Fisher market

Last updated

Fisher market is an economic model attributed to Irving Fisher. It has the following ingredients: [1]

Contents

Each product has a price ; the prices are determined by methods described below. The price of a bundle of products is the sum of the prices of the products in the bundle. A bundle is represented by a vector , where is the quantity of product . So the price of a bundle is .

A bundle is affordable for a buyer if the price of that bundle is at most the buyer's budget. I.e, a bundle is affordable for buyer if .

Each buyer has a preference relation over bundles, which can be represented by a utility function. The utility function of buyer is denoted by . The demand set of a buyer is the set of affordable bundles that maximize the buyer's utility among all affordable bundles, i.e.:

.

A competitive equilibrium (CE) is a price-vector in which it is possible to allocate, to each agent, a bundle from his demand-set, such that the total allocation exactly equals the supply of products. The corresponding prices are called market-clearing prices. The main challenge in analyzing Fisher markets is finding a CE. [2] :103–105

Fisher market with divisible items

Existence of equilibrium

When all items in the market are divisible, a CE always exists. This can be proved using the famous Sperner's lemma. [4] :67

Assume the quantities are normalized so that there is 1 unit per product, and the budgets are normalized so that their sum is 1. Also assume that all products are good, i.e., an agent always strictly prefers to have more of each product, if he can afford it.

Consider the standard simplex with m vertices. Each point in this simplex corresponds to a price-vector, where the sum of all prices is 1; hence the price of all goods together is 1.

In each price-vector p, we can find a demanded set of each agent, then calculate the sum of all demanded sets, then find the total price of this aggregate demand. Since the price of each demanded set is at most the agent's budget, and the sum of budgets is at most 1, the price of the aggregate demand is at most 1. Hence, for each p, there is at least one product for which the total demand is at most 1. Let's call such product an "expensive product" in p.

Triangulate the m-vertex simplex, and label each triangulation-vertex p with an index of an arbitrary expensive-product in p. In each face of the simplex, some products cost 0. Since all products are good, the demand of each agent for a product that costs 0 is always 1; hence a product which costs 0 can never be considered expensive. Hence, the above labeling satisfies Sperner's boundary condition.

By Sperner's lemma, there exists a baby-simplex whose vertices are labeled with m different labels. Since the demand function is continuous, by taking finer and finer triangulations we find a single price-vector p*, in which all products are expensive, i.e., the aggregate demand for every product is at most 1.

But, since the sum of all budgets is 1, the aggregate demand for every product in p* must be exactly 1. Hence p* is a vector of market-clearing prices.

Computation of equilibrium

While Sperner's lemma can be used to find a CE, [4] it is very inefficient computationally. There are more efficient methods (see also market equilibrium computation).

Devanur, Papadimitriou, Saberi and Vazirani [5] gave a polynomial-time algorithm for exactly computing an equilibrium for Fisher markets with linear utility functions. Their algorithm uses the primal–dual paradigm in the enhanced setting of KKT conditions and convex programs. Their algorithm is weakly-polynomial: it solves maximum flow problems, and thus it runs in time , where umax and Bmax are the maximum utility and budget, respectively.

Orlin [6] gave an improved algorithm for a Fisher market model with linear utilities, running in time . He then improved his algorithm to run in strongly-polynomial time: .

Chen and Teng [7] proved that, when the agents' utilities can be arbitrary SPLC (Separable piecewise-linear concave) functions, finding a CE is PPAD-hard.

Bads and mixed manna

Bogomolnaia and Moulin and Sandomirskiy and Yanovskaia studied the existence and properties of CE in a Fisher market with bads (items with negative utilities) [8] and with a mixture of goods and bads. [9] In contrast to the setting with goods, when the resources are bads the CE does not solve any convex optimization problem even with linear utilities. CE allocations correspond to local minima, local maxima, and saddle points of the product of utilities on the Pareto frontier of the set of feasible utilities. The CE rule becomes multivalued. This work has led to several works on algorithms of finding CE in such markets:

If both n and m are variable, the problem becomes computationally hard:

Fisher markets with indivisible items

When the items in the market are indivisible, a CE is not guaranteed to exist. Deciding whether a CE exist is a computationally hard problem.

