China's Rural Reform

Last updated

China's Rural Reform (also called Agricultural Reform) was one of the multiple Chinese reforms implemented in China in 1978. The reforms were initiated by Deng Xiaoping, the leader of the Chinese Communist Party at the time.

Contents

The reform in the agricultural sector was the first to be introduced which resulted in China meeting 4 objectives :

Background

With the crisis of food shortages that resulted from the two Chinese revolutions and the rapidly growing population, a reform was needed that could ensure stable production of food. However, the pace of reforms was very slow. With the aim of surpassing Great Britain and catching up with America, the Great Leap Forward led by Mao Zedong from 1958 to 1962 focused on heavy industry. [2] Producing steel to make military equipment became the highest priority and other economic sectors related to the improvement of livelihood of the people such as agriculture and light industry were undervalued. To boost the spirit and morale of the people, exaggerated yields were reported. This led to the Great Chinese Famine in 1959 - one of the most deadly famines in history. According to research led by Yang Jisheng, an estimated 36 million people died of starvation during the famine period, while other western researchers approximate the casualties to be as high as 45 million. [3]

To regain power, momentum and consolidate his communist ideology within the party, Mao Zedong initiated the ten-year Cultural Revolution in 1966. Anything associated with capitalism or traditional values were removed. Millions of people fled due to the instability of the country. The 10-year movement crippled the country both politically and economically. The economy was stagnant and countless people died. Moreover, due to Zedong's belief that prosperity of the country comes with a greater population, he encouraged couples to have more children. According to statistics from World Bank, the fertility rate of China peaked in 1966, with each woman giving birth to an average of 6.37 children. [4] This increased birth rate resulted in a 2.78% population growth in 1966, the highest annual growth in China's history. [5] The population growth combined with the stagnant economy resulted in food shortages, which became the rationale for the rural reform.

Before the reform

The Beidaihe conference in 1958 affirmed the centralization of agricultural production. [6] The people's right to own private properties were removed and people's commune became the production unit in the rural area. Prior to the reform, households were divided into collective production units, in which families worked together as a team. As it was difficult to monitor the performance of each person, yields were equally divided among households, disregarding the different degrees of efforts individuals put in. This resulted in low incentives for the farmers to work hard, which led to slacking and inefficiency in production. [7]

Cause of the reform

In the beginning, the agricultural reform was not intended or initiated by the Chinese government, rather, it was initiated by 18 households in Xiaogang Village, Fengyang Xian, Anhui Province. [7] In 1978, Fengyang Xian experienced a serious drought. To overcome the problem, they came up with an arrangement where each household was responsible for their own production. Farming tools and land were equally distributed among the households in return for delivery of fixed output quotas. [8] Each member had the free will to decide which types of crops to grow and they were entitled to sell excess yields in the free market. They were also expected to deal with whatever losses they suffered on their own. This was the prototype of the household responsibility system. This arrangement was completely against the values of the Communist Party, and the villagers could have been prosecuted for it. Because of this, the arrangement was kept a secret without the awareness of higher officials. The arrangement turned out to be successful and soon spread to other parts of Anhui Province and Sichuan Province.

In 1980, Deng Xiaoping publicly announced his endorsement of such policy and this officially began the enforcement of the rural reform.

Reforms in different sectors

Institution

After the Household Responsibility System was introduced, the collective-farming policy was discarded. The original collectively owned land was reassigned to two or more and their autonomy of production and operation was guaranteed. The farmers were allowed to produce by themselves and were expected to be responsible for their own earnings and losses. They were only required to submit part of the yield as taxes to the government and were entitled to sell the excess gains in the free market. Such institutional reform significantly raised their willingness to work hard and produce a greater yield. With the year of 1978 as the reference point of 100, the crop output increased from 77.10 in 1970 to 148.21 in 1987; the crop output saw an increase of 48.21% in 9 years. [9]

