> Measure of excess

A risk premium is a measure of excess return that is required by an individual to compensate being subjected to an increased level of risk. It is used widely in finance and economics, the general definition being the expected risky return less the risk-free return, as demonstrated by the formula below.

Modern portfolio theory (MPT), or mean-variance analysis, is a mathematical framework for assembling a portfolio of assets such that the expected return is maximized for a given level of risk. It is a formalization and extension of diversification in investing, the idea that owning different kinds of financial assets is less risky than owning only one type. Its key insight is that an asset's risk and return should not be assessed by itself, but by how it contributes to a portfolio's overall risk and return. The variance of return is used as a measure of risk, because it is tractable when assets are combined into portfolios. Often, the historical variance and covariance of returns is used as a proxy for the forward-looking versions of these quantities, but other, more sophisticated methods are available.

In finance, arbitrage pricing theory (APT) is a multi-factor model for asset pricing which relates various macro-economic (systematic) risk variables to the pricing of financial assets. Proposed by economist Stephen Ross in 1976, it is widely believed to be an improved alternative to its predecessor, the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). APT is founded upon the law of one price, which suggests that within an equilibrium market, rational investors will implement arbitrage such that the equilibrium price is eventually realised. As such, APT argues that when opportunities for arbitrage are exhausted in a given period, then the expected return of an asset is a linear function of various factors or theoretical market indices, where sensitivities of each factor is represented by a factor-specific beta coefficient or factor loading. Consequently, it provides traders with an indication of ‘true’ asset value and enables exploitation of market discrepancies via arbitrage. The linear factor model structure of the APT is used as the basis for evaluating asset allocation, the performance of managed funds as well as the calculation of cost of capital. Furthermore, the newer APT model is more dynamic being utilised in more theoretical application than the preceding CAPM model. A 1986 article written by Gregory Connor and Robert Korajczyk, utilised the APT framework and applied it to portfolio performance measurement suggesting that the Jensen coefficient is an acceptable measurement of portfolio performance.

In finance, the beta is a statistic that measures the expected increase or decrease of an individual stock price in proportion to movements of the stock market as a whole. Beta can be used to indicate the contribution of an individual asset to the market risk of a portfolio when it is added in small quantity. It refers to an asset's non-diversifiable risk, systematic risk, or market risk. Beta is not a measure of idiosyncratic risk.

In finance, Jensen's alpha is used to determine the abnormal return of a security or portfolio of securities over the theoretical expected return. It is a version of the standard alpha based on a theoretical performance instead of a market index.

Alpha is a measure of the active return on an investment, the performance of that investment compared with a suitable market index. An alpha of 1% means the investment's return on investment over a selected period of time was 1% better than the market during that same period; a negative alpha means the investment underperformed the market. Alpha, along with beta, is one of two key coefficients in the capital asset pricing model used in modern portfolio theory and is closely related to other important quantities such as standard deviation, R-squared and the Sharpe ratio.

The single-index model (SIM) is a simple asset pricing model to measure both the risk and the return of a stock. The model has been developed by William Sharpe in 1963 and is commonly used in the finance industry. Mathematically the SIM is expressed as:

Within mathematical finance, the intertemporal capital asset pricing model, or ICAPM, is an alternative to the CAPM provided by Robert Merton. It is a linear factor model with wealth as state variable that forecasts changes in the distribution of future returns or income.

The consumption-based capital asset pricing model (CCAPM) is a model of the determination of expected return on an investment. The foundations of this concept were laid by the research of Robert Lucas (1978) and Douglas Breeden (1979).

In corporate finance, Hamada’s equation is an equation used as a way to separate the financial risk of a levered firm from its business risk. The equation combines the Modigliani–Miller theorem with the capital asset pricing model. It is used to help determine the levered beta and, through this, the optimal capital structure of firms. It was named after Robert Hamada, the Professor of Finance behind the theory.

Roll's critique is a famous analysis of the validity of empirical tests of the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) by Richard Roll. It concerns methods to formally test the statement of the CAPM, the equation

A portfolio manager (PM) is a professional responsible for making investment decisions and carrying out investment activities on behalf of vested individuals or institutions. Clients invest their money into the PM's investment policy for future growth, such as a retirement fund, endowment fund, or education fund. PMs work with a team of analysts and researchers and are responsible for establishing an investment strategy, selecting appropriate investments, and allocating each investment properly towards an investment fund or asset management vehicle.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Security characteristic line</span>

Security characteristic line (SCL) is a regression line, plotting performance of a particular security or portfolio against that of the market portfolio at every point in time. The SCL is plotted on a graph where the Y-axis is the excess return on a security over the risk-free return and the X-axis is the excess return of the market in general. The slope of the SCL is the security's beta, and the intercept is its alpha.