Deng et al [15] studied a market to which each agent comes with an initial endowment (rather than an initial income) and all valuations are additive. They proved that deciding whether CE exists is NP-hard even with 3 agents. They presented an approximation algorithm which relaxes the CE conditions in two ways: (1) The bundle allocated to each agent is valued at least 1-epsilon of the optimum given the prices, and (2) the demand is at least 1-epsilon times the supply.

Bouveret and Lemaitre [16] studied CE-from-equal-incomes (CEEI) as a rule for fair allocation of items. They related it to four other fairness criteria assuming all agents have additive valuation functions. They asked what is the computational complexity of deciding whether CEEI exists.

This question was answered soon afterwards by Aziz, [17] who proved that the problem is weakly NP-hard when there are two agents and m items, and strongly NP-hard when there are n agents and 3n items. He also presented a stronger condition called CEEI-FRAC which is, interestingly, easier to verify --- it can be verified in polynomial time. Miltersen, Hosseini and Branzei [18] proved that even verifying whether a given allocation is CEEI is co-NP-hard. They studied CEEI also for single-minded agents. In this case, verifying whether a given allocation is CEEI is polynomial but checking if CEEI exists is co-NP-complete.

Heinen et al [19] extended the work of Bouveret and Lemaitre from additive to k-additive utility functions, in which each agent reports a value for bundles containing at most k items, and the values of larger bundles are determined by adding and subtracting the values of the basic bundles.

Budish [20] studied the most general setting in which agents can have arbitrary preference relations over bundles. He invented the mechanism of Approximate Competitive Equilibrium from Equal Incomes, which relaxes the CEEI conditions in two ways: (1) The agents' incomes are not exactly equal, and (2) a small number of items may remain unallocated. He proved that an approximate-CEEI always exists (although Othman et al [21] recently proved that the computation of approximate-CEEI is PPAD complete).

Barman and Krishnamurthy [22] study Fisher markets in which all agents have additive utilities. They show that a fractional CE (where some goods are divided) can always be rounded to an integral CE (where goods remain indivisible), by changing the agents' budgets. The change in each budget can be as high as the largest price of a good in the fractional CE.

Babaioff, Nisan and Talgam-Cohen [23] studied whether CE exists when the incomes are generic, i.e., do not satisfy a finite set of equalities. In other words: whether there exists a CE for almost all income-vectors. They proved existence for three goods, and for four goods and two agents. They proved non-existence for five goods and two agents. Later, it has proved that with four goods and three agents, CE may not exist when the valuations are non-additive, but always exists when the valuations are additive. [24]

See also

Related Research Articles

A Lindahl tax is a form of taxation conceived by Erik Lindahl in which individuals pay for public goods according to their marginal benefits. In other words, they pay according to the amount of satisfaction or utility they derive from the consumption of an additional unit of the public good. Lindahl taxation is designed to maximize efficiency for each individual and provide the optimal level of a public good.

Competitive equilibrium is a concept of economic equilibrium, introduced by Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu in 1951, appropriate for the analysis of commodity markets with flexible prices and many traders, and serving as the benchmark of efficiency in economic analysis. It relies crucially on the assumption of a competitive environment where each trader decides upon a quantity that is so small compared to the total quantity traded in the market that their individual transactions have no influence on the prices. Competitive markets are an ideal standard by which other market structures are evaluated.

In economics, especially in consumer theory, a Leontief utility function is a function of the form:

In algorithmic game theory, a succinct game or a succinctly representable game is a game which may be represented in a size much smaller than its normal form representation. Without placing constraints on player utilities, describing a game of players, each facing strategies, requires listing utility values. Even trivial algorithms are capable of finding a Nash equilibrium in a time polynomial in the length of such a large input. A succinct game is of polynomial type if in a game represented by a string of length n the number of players, as well as the number of strategies of each player, is bounded by a polynomial in n.

