Auction

Last updated
An American auctioneer using auction chant at a livestock auction, November 2010

An auction is usually a process of buying and selling goods or services by offering them up for bids, taking bids, and then selling the item to the highest bidder or buying the item from the lowest bidder. Some exceptions to this definition exist and are described in the section about different types. The branch of economic theory dealing with auction types and participants' behavior in auctions is called auction theory.

Contents

The open ascending price auction is arguably the most common form of auction and has been used throughout history. [1] Participants bid openly against one another, with each subsequent bid being higher than the previous bid. [2] An auctioneer may announce prices, while bidders submit bids vocally or electronically. [2]

Auctions are applied for trade in diverse contexts. These contexts include antiques, paintings, rare collectibles, expensive wines, commodities, livestock, radio spectrum, used cars, real estate, online advertising, vacation packages, emission trading, and many more.

Etymology

The word "auction" is derived from auctus, the past participle of the Latin verb augeō , ("I increase"). [1]

History

Classical antiquity

The Babylonian Marriage Market, Edwin Long, 1875. Babylonian marriage market.jpg
The Babylonian Marriage Market , Edwin Long, 1875.

Auctions have been recorded as early as 500 BC. [3] According to Herodotus, in Babylon, auctions of women for marriage were held annually. The auctions began with the woman the auctioneer considered to be the most beautiful and progressed to the least beautiful. It was considered illegal to allow a daughter to be sold outside of the auction method. [4] Attractive maidens were offered in a forward auction to determine the price to be paid by a swain, while unattractive maidens required a reverse auction to determine the price to be paid to a swain. [5]

Auctions took place in Ancient Greece, other Hellenistic societies, and also in Rome. [6] During the Roman Empire, after a military victory, Roman soldiers would often drive a spear into the ground around which the spoils of war were left, to be auctioned off. Slaves, often captured as the "spoils of war", were auctioned in the Forum under the sign of the spear, with the proceeds of sale going toward the war effort. [4]

The Romans also used auctions to liquidate the assets of debtors whose property had been confiscated. [7] For example, Marcus Aurelius sold household furniture to pay off debts, the sales lasting for months. [8] One of the most significant historical auctions was in 193 AD, when the entire Roman Empire was put on the auction block by the Praetorian Guard. On 28 March 193, the Praetorian Guard first killed emperor Pertinax, then offered the empire to the highest bidder. Didius Julianus won the auction at the price of 6,250 drachmas per guard,[ clarification needed ] [9] [10] [11] an act that initiated a brief civil war. Didius was beheaded two months later when Septimius Severus conquered Rome. [7]

From the end of the Roman Empire to the 18th century, auctions lost favor in Europe, [7] while they had never been widespread in Asia. [4] In China, the personal belongings of deceased Buddhist monks were sold at auction as early as the seventh century AD. [5]

Modern revival

A Peep at Christies (1796) - caricature of actress Elizabeth Farren and huntsