Macmillan Committee

Last updated

The Macmillan Committee, officially known as the Committee on Finance and Industry, was a committee, composed mostly of economists, formed by the British government after the 1929 stock market crash to determine the root causes of the depressed economy of the United Kingdom. [1] The Macmillan Committee was formed in 1929 by Royal Command 3897, [1] and it was tasked with determining whether the contemporary banking and financial system was helping or hindering British trade and industry. [2] Scottish lawyer Hugh Pattison Macmillan was named as its chairman, although due to his lack of economic or financial expertise, he largely "remained in the background". [3] Other members of the committee included Ernest Bevin, Lord Bradbury, R. H. Brand, Theodore Gregory, John Maynard Keynes, and Reginald McKenna. [2]

The committee took evidence from many leading economists of the day, such as Arthur Cecil Pigou, D. H. Robertson and Lionel Robbins, on the subject of unemployment. It decided in favour of the so-called Treasury view that expenditure on public works was not the answer, in spite of the signing of Addendum 1 by some of its leading members. This addendum, which was signed by Keynes, A.A.G. Tullock, J. Frater Taylor, Sir T. Allen, Ernest Bevin and R. McKenna, advocated a programme of public works and import restrictions. However the committee insisted that monetary policy should be concerned with 'the maintenance of the parity of the foreign exchanges before the avoidance of the credit cycle and the stability of the price level.' [4] The committee published its findings and recommendations in the Report of Committee on Finance and Industry, or more simply, the Macmillan Report, in 1931. [5]

The Macmillan Report "served as a venue in which J. M. Keynes challenged the 'Treasury View'", according to economist Friedrich von Hayek. [5] The report was largely authored by Keynes, and it recommended several Keynesian policies such as nationalization of the Bank of England and government regulation of international trade. [6] Historian Charles Loch Mowat characterized these recommendations as "cautious" and said that, by the time of its publication, they "had been almost overtaken by events". [2] Its members disagreed on some points and one member dissented on its findings. These opinions and reservations were included in the report's extensive addenda. [1]

The report also asserted that "the relations between the British financial world and British industry ... have never been so close as" those respective relationships in Germany and those in the United States. From this conclusion arose the term the "Macmillan Gap". [7] As such, many Britons felt that their banks were failing their industrial base. This view did not consider the balance that banking institutions needed to strike between their depositors, who desired high interest rates and liquidity, and their debtors, that is, those in industry, who desired low-interest loans that could not be recalled quickly. [7] Investments of relatively small amounts of money were riskier and more costly for lenders, which put small businesses seeking loans at a disadvantage. [8] While the report dedicated only 300 words to such a disparity, [9] the term Macmillan Gap is the most enduring part of the report. [8] It was also one of the few recommendations which were acted upon. In response to the committee's suggestion, an institution was created to finance small businesses: [9] the Industrial and Commercial Finance Corporation. [10]

The maintenance of the exchange rate was agreed to be the first priority by all, including the signatories of Addendum 1. Two months after the report was published the UK came off the Gold Standard and the exchange rate depreciated immediately by 2% and continued downwards for 12 months.

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Friedrich Hayek</span> Austrian–British economist, philosopher, Nobel Laureate

Friedrich August von Hayek, often referred to by his initials F. A. Hayek, was an Austrian-British economist and political philosopher who made contributions to economics, political philosophy, psychology, intellectual history, and other fields. Hayek shared the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences with Gunnar Myrdal for work on money and economic fluctuations, and the interdependence of economic, social and institutional phenomena. His account of how prices communicate information is widely regarded as an important contribution to economics that led to him receiving the prize.

Keynesian economics are the various macroeconomic theories and models of how aggregate demand strongly influences economic output and inflation. In the Keynesian view, aggregate demand does not necessarily equal the productive capacity of the economy. It is influenced by a host of factors that sometimes behave erratically and impact production, employment, and inflation.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">John Maynard Keynes</span> British economist (1883–1946)

John Maynard Keynes, 1st Baron Keynes was an English economist and philosopher whose ideas fundamentally changed the theory and practice of macroeconomics and the economic policies of governments. Originally trained in mathematics, he built on and greatly refined earlier work on the causes of business cycles. One of the most influential economists of the 20th century, he produced writings that are the basis for the school of thought known as Keynesian economics, and its various offshoots. His ideas, reformulated as New Keynesianism, are fundamental to mainstream macroeconomics. He is known as the "father of macroeconomics".

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Piero Sraffa</span> Italian economist (1898–1983)

Piero Sraffa, FBA was an influential Italian economist who served as lecturer of economics at the University of Cambridge. His book Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities is taken as founding the neo-Ricardian school of economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Arthur Cecil Pigou</span> English economist (1877–1959)

Arthur Cecil Pigou was an English economist. As a teacher and builder of the School of Economics at the University of Cambridge, he trained and influenced many Cambridge economists who went on to take chairs of economics around the world. His work covered various fields of economics, particularly welfare economics, but also included business cycle theory, unemployment, public finance, index numbers, and measurement of national output. His reputation was affected adversely by influential economic writers who used his work as the basis on which to define their own opposing views. He reluctantly served on several public committees, including the Cunliffe Committee and the 1919 Royal Commission on income tax.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">William Beveridge</span> British Liberal politician, economist, and social reformer

William Henry Beveridge, 1st Baron Beveridge, was a British economist and Liberal politician who was a progressive and social reformer who played a central role in designing the British welfare state. His 1942 report Social Insurance and Allied Services served as the basis for the welfare state put in place by the Labour government elected in 1945.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Jacob Viner</span> Canadian economist

Jacob Viner was a Canadian economist and is considered with Frank Knight and Henry Simons to be one of the "inspiring" mentors of the early Chicago school of economics in the 1930s: he was one of the leading figures of the Chicago faculty. Paul Samuelson named Viner as one of the several "American saints in economics" born after 1860. He was an important figure in the field of political economy.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Lionel Robbins</span> British economist (1898–1984)

Lionel Charles Robbins, Baron Robbins, was a British economist, and prominent member of the economics department at the London School of Economics (LSE). He is known for his leadership at LSE, his proposed definition of economics, and for his instrumental efforts in shifting Anglo-Saxon economics from its Marshallian direction. He is famous for the quote, "Humans want what they can't have."

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Colin Clark (economist)</span> British and Australian economist and statistician

Colin Grant Clark was a British and Australian economist and statistician who worked in both the United Kingdom and Australia. He pioneered the use of gross national product (GNP) as the basis for studying national economies.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Abba P. Lerner</span> Russian-British economist (1903–1982)

Abraham "Abba" Ptachya Lerner was a Russian-born American-British economist.

Gibson's paradox is the observation that the rate of interest and the general level of prices under the gold standard are positively correlated. It is named for British economist Alfred Herbert Gibson who noted the correlation in a 1923 article for Banker's Magazine. The correlation had been noted earlier by Thomas Tooke.

Events from the year 1931 in the United Kingdom.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">2008–2009 Keynesian resurgence</span> Great Recession-era revival of interest in aggregate demand-side economics

Following the global financial crisis of 2007–2008, there was a worldwide resurgence of interest in Keynesian economics among prominent economists and policy makers. This included discussions and implementation of economic policies in accordance with the recommendations made by John Maynard Keynes in response to the Great Depression of the 1930s, most especially fiscal stimulus and expansionary monetary policy.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Keynesian Revolution</span> Economic theory

The Keynesian Revolution was a fundamental reworking of economic theory concerning the factors determining employment levels in the overall economy. The revolution was set against the then orthodox economic framework, namely neoclassical economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Post-war displacement of Keynesianism</span>

The post-war displacement of Keynesianism was a series of events which from mostly unobserved beginnings in the late 1940s, had by the early 1980s led to the replacement of Keynesian economics as the leading theoretical influence on economic life in the developed world. Similarly, the allied discipline known as development economics was largely displaced as the guiding influence on economic policies adopted by developing nations.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Tony Thirlwall</span> British economist (1941–2023)

Anthony Philip Thirlwall was a British economist who was Professor of Applied Economics at the University of Kent. He made major contributions to regional economics; the analysis of unemployment and inflation; balance of payments theory, and to growth and development economics with particular reference to developing countries. He was the author of the bestselling textbook Economics of Development: Theory and Evidence now in its ninth edition. He was also the biographer and literary executor of the famous Cambridge economist Nicholas Kaldor. Perhaps his most notable contribution was to show that if long-run balance of payments equilibrium is a requirement for a country, its growth of national income can be approximated by the ratio of the growth of exports to the income elasticity of demand for imports.

Henry Higgs was a British civil servant, economist, and historian of economic thought.

In the United Kingdom, the interwar period (1918–1939) entered a period of relative stability after the Partition of Ireland, although it was also characterised by economic stagnation. In politics, the Liberal Party collapsed and the Labour Party became the main challenger to the dominant Conservative Party throughout the period. The Great Depression affected Britain less severely economically and politically than other major nations, although some areas still suffered from severe long-term unemployment and hardship, especially mining districts and in Scotland and North West England.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Tyler Goodspeed</span> American economist

Tyler Beck Goodspeed is an American economist and economic historian who was the acting chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers from June 2020 to January 2021. He resigned from his position on January 7 in the wake of the 2021 storming of the United States Capitol.

<i>Britains Industrial Future</i>

Britain's Industrial Future, commonly known as the Yellow Book, was the report of the British Liberal Party's Industrial Inquiry of 1928.

References

  1. 1 2 3 J. C. Stamp, The Report of the Macmillan Committee, The Economic Journal , pp. 424–435, Vol. 41, No. 163, September 1931.
  2. 1 2 3 Charles Loch Mowat, Britain Between the Wars: 1918-1940, pp. 260–261, Taylor & Francis, 1978, ISBN   0-416-29510-X.
  3. Donald Edward Moggridge, Maynard Keynes: An Economist's Biography, p. 510, Routledge, 1992, ISBN   0-415-05141-X.
  4. The Penguin Dictionary of Economics George Bannock, R. E. Baxter and Evan Davis. 5th Edition. Penguin Books 1992.
  5. 1 2 Friedrich A. von Hayek, The Road to Serfdom , pp. 66–67, University of Chicago Press, 1944.
  6. Philip Williamson, National Crisis and National Government, pp. 255–258, Cambridge University Press, 2003, ISBN   0-521-52141-6.
  7. 1 2 Chris Wrigley, A Companion to Early Twentieth-Century Britain, pp. 250-251, Wiley-Blackwell, 2003, ISBN   0-631-21790-8.
  8. 1 2 W. A. Thomas, The Finance of British Industry 1918–1976, pp. 117–118, Taylor & Francis, 2006, ISBN   0-415-37862-1.
  9. 1 2 Raymond Frost, The Macmillan Gap 1931-53, Oxford Economic Papers, Oxford University Press, p. 1.
  10. M. M. Postan, An Economic History of Western Europe: 1945-1964, p. 122, Taylor & Francis, 2006, ISBN   0-415-37921-0.