Turnpike theory

Last updated

Turnpike theory refers to a set of economic theories about the optimal path of accumulation (often capital accumulation) in a system, depending on the initial and final levels. In the context of a macroeconomic exogenous growth model, for example, it says that if an infinite optimal path is calculated, and an economic planner wishes to move an economy from one level of capital to another, as long as the planner has sufficient time, the most efficient path is to quickly move the level of capital stock to a level close to the infinite optimal path, and to allow capital to develop along that path until it is nearly the end of the desired term and the planner must move the capital stock to the desired final level. The name of the theory refers to the idea that a turnpike is the fastest route between two points which are far apart, even if it is not the most direct route.

Contents

Origins

Although the idea can be traced back to John von Neumann in 1945, [1] Lionel W. McKenzie traces the term to Robert Dorfman, Paul Samuelson, and Robert Solow's Linear Programming and Economic Analysis in 1958, referring to an American English word for a Highway:

Thus in this unexpected way, we have found a real normative significance for steady growth—not steady growth in general, but maximal von Neumann growth. It is, in a sense, the single most effective way for the system to grow, so that if we are planning long-run growth, no matter where we start, and where we desire to end up, it will pay in the intermediate stages to get into a growth phase of this kind. It is exactly like a turnpike paralleled by a network of minor roads. There is a fastest route between any two points; and if the origin and destination are close together and far from the turnpike, the best route may not touch the turnpike. But if the origin and destination are far enough apart, it will always pay to get on to the turnpike and cover distance at the best rate of travel, even if this means adding a little mileage at either end. The best intermediate capital configuration is one which will grow most rapidly, even if it is not the desired one, it is temporarily optimal. [2]

The theorem was subsequently proved for various versions. [3] [4] [5] [6] [7]

Variations

McKenzie in 1976 published a review of the idea up to that point. He saw three general variations of turnpike theories. [8]

Applications

The theorem has many applications in optimal control and in a general equilibrium context. In general equilibrium, the variation which involves infinite capital accumulation paths can be applied. In a system with many infinitely lived agents with the same (small) discount rates on the future, regardless of initial endowments, the equilibrium allocations of all agents converge. [10] [11]

Although studies on the turnpike theorem are mostly theoretical, Tsukui's work [12] is a notable exception. He empirically implemented the theorem using actual input-output data for Japan, and the resulting model was used for planning purposes by the Japanese government. [13]

Related Research Articles

In economics, general equilibrium theory attempts to explain the behavior of supply, demand, and prices in a whole economy with several or many interacting markets, by seeking to prove that the interaction of demand and supply will result in an overall general equilibrium. General equilibrium theory contrasts with the theory of partial equilibrium, which analyzes a specific part of an economy while its other factors are held constant. In general equilibrium, constant influences are considered to be noneconomic, or in other words, considered to be beyond the scope of economic analysis. The noneconomic influences may change given changes in the economic factors however, and therefore the prediction accuracy of an equilibrium model may depend on the independence of the economic factors from noneconomic ones.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Kenneth Arrow</span> American economist (1921–2017)

Kenneth Joseph Arrow was an American economist, mathematician, writer, and political theorist. Along with John Hicks, he won the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1972.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Gérard Debreu</span> French economist and mathematician

Gérard Debreu was a French-born economist and mathematician. Best known as a professor of economics at the University of California, Berkeley, where he began work in 1962, he won the 1983 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Michio Morishima</span>

Michio Morishima was a Japanese heterodox economist and public intellectual who was the Sir John Hicks Professor of Economics at the London School of Economics from 1970 to 1988. He was also professor at Osaka University and member of the British Academy. In 1976 he won the Order of Culture.

The overlapping generations (OLG) model is one of the dominating frameworks of analysis in the study of macroeconomic dynamics and economic growth. In contrast to the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans neoclassical growth model in which individuals are infinitely-lived, in the OLG model individuals live a finite length of time, long enough to overlap with at least one period of another agent's life.

In economics, the Golden Rule savings rate is the rate of savings which maximizes steady state level of the growth of consumption, as for example in the Solow–Swan model. Although the concept can be found earlier in the work of John von Neumann and Maurice Allais, the term is generally attributed to Edmund Phelps who wrote in 1961 that the golden rule "do unto others as you would have them do unto you" could be applied inter-generationally inside the model to arrive at some form of "optimum", or put simply "do unto future generations as we hope previous generations did unto us."

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Bid shading</span> Bidding less than an item is worth in an auction

In an auction, bid shading is the practice of a bidder placing a bid that is below what they believe a bid is worth.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Hirofumi Uzawa</span> Japanese economist (1928–2014)

Hirofumi Uzawa was a Japanese economist.

In game theory, folk theorems are a class of theorems describing an abundance of Nash equilibrium payoff profiles in repeated games. The original Folk Theorem concerned the payoffs of all the Nash equilibria of an infinitely repeated game. This result was called the Folk Theorem because it was widely known among game theorists in the 1950s, even though no one had published it. Friedman's (1971) Theorem concerns the payoffs of certain subgame-perfect Nash equilibria (SPE) of an infinitely repeated game, and so strengthens the original Folk Theorem by using a stronger equilibrium concept: subgame-perfect Nash equilibria rather than Nash equilibria.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">David Cass</span> American economist

David Cass was a professor of economics at the University of Pennsylvania, mostly known for his contributions to general equilibrium theory. His most famous work was on the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model of economic growth.