Fair item allocation is a kind of the fair division problem in which the items to divide are discrete rather than continuous. The items have to be divided among several partners who potentially value them differently, and each item has to be given as a whole to a single person. This situation arises in various real-life scenarios:

In economics and consumer theory, a linear utility function is a function of the form:

Weller's theorem is a theorem in economics. It says that a heterogeneous resource ("cake") can be divided among n partners with different valuations in a way that is both Pareto-efficient (PE) and envy-free (EF). Thus, it is possible to divide a cake fairly without compromising on economic efficiency.

Envy-free (EF) item allocation is a fair item allocation problem, in which the fairness criterion is envy-freeness - each agent should receive a bundle that they believe to be at least as good as the bundle of any other agent.

Approximate Competitive Equilibrium from Equal Incomes (A-CEEI) is a procedure for fair item assignment. It was developed by Eric Budish.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Price of anarchy in auctions</span>

The Price of Anarchy (PoA) is a concept in game theory and mechanism design that measures how the social welfare of a system degrades due to selfish behavior of its agents. It has been studied extensively in various contexts, particularly in auctions.

Maximin share (MMS) is a criterion of fair item allocation. Given a set of items with different values, the 1-out-of-n maximin-share is the maximum value that can be gained by partitioning the items into parts and taking the part with the minimum value. An allocation of items among agents with different valuations is called MMS-fair if each agent gets a bundle that is at least as good as his/her 1-out-of-n maximin-share. MMS fairness is a relaxation of the criterion of proportionality - each agent gets a bundle that is at least as good as the equal split ( of every resource). Proportionality can be guaranteed when the items are divisible, but not when they are indivisible, even if all agents have identical valuations. In contrast, MMS fairness can always be guaranteed to identical agents, so it is a natural alternative to proportionality even when the agents are different.

Envy-free pricing is a kind of fair item allocation. There is a single seller that owns some items, and a set of buyers who are interested in these items. The buyers have different valuations to the items, and they have a quasilinear utility function; this means that the utility an agent gains from a bundle of items equals the agent's value for the bundle minus the total price of items in the bundle. The seller should determine a price for each item, and sell the items to some of the buyers, such that there is no envy. Two kinds of envy are considered:

When allocating objects among people with different preferences, two major goals are Pareto efficiency and fairness. Since the objects are indivisible, there may not exist any fair allocation. For example, when there is a single house and two people, every allocation of the house will be unfair to one person. Therefore, several common approximations have been studied, such as maximin-share fairness (MMS), envy-freeness up to one item (EF1), proportionality up to one item (PROP1), and equitability up to one item (EQ1). The problem of efficient approximately fair item allocation is to find an allocation that is both Pareto-efficient (PE) and satisfies one of these fairness notions. The problem was first presented at 2016 and has attracted considerable attention since then.

Egalitarian item allocation, also called max-min item allocation is a fair item allocation problem, in which the fairness criterion follows the egalitarian rule. The goal is to maximize the minimum value of an agent. That is, among all possible allocations, the goal is to find an allocation in which the smallest value of an agent is as large as possible. In case there are two or more allocations with the same smallest value, then the goal is to select, from among these allocations, the one in which the second-smallest value is as large as possible, and so on. Therefore, an egalitarian item allocation is sometimes called a leximin item allocation.

Market equilibrium computation is a computational problem in the intersection of economics and computer science. The input to this problem is a market, consisting of a set of resources and a set of agents. There are various kinds of markets, such as Fisher market and Arrow–Debreu market, with divisible or indivisible resources. The required output is a competitive equilibrium, consisting of a price-vector, and an allocation, such that each agent gets the best bundle possible given the budget, and the market clears.

In economics and computer science, Fractional Pareto efficiency or Fractional Pareto optimality (fPO) is a variant of Pareto efficiency used in the setting of fair allocation of discrete objects. An allocation of objects is called discrete if each item is wholly allocated to a single agent; it is called fractional if some objects are split among two or more agents. A discrete allocation is called Pareto-efficient (PO) if it is not Pareto-dominated by any discrete allocation; it is called fractionally Pareto-efficient (fPO) if it is not Pareto-dominated by any discrete or fractional allocation. So fPO is a stronger requirement than PO: every fPO allocation is PO, but not every PO allocation is fPO.

Fair allocation of items and money is a class of fair item allocation problems in which, during the allocation process, it is possible to give or take money from some of the participants. Without money, it may be impossible to allocate indivisible items fairly. For example, if there is one item and two people, and the item must be given entirely to one of them, the allocation will be unfair towards the other one. Monetary payments make it possible to attain fairness, as explained below.

The welfare maximization problem is an optimization problem studied in economics and computer science. Its goal is to partition a set of items among agents with different utility functions, such that the welfare – defined as the sum of the agents' utilities – is as high as possible. In other words, the goal is to find an item allocation satisfying the utilitarian rule.

In theoretical economics, an Arrow–Debreu exchange market is a special case of the Arrow–Debreu model in which there is no production - there is only an exchange of already-existing goods. An Arrow–Debreu exchange market has the following ingredients:

References

  1. Yishay Mansour (2011). "Lecture 10: Market Equilibrium" (PDF). Advanced Topics in Machine Learning and Algorithmic Game Theory. Retrieved 15 March 2016.
  2. Vazirani, Vijay V.; Nisan, Noam; Roughgarden, Tim; Tardos, Éva (2007). "Chapter 5: Combinatorial Algorithms for Market Equilibria / Vijay V. Vazirani". Algorithmic Game Theory (PDF). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. ISBN   0-521-87282-0.
  3. Jain, Kamal; Vazirani, Vijay V. (2010). "Eisenberg–Gale markets: Algorithms and game-theoretic properties". Games and Economic Behavior. 70: 84–106. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2008.11.011.
  4. 1 2 Scarf, Herbert (1967). "The Core of an N Person Game". Econometrica. 35 (1): 50–69. doi:10.2307/1909383. JSTOR   1909383.
  5. Devanur, Nikhil R.; Papadimitriou, Christos H.; Saberi, Amin; Vazirani, Vijay V. (2008-11-05). "Market equilibrium via a primal--dual algorithm for a convex program". Journal of the ACM. 55 (5): 22:1–22:18. doi:10.1145/1411509.1411512. ISSN   0004-5411. S2CID   11836728.
  6. Orlin, James B. (2010-06-05). "Improved algorithms for computing fisher's market clearing prices". Proceedings of the forty-second ACM symposium on Theory of computing. STOC '10. Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA: Association for Computing Machinery. pp. 291–300. doi:10.1145/1806689.1806731. hdl: 1721.1/68009 . ISBN   978-1-4503-0050-6. S2CID   8235905.
  7. Chen, Xi; Teng, Shang-Hua (2009). Dong, Yingfei; Du, Ding-Zhu; Ibarra, Oscar (eds.). "Spending Is Not Easier Than Trading: On the Computational Equivalence of Fisher and Arrow-Debreu Equilibria". Algorithms and Computation. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. 5878. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer: 647–656. arXiv: 0907.4130 . doi:10.1007/978-3-642-10631-6_66. ISBN   978-3-642-10631-6. S2CID   7817966.
  8. Bogomolnaia, Anna; Moulin, Hervé; Sandomirskiy, Fedor; Yanovskaia, Elena (2019-03-01). "Dividing bads under additive utilities". Social Choice and Welfare. 52 (3): 395–417. doi: 10.1007/s00355-018-1157-x . ISSN   1432-217X.
  9. Bogomolnaia, Anna; Moulin, Hervé; Sandomirskiy, Fedor; Yanovskaya, Elena (2017). "Competitive Division of a Mixed Manna". Econometrica. 85 (6): 1847–1871. arXiv: 1702.00616 . doi:10.3982/ECTA14564. ISSN   1468-0262. S2CID   17081755.
  10. Brânzei, Simina; Sandomirskiy, Fedor (2019-07-03). "Algorithms for Competitive Division of Chores". arXiv: 1907.01766 [cs.GT].
  11. Garg, Jugal; McGlaughlin, Peter (2020-05-05). "Computing Competitive Equilibria with Mixed Manna". Proceedings of the 19th International Conference on Autonomous Agents and MultiAgent Systems. AAMAS '20. Auckland, New Zealand: International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems: 420–428. ISBN   978-1-4503-7518-4.
