Supply-chain auction

Last updated

A supply-chain auction is an auction for coordinating trade among various suppliers and consumers in a supply chain. [1] [2] [3] It is a generalization of a double auction. In a double auction, each deal involves two agents - a buyer and a seller, so the "supply-chain" contains only a single link. In a general supply-chain auction, each deal may involve many different agents, for example: a seller, a mediator, a transporter and a buyer.

Contents

Auction for a linear supply-chain

Babaioff and Nisan [1] present an auction for the case in which the supply-chain is linear - each node in the chain consumes the output of the previous node and produces input for the next node. There is one class of initial suppliers, several classes of converters, and one class of end consumers.

Their running example is a lemonade market, in which there are three kinds of agents: pickers, squeezers and drinkers:

In this market, each deal involves three agents - one of each kind. The costs/values of different agents of the same kind might differ, so it is desirable to arrange the trade using a truthful mechanism. Babaioff and Nisan suggest to conduct three different double auctions - one for each kind of agents:

For each double auction there are several options, for example: a VCG auction (which is truthful and efficient but has a deficit), or a trade-reduction auction (which is truthful and has no deficit but is only approximately-efficient).

They suggest two protocols for combining the different double-auctions into a single outcome:

Example

Suppose there are three pickers with values -3, -6, -7 (negative values denote costs); three squeezers with values -1, -3, -6; and three consumers with values +12, +11, +7. The following table presents the three double-auctions (the boldfaced values denote the actual traders; the non-boldfaced values are the virtual traders calculated as sum/difference of other traders' values.

Lemon marketSqueezing marketJuice marketCombined
Buyers' values:+11,+8,+1+9,+5,+0+12,+11,+7
Sellers' values:-3,-6,-7-1,-3,-6-4,-9,-13
Symmetric protocol,

VCG auction (truthful and efficient)

Two sellers (pickers) sell for -7

= max(-8,-7).

Two sellers (squeezers) sell for -5

= max(-5,-6).

Two buyers (drinkers) buy for +9

= max(+9,+7).

Two pickers pick for -7;

Two squeezers squeeze for -5;

Two drinkers drink for +9;

Social welfare 12+11-1-3-3-6 = +10;

Deficit -3 per unit = -6.

Symmetric protocol,

Trade-reduction auction (truthful and has no deficit)

One seller (picker) sells for -6; One seller (squeezer) sells for -3; One buyer (drinker) buys for +11;


One picker picks for -6;

One squeezer squeezes for -3;

One drinker drinks for +11;

Social welfare 12-1-3 = +8;

Surplus +2 per unit = +2.

Symmetric protocol,

Market-equilibrium outcome

(efficient and budget-balanced)

Two sellers (pickers) sell for -6;
Two sellers (squeezers) sell for -3;
Two buyers (drinkers) buy for +9;
Two pickers pick for -6;

Two squeezers squeeze for -3;

Two drinkers drink for +9;

Social welfare 12+11-1-3-3-6 = +10;

Budget is balanced.

Pivot protocol

(starting at juice market),

VCG auction (truthful and efficient)

The trade-size is 2, so

two sellers (pickers) sell;

their price is max(-8, -7)=-7.

The trade-size is 2, so

two sellers (squeezers) sell;

their price is max(-11--6,-6)=-5.

Send to previous market the

trade-size (2) and the seller price (-11--3=-8)

Two buyers (drinkers) buy for +9;

Two sellers (virtual) sell for -11

= max(-11,-13);

Send to previous market the

trade-size (2) and the seller price (-11).

Two pickers pick for -7;

Two squeezers squeeze for -5;

Two drinkers drink for +9;

Social welfare 12+11-1-3-3-6 = +10;

Deficit -3 per unit = -6.