Downside risk is the financial risk associated with losses. That is, it is the risk of the actual return being below the expected return, or the uncertainty about the magnitude of that difference.

In finance, active return refers the returns produced by an investment portfolio due to active management decisions made by the portfolio manager that cannot be explained by the portfolio's exposure to returns or to risks in the portfolio's investment benchmark; active return is usually the objective of active management and subject of performance attribution. In contrast, passive returns refers to returns produced by an investment portfolio due to its exposure to returns of its benchmark. Passive returns can be obtained deliberately through passive tracking of the portfolio benchmark or obtained inadvertently through an investment process unrelated to tracking the index.

Returns-based style analysis (RBSA) is a statistical technique used in finance to deconstruct the returns of investment strategies using a variety of explanatory variables. The model results in a strategy's exposures to asset classes or other factors, interpreted as a measure of a fund or portfolio manager's investment style. While the model is most frequently used to show an equity mutual fund’s style with reference to common style axes, recent applications have extended the model’s utility to model more complex strategies, such as those employed by hedge funds.

In investing, downside beta is the beta that measures a stock's association with the overall stock market (risk) only on days when the market’s return is negative. Downside beta was first proposed by Roy 1952 and then popularized in an investment book by Markowitz (1959).

In investing, upside beta is the element of traditional beta that investors do not typically associate with the true meaning of risk. It is defined to be the scaled amount by which an asset tends to move compared to a benchmark, calculated only on days when the benchmark's return is positive.

References

  1. Bodie, Z., Kane, A. and Marcus, A. J., 2014. Investments. McGraw-Hill Education: Berkshire.
  2. Mayers, D., 1973. Nonmarketable Assets and the Determination of Capital Asset Prices in the Absence of a Riskless Asset, The Journal of Business, Vol. 46, No.2, pp. 258-267. The University of Chicago Press: Chicago.
  3. Bodie, Z., Kane, A. and Marcus, A. J., 2014. Investments. McGraw-Hill Education: Berkshire.
  4. Bodie, Z., Kane, A. and Marcus, A. J., 2014. Investments. McGraw-Hill Education: Berkshire.
  5. Bodie, Z., Kane, A. and Marcus, A. J., 2014. Investments. McGraw-Hill Education: Berkshire.
  6. Bodie, Z., Kane, A. and Marcus, A. J., 2014. Investments. McGraw-Hill Education: Berkshire.
  7. Heaton, J. and Lucas, D., 2000. Portfolio Choice and Asset Prices: The Importance of Entrepreneurial Risk, Journal of Finance, Vol. 55, No.3, pp. 1163-98.
  8. Bodie, Z., Kane, A. and Marcus, A. J., 2014. Investments. McGraw-Hill Education: Berkshire.
  9. Mayers, D., 1973. Nonmarketable Assets and the Determination of Capital Asset Prices in the Absence of a Riskless Asset, The Journal of Business, Vol. 46, No.2, pp. 258-267. The University of Chicago Press: Chicago.
  10. Mayers, D., 1972. Nonmarketable assets and capital market equilibrium under uncertainty. Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, Ed. Michael C. Jensen, pp. 223-48.
  11. Mayers, D., 1973. Nonmarketable Assets and the Determination of Capital Asset Prices in the Absence of a Riskless Asset, The Journal of Business, Vol. 46, No.2, pp. 258-267.
  12. Bodie, Z., Kane, A. and Marcus, A. J., 2014. Investments. McGraw-Hill Education: Berkshire.
  13. Bodie, Z., Kane, A. and Marcus, A. J., 2014. Investments. McGraw-Hill Education: Berkshire.
  14. Mayers, D., 1973. Nonmarketable Assets and the Determination of Capital Asset Prices in the Absence of a Riskless Asset, The Journal of Business, Vol. 46, No.2, pp. 258-267.
  15. Jagannathan, R. and Wang, Z., 1996. The conditional CAPM and the cross‐section of expected returns. The Journal of Finance, 51(1), pp.3-53.