  12. Chaudhury, Bhaskar Ray; Garg, Jugal; McGlaughlin, Peter; Mehta, Ruta (2021-01-01), "Competitive Allocation of a Mixed Manna", Proceedings of the 2021 ACM-SIAM Symposium on Discrete Algorithms (SODA), Proceedings, Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics, pp. 1405–1424, arXiv: 2008.02753 , doi: 10.1137/1.9781611976465.85 , ISBN   978-1-61197-646-5
  13. Chen, Xi; Teng, Shang-Hua (2009). Dong, Yingfei; Du, Ding-Zhu; Ibarra, Oscar (eds.). "Spending Is Not Easier Than Trading: On the Computational Equivalence of Fisher and Arrow-Debreu Equilibria". Algorithms and Computation. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. 5878. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer: 647–656. arXiv: 0907.4130 . doi:10.1007/978-3-642-10631-6_66. ISBN   978-3-642-10631-6. S2CID   7817966.
  14. 1 2 Chaudhury, Bhaskar Ray; Garg, Jugal; McGlaughlin, Peter; Mehta, Ruta (2020-08-01). "Dividing Bads is Harder than Dividing Goods: On the Complexity of Fair and Efficient Division of Chores". arXiv: 2008.00285 [cs.GT].
  15. Deng, Xiaotie; Papadimitriou, Christos; Safra, Shmuel (2003-09-01). "On the complexity of price equilibria". Journal of Computer and System Sciences. 67 (2): 311–324. doi: 10.1016/S0022-0000(03)00011-4 . ISSN   0022-0000.
  16. Lemaître, Michel; Bouveret, Sylvain (2016-03-01). "Characterizing conflicts in fair division of indivisible goods using a scale of criteria". Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems. 30 (2): 259–290. doi:10.1007/s10458-015-9287-3. ISSN   1573-7454. S2CID   16041218.
  17. Aziz, Haris (2015-11-01). "Competitive equilibrium with equal incomes for allocation of indivisible objects". Operations Research Letters. 43 (6): 622–624. arXiv: 1501.06627 . Bibcode:2015arXiv150106627A. doi:10.1016/j.orl.2015.10.001. ISSN   0167-6377. S2CID   11495811.
  18. Miltersen, Peter Bro; Hosseini, Hadi; Brânzei, Simina (2015-09-28). "Characterization and Computation of Equilibria for Indivisible Goods". Algorithmic Game Theory. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. Vol. 9347. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. pp. 244–255. arXiv: 1503.06855 . doi:10.1007/978-3-662-48433-3_19. ISBN   9783662484326. S2CID   656603.
  19. Rothe, Jörg; Nguyen, Nhan-Tam; Heinen, Tobias (2015-09-27). "Fairness and Rank-Weighted Utilitarianism in Resource Allocation". Algorithmic Decision Theory. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. Vol. 9346. Springer, Cham. pp. 521–536. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-23114-3_31. ISBN   9783319231136.
  20. Budish, Eric (2011). "The Combinatorial Assignment Problem: Approximate Competitive Equilibrium from Equal Incomes". Journal of Political Economy. 119 (6): 1061–1103. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.357.9766 . doi:10.1086/664613. S2CID   154703357.
  21. Othman, Abraham; Papadimitriou, Christos; Rubinstein, Aviad (2016-08-01). "The Complexity of Fairness Through Equilibrium". ACM Transactions on Economics and Computation. 4 (4): 20:1–20:19. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.747.956 . doi:10.1145/2956583. ISSN   2167-8375. S2CID   2780775.
  22. Barman, Siddharth; Krishnamurthy, Sanath Kumar (2018-11-21). "On the Proximity of Markets with Integral Equilibria". arXiv: 1811.08673 [cs.GT].
  23. Talgam-Cohen, Inbal; Nisan, Noam; Babaioff, Moshe (2017-03-23). "Competitive Equilibrium with Indivisible Goods and Generic Budgets". arXiv: 1703.08150 [cs.GT].
  24. Segal-Halevi, Erel (2020-02-20). "Competitive equilibrium for almost all incomes: existence and fairness". Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems. 34 (1): 26. arXiv: 1705.04212 . doi:10.1007/s10458-020-09444-z. ISSN   1573-7454. S2CID   210911501.