Market and Planning

As the total crop output increased, there was an excess of grains. This excess decreased the market price of the products. Consequently, the government encouraged farmers in grain-sufficient areas to invest in cash crops such as cotton and sugarcane. The area devoted to cash crops increased from 9.6% in 1978 to 13.4% in 1984; a 41.6% increase. [9] The government also encouraged the development of township enterprises that emphasized branding and developing special features. Villages and towns discovered their advantages and focused on specialization in producing specific products. The increase in capital and the use of chemical fertilizers indicated the prevalence of commercialization and agricultural mechanization, which also explains the gradual decrease in farm labor after 1984. As the agricultural production line was increasingly automated, the excess farming labor was released from the rural area into the city to aid in urban development.

Solution

The pragmatic modernists reformed the Chinese economy to guarantee an outflow of surplus value from agriculture to finance the modernization of industry and expansion and modernization of infrastructure (mostly in urban areas). Today and for the entire reform era, the percentage of social investment going to agriculture has been a fraction of the amount of surplus generated in that sector (and less than 2% of the total). According to Fang Gang, writing in the China Rural Survey, "If agriculture's share of national investment were to be brought in line with its share of national income, farm investment would have to rise to over 300 billion yuan (at 1994 prices), or to ten times its current level." [10] In order to raise agricultural productivity surplus investments would be required to be made to improve agriculture from presumably from industry , but the result would be a slowdown in the modernization of industry (with the concomitant slowdown in productivity improvements and "competitiveness" in that sector). Trade related competition will take its toll, either in agriculture or industry or both.

Related Research Articles

Great Leap Forward Economic and social campaign

The Great Leap Forward of the People's Republic of China (PRC) was an economic and social campaign led by the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) from 1958 to 1962. Chairman Mao Zedong launched the campaign to reconstruct the country from an agrarian economy into a communist society through the formation of people's communes. Mao decreed that efforts to multiply grain yields and bring industry to the countryside should be increased. Local officials were fearful of Anti-Rightist Campaigns and they competed to fulfill or over-fulfill quotas which were based on Mao's exaggerated claims, collecting non-existent "surpluses" and leaving farmers to starve. Higher officials did not dare to report the economic disaster which was being caused by these policies, and national officials, blaming bad weather for the decline in food output, took little or no action. Millions of people died in China during the Great Leap, with estimates ranging from 15 to 55 million, making the Great Chinese Famine the largest or second-largest famine in human history.

The Great Chinese Famine was a period between 1959 and 1961 in the history of the People's Republic of China (PRC) characterized by widespread famine. Some scholars have also included the years 1958 or 1962. It is widely regarded as the deadliest famine and one of the greatest man-made disasters in human history, with an estimated death toll due to starvation that ranges in the tens of millions. The most stricken provinces were Anhui, Chongqing (15%), Sichuan (13%), Guizhou (11%) and Hunan (8%).

Peoples commune Former rural administrative division of the Peoples Republic of China (1958-83)

The people's commune was the highest of three administrative levels in rural areas of the People's Republic of China during the period from 1958 to 1983, until they were replaced by townships. Communes, the largest collective units, were divided in turn into production brigades and production teams. The communes had governmental, political, and economic functions during the Cultural Revolution. The people's commune was commonly known for collectivizing living and working practices, especially during the Great Leap Forward. The scale of the commune and its ability to extract income from the rural population enabled commune administrations to invest in large-scale mechanization, infrastructure, and industrial projects. The communes did not, however, meet many of their long-term goals, such as facilitating the construction of socialism in the rural areas, liberating women from housework, and creating sustainable agriculture practices in the countryside. They ranged in number from 50,000 to 90,000.

Trade can be a key factor in economic development. The prudent use of trade can boost a country's development and create absolute gains for the trading partners involved. Trade has been touted as an important tool in the path to development by prominent economists. However trade may not be a panacea for development as important questions surrounding how free trade really is and the harm trade can cause domestic infant industries to come into play.

Sum, sumu, sumon, and somon are the lowest level of administrative division used in China, Mongolia, and Russia. The word sumu is a direct translation of a Manchu word niru, meaning ‘arrow’ Countries such as China and Mongolia, have employed the sumu administrative processes in order to fulfil their nations economic, social and political goals. This system was acted in the 1980s after the Chinese Communist Party gained power in conjunction with their growing internal and external problems. The decentralisation of government included restructuring of organisational methods, reduction of roles in rural government and creation of sumu’s.

Đổi Mới (𢷮㵋), IPA: [ɗo᷉i mə̌ːi]; transl. "renovation" or "innovation") is the name given to the economic reforms initiated in Vietnam in 1986 with the goal of creating a "socialist-oriented market economy". The term đổi mới itself is a general term with wide use in the Vietnamese language meaning "innovate" or "renovate". However, the Đổi Mới Policy refers specifically to these reforms that sought to transition Vietnam from a command economy to a socialist-oriented market economy.

The dual-sector model is a model in development economics. It is commonly known as the Lewis model after its inventor W. Arthur Lewis. It explains the growth of a developing economy in terms of a labour transition between two sectors, the capitalist sector and the subsistence sector.

Rural society in China

Rural society in the People's Republic of China encompasses less than half of China's population and has a varied range of standard of living and means of living. Life in rural China differs from that of urban China. In southern and coastal China, rural areas are developing and, in some cases, statistically approaching urban economies. In northwest and western regions, rural society is still perceived as lowly and primitive. Basic needs such as running water and accessible transportation are a problem in these areas.

The economic history of China describes the changes and developments in China's economy from the founding of the People's Republic of China (PRC) in 1949 to the present day.

Agriculture in Vietnam

In 2004, agriculture and forestry accounted for 21.8 percent of Vietnam's gross domestic product (GDP), and between 1994 and 2004, the sector grew at an annual rate of 4.1 percent. Agriculture's share of economic output has declined in recent years, falling as a share of GDP from 42% in 1989 to 26% in 1999, as production in other sectors of the economy has risen. However, agricultural employment was much higher than agriculture's share of GDP; in 2005, approximately 60 percent of the employed labor force was engaged in agriculture, forestry, and fishing. Agricultural products accounted for 30 percent of exports in 2005. The relaxation of the state monopoly on rice exports transformed the country into the world's second or third largest rice exporter. Other cash crops are coffee, cotton, peanuts, rubber, sugarcane, and tea.

Agriculture in China Farming in China

China primarily produces rice, wheat, potatoes, tomato, sorghum, peanuts, tea, millet, barley, cotton, oilseed, corn and soybeans.

History of agriculture in China Agriculture in China under Communist Party rule

For 4,000 years China has been a nation of farmers. By the time the People's Republic of China was established in 1949, virtually all arable land was under cultivation; irrigation and drainage systems constructed centuries earlier and intensive farming practices already produced relatively high yields. But little prime virgin land was available to support population growth and economic development. However, after a decline in production as a result of the Great Leap Forward (1958–60), agricultural reforms implemented in the 1980s increased yields and promised even greater future production from existing cultivated land.

The technological and industrial history of China is extremely varied, and extensive. China's industrial sector has shown great progress using most of its technology from the 1950s.

Industry of China Manufacturing and economic sector of China

Industry was 39.9% of China's gross domestic product (GDP) in 2017. In 2007, industry contributed 46.7 percent of GDP in 2010 and occupied 27 percent of the workforce. In 2015, the manufacturing industrial sectors contributed to 40% of China's GDP. The manufacturing sector produced 44.1 percent of GDP in 2004 and accounted for 11.3 percent of total employment in 2006.

Agriculture in Pakistan

Agriculture is considered the backbone of Pakistan's economy, which relies heavily on its major crops. Pakistan's principal natural resources are arable land and water. Agriculture accounts for about 18.9% of Pakistan's GDP and employs about 42.3% of the labour force. The most agricultural province is Punjab where wheat & cotton are the most grown. Mango orchards are mostly found in Sindh and Punjab provinces,making it the world's 4th largest producer of mangoes.

Despite crisis in Syria, agriculture remains a key part of the economy. The sector still accounts for an estimated 26 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) and represents a critical safety net for the 6.7 million Syrians – including those internally displaced - who still remain in rural areas. However, agriculture and the livelihoods that depend on it have suffered massive loss. Today, food production is at a record low and around half the population remaining in Syria are unable to meet their daily food needs.

The Five-Year Plans are a series of social and economic development initiatives issued by the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) since 1953 in the People's Republic of China. Since 1949, the CCP has shaped the Chinese economy through the plenums of its Central Committee and national congresses. The party plays a leading role in establishing the foundations and principles of Chinese communism, mapping strategies for economic development, setting growth targets, and launching reforms.

Chinese economic reform Reforms allowing more free markets in China since Deng Xiaoping

The Chinese economic reform or reform and opening-up, known in the West as the opening of China, is the program of economic reforms termed "Socialism with Chinese characteristics" and "socialist market economy" in the People's Republic of China (PRC). Led by Deng Xiaoping, often credited as the "General Architect", the reforms were launched by reformists within the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) on December 18, 1978, during the "Boluan Fanzheng" period. The reforms went into stagnation after the military crackdown on 1989 Tiananmen Square protests, but were revived after Deng Xiaoping's Southern Tour in 1992. In 2010, China overtook Japan as the world's second-largest economy by nominal GDP and in 2014 overtook the United States by becoming the world's largest economy by GDP (PPP).

Xiaogang, Anhui Place in Anhui, Peoples Republic of China

Xiaogang Village is a small village in Xiaoxihe, Fengyang County, Chuzhou, Anhui province in China, not far from Nanjing. China's move toward reform has been traced to an agreement among farmers in Xiaogang to secretly subdivide their common farmland in December 1978, after which the production of grain increased dramatically. The village was held up as a model for agricultural reform by China's new leadership after Deng Xiaoping came to power.

Land Reform Movement (China) Chinese campaign led by Mao Zedong (1946–1953)

The Land Reform Movement, also known by the Chinese abbreviation Tǔgǎi (土改), was a campaign by the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) leader Mao Zedong during the late phase of the Chinese Civil War and the early People's Republic of China. The campaign involved the mass killing of landlords by tenants and land redistribution to the peasantry. The estimated number of casualties of the movement ranges from hundreds of thousands to millions. In terms of the CCP's evaluation, Zhou Enlai estimated 830,000 had been killed and Mao Zedong estimated as many as 2 to 3 million were killed.

References

  1. "OECD Review of Agricultural Policies - China - OECD". www.oecd.org. Retrieved 2018-06-17.
  2. "China's Great Leap Forward". chronicle.uchicago.edu. Retrieved 2018-07-05.
  3. "A Grim Chronicle Of China's Great Famine". NPR.org. Retrieved 2017-12-09.
  4. "Fertility rate, total (births per woman) | Data". data.worldbank.org. Retrieved 2017-12-09.
  5. "Population growth (annual %) | Data". data.worldbank.org. Retrieved 2017-12-09.
  6. Cheek, Timothy (2002). Mao Zedong and China's Revolutions. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 160–166. ISBN   978-1-349-63485-9.
  7. 1 2 Lau, Lawrence J.; Zheng, Huanhuan (2015-09-01). "How Much Slack Was There in the Chinese Economy Prior to its Economic Reform of 1978?". Rochester, NY. SSRN   2657691.{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  8. "30 years of rural reform in China -- China.org.cn". www.china.org.cn. Retrieved 2018-06-19.
  9. 1 2 Lin, Justin Yifu (1992). "Rural Reforms and Agricultural Growth in China". The American Economic Review. 82 (1): 34–51. JSTOR   2117601.
  10. Gabriel, S. (2005). Chinese Capitalism and the Modernist Vision. London: Routledge. p. 125. ISBN   0-415-70003-5.

[1]

  1. "Agricultural Reforms in China?". www.mtholyoke.edu. Retrieved 2018-04-16.