Auction for a directed acyclic graph

Babaioff and Walsh [2] extend the above work to the case in which the supply-chain can be any acyclic graph. As an example, they consider the following market with six agent kinds:

Procurement auction

Chen, Roundy, Zhang and Janakiraman [3] study a different setting in which there is a single buyer and single item-kind, but there are different producers in different supply-locations. The buyer needs a different quantity of the item in different demand-locations. The buyer conducts a reverse auction. The buyer has to pay, in addition to the cost of production, also the cost of transportation from the supply-locations to the demand-locations. They present three different mechanisms: the first is truthful and efficient in terms of supply, but ignores the transportation costs; the second is truthful and efficient in terms of supply and transportation, but may be worse for the buyer; the third is truthful only for the producers but not for the buyer.

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Microeconomics</span> Behavior of individuals and firms

Microeconomics is a branch of economics that studies the behavior of individuals and firms in making decisions regarding the allocation of scarce resources and the interactions among these individuals and firms. Microeconomics focuses on the study of individual markets, sectors, or industries as opposed to the national economy as a whole, which is studied in macroeconomics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">The Market for Lemons</span> 1970 economic paper

"The Market for 'Lemons': Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism" is a widely cited seminal paper in the field of economics which explores the concept of asymmetric information in markets. The paper was written in 1970 by George Akerlof and published in the Quarterly Journal of Economics. The paper's findings have since been applied to many other types of markets. However, Akerlof's research focused solely on the market for used cars.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Vickrey auction</span> Auction priced by second-highest sealed bid

A Vickrey auction or sealed-bid second-price auction (SBSPA) is a type of sealed-bid auction. Bidders submit written bids without knowing the bid of the other people in the auction. The highest bidder wins but the price paid is the second-highest bid. This type of auction is strategically similar to an English auction and gives bidders an incentive to bid their true value. The auction was first described academically by Columbia University professor William Vickrey in 1961 though it had been used by stamp collectors since 1893. In 1797 Johann Wolfgang von Goethe sold a manuscript using a sealed-bid, second-price auction.

In economics, a market is a composition of systems, institutions, procedures, social relations or infrastructures whereby parties engage in exchange. While parties may exchange goods and services by barter, most markets rely on sellers offering their goods or services to buyers in exchange for money. It can be said that a market is the process by which the prices of goods and services are established. Markets facilitate trade and enable the distribution and allocation of resources in a society. Markets allow any tradeable item to be evaluated and priced. A market emerges more or less spontaneously or may be constructed deliberately by human interaction in order to enable the exchange of rights of services and goods. Markets generally supplant gift economies and are often held in place through rules and customs, such as a booth fee, competitive pricing, and source of goods for sale.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Double auction</span>

A double auction is a process of buying and selling goods with multiple sellers and multiple buyers. Potential buyers submit their bids and potential sellers submit their ask prices to the market institution, and then the market institution chooses some price p that clears the market: all the sellers who asked less than p sell and all buyers who bid more than p buy at this price p. Buyers and sellers that bid or ask for exactly p are also included. A common example of a double auction is stock exchange.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Auction theory</span> Branch of applied economics regarding the behavior of bidders in auctions

Auction theory is an applied branch of economics which deals with how bidders act in auction markets and researches how the features of auction markets incentivise predictable outcomes. Auction theory is a tool used to inform the design of real-world auctions. Sellers use auction theory to raise higher revenues while allowing buyers to procure at a lower cost. The conference of the price between the buyer and seller is an economic equilibrium. Auction theorists design rules for auctions to address issues which can lead to market failure. The design of these rulesets encourages optimal bidding strategies among a variety of informational settings. The 2020 Nobel Prize for Economics was awarded to Paul R. Milgrom and Robert B. Wilson “for improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats.”

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Multiunit auction</span>

A multiunit auction is an auction in which several homogeneous items are sold. The units can be sold each at the same price or at different prices.

A bilateral monopoly is a market structure consisting of both a monopoly and a monopsony.

Competitive equilibrium is a concept of economic equilibrium, introduced by Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu in 1951, appropriate for the analysis of commodity markets with flexible prices and many traders, and serving as the benchmark of efficiency in economic analysis. It relies crucially on the assumption of a competitive environment where each trader decides upon a quantity that is so small compared to the total quantity traded in the market that their individual transactions have no influence on the prices. Competitive markets are an ideal standard by which other market structures are evaluated.