The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model, or Ramsey growth model, is a neoclassical model of economic growth based primarily on the work of Frank P. Ramsey, with significant extensions by David Cass and Tjalling Koopmans. The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model differs from the Solow–Swan model in that the choice of consumption is explicitly microfounded at a point in time and so endogenizes the savings rate. As a result, unlike in the Solow–Swan model, the saving rate may not be constant along the transition to the long run steady state. Another implication of the model is that the outcome is Pareto optimal or Pareto efficient.

Lionel Wilfred McKenzie was an American economist. He was the Wilson Professor Emeritus of Economics at the University of Rochester. He was born in Montezuma, Georgia. He completed undergraduate studies at Duke University in 1939 and subsequently moved to Oxford that year as a Rhodes Scholar. McKenzie worked with the Cowles Commission while it was in Chicago and served as an assistant professor at Duke from 1948 to 1957. Having received his Ph.D. at Princeton University in 1956, McKenzie moved to Rochester where he was responsible for the establishment of the graduate program in economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Artyom Shneyerov</span> Canadian economist

Artyom Shneyerov is a microeconomist working at Concordia University in Montreal, Quebec, Canada. He is also an associate editor of the International Journal of Industrial Organization. His current research is in the fields of game theory, industrial organization and applied econometrics. His contributions to these and other areas of economics include the following:

Mathematical economics is the application of mathematical methods to represent theories and analyze problems in economics. Often, these applied methods are beyond simple geometry, and may include differential and integral calculus, difference and differential equations, matrix algebra, mathematical programming, or other computational methods. Proponents of this approach claim that it allows the formulation of theoretical relationships with rigor, generality, and simplicity.

Optimal capital income taxation is a subarea of optimal tax theory which studies the design of taxes on capital income such that a given economic criterion like utility is optimized.

Hukukane Nikaido was a Japanese economist.

Edi Karni is an Israeli born American economist and decision theorist. Karni is the Scott and Barbara Black Professor of Economics at Johns Hopkins University. He is a Fellow of the Econometric Society and an Economic Theory Fellow of the Society for the Advancement of Economic Theory.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Makoto Yano</span> Japanese economist (born 1952)

Makoto Yano is a Japanese economist, currently the president and chief research officer of the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry. He is also a professor emeritus at Kyoto University and a professor by special appointment at Kyoto University's Institute of Economic Research and Sophia University.

Kim C. Border was an American behavioral economist and professor of economics at the California Institute of Technology.

Joel Sobel is an American economist and currently professor of economics at the University of California, San Diego. His research focuses on game theory and has been seminal in the field of strategic communication in economic games. His work with Vincent Crawford established the game-theoretic concept of cheap talk.

References

  1. Neumann, J. V. (1945–46). "A Model of General Economic Equilibrium". Review of Economic Studies . 13 (1): 1–9. doi:10.2307/2296111. JSTOR   2296111.
  2. Dorfman; Samuelson; Solow (1958). "Efficient Programs of Capital Accumulation". Linear Programming and Economic Analysis . New York: McGraw Hill. p.  331.
  3. McKenzie, Lionel W. (October 1963). "The Turnpike Theorem of Morishima". The Review of Economic Studies. 30 (3): 169. doi:10.2307/2296317. ISSN   0034-6527.
  4. Morishima, M. (February 1961). "Proof of a Turnpike Theorem: The "No Joint Production" Case". The Review of Economic Studies. 28 (2): 89. doi:10.2307/2295706. ISSN   0034-6527.
  5. Nikaidô, Hukukane (1964). "Persistence of Continual Growth Near the von Neumann Ray: A Strong Version of the Radner Turnpike Theorem". Econometrica. 32 (1/2): 151–162. doi:10.2307/1913740. ISSN   0012-9682.
  6. Atsumi, Hiroshi (April 1965). "Neoclassical Growth and the Efficient Program of Capital Accumulation". The Review of Economic Studies. 32 (2): 127. doi:10.2307/2296057.
  7. Tsukui, Jinkichi (1966). "Turnpike Theorem in a Generalized Dynamic Input-Output System". Econometrica. 34 (2): 396–407. doi:10.2307/1909940. ISSN   0012-9682.
  8. McKenzie, Lionel (1976). "Turnpike Theory". Econometrica . 44 (5): 841–865. doi:10.2307/1911532. JSTOR   1911532.
  9. A review of different variations in the theory can be found in McKenzie, Lionel (1976). "Turnpike Theory". Econometrica . 44 (5): 841–865. doi:10.2307/1911532. JSTOR   1911532.
  10. Bewley, Truman (1982). "An Integration of Equilibrium Theory and Turnpike Theory" (PDF). Journal of Mathematical Economics . 10 (2–3): 233–267. doi:10.1016/0304-4068(82)90039-8.
  11. Yano, Makoto (1984). "The Turnpike of Dynamic General Equilibrium Paths in Its Insensitivity to Initial Conditions". Journal of Mathematical Economics. 13 (3): 235–254. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.295.3005 . doi:10.1016/0304-4068(84)90032-6.
  12. Tsukui, Jinkichi (1968). "Application of a Turnpike Theorem to Planning for Efficient Accumulation: An Example for Japan". Econometrica. 36 (1): 172–186. doi:10.2307/1909611. ISSN   0012-9682.
  13. Shiniji Yoshioka and Hirofumi Kawasaki, Japan's High-Growth Postwar Period: The Role of Economic Plans, ESRI Research Note No. 27, Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office, Tokyo, Japan https://www.esri.cao.go.jp/jp/esri/archive/e_rnote/e_rnote030/e_rnote027.pdf