Buying agents or purchasing agents are people or companies that offer to buy goods or property on behalf of another party. Indent agents or indenting agents are alternative terms for buying agents. An indent is an order for goods under specified conditions of sale.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Lemon squeezer</span> Kitchen utensil

A lemon squeezer is a small kitchen utensil designed to extract juice from lemons or other citrus fruit such as oranges, grapefruit, or lime. It is designed to separate and crush the pulp of the fruit in a way that is easy to operate. Lemon squeezers can be made from any solid, acid-resistant material, such as plastic, glass, metal or ceramic.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Market design</span>

Market design is a practical methodology for creation of markets of certain properties, which is partially based on mechanism design. In some markets, prices may be used to induce the desired outcomes — these markets are the study of auction theory. In other markets, prices may not be used — these markets are the study of matching theory.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Reverse auction</span> Auction with one buyer and many potential sellers

A reverse auction is a type of auction in which the traditional roles of buyer and seller are reversed. Thus, there is one buyer and many potential sellers. In an ordinary auction also known as a forward auction, buyers compete to obtain goods or services by offering increasingly higher prices. In contrast, in a reverse auction, the sellers compete to obtain business from the buyer and prices will typically decrease as the sellers underbid each other.

In mechanism design, a Vickrey–Clarke–Groves (VCG) mechanism is a generic truthful mechanism for achieving a socially-optimal solution. It is a generalization of a Vickrey–Clarke–Groves auction. A VCG auction performs a specific task: dividing items among people. A VCG mechanism is more general: it can be used to select any outcome out of a set of possible outcomes.

A Bayesian-optimal mechanism (BOM) is a mechanism in which the designer does not know the valuations of the agents for whom the mechanism is designed, but the designer knows that they are random variables and knows the probability distribution of these variables.

A prior-free mechanism (PFM) is a mechanism in which the designer does not have any information on the agents' valuations, not even that they are random variables from some unknown probability distribution.

Fisher market is an economic model attributed to Irving Fisher. It has the following ingredients:

In mechanism design and auction theory, a profit extraction mechanism is a truthful mechanism whose goal is to win a pre-specified amount of profit, if it is possible.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Price of anarchy in auctions</span>

The Price of Anarchy (PoA) is a concept in game theory and mechanism design that measures how the social welfare of a system degrades due to selfish behavior of its agents. It has been studied extensively in various contexts, particularly in auctions.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Budget-balanced mechanism</span>

In mechanism design, a branch of economics, a weakly-budget-balanced (WBB) mechanism is a mechanism in which the total payment made by the participants is at least 0. This means that the mechanism operator does not incur a deficit, i.e., does not have to subsidize the market. Weak budget balance is considered a necessary requirement for the economic feasibility of a mechanism. A strongly-budget-balanced (SBB) mechanism is a mechanism in which the total payment made by the participants is exactly 0. This means that all payments are made among the participants - the mechanism has neither a deficit nor a surplus. The term budget-balanced mechanism is sometimes used as a shorthand for WBB, and sometimes as a shorthand for SBB.

References

  1. 1 2 Babaioff, M.; Nisan, N. (2004-05-01). "Concurrent Auctions Across The Supply Chain". Journal of Artificial Intelligence Research. 21: 595–629. arXiv: 1107.0028 . doi: 10.1613/jair.1316 . ISSN   1076-9757.
  2. 1 2 Babaioff, Moshe; Walsh, William E. (2005-03-01). "Incentive-compatible, budget-balanced, yet highly efficient auctions for supply chain formation". Decision Support Systems. 39 (1): 123–149. doi:10.1016/j.dss.2004.08.008.
  3. 1 2 Chen, Rachel R.; Roundy, Robin O.; Zhang, Rachel Q.; Janakiraman, Ganesh (2005-03-01). "Efficient Auction Mechanisms for Supply Chain Procurement". Management Science. 51 (3): 467–482. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1040.0329. ISSN   0025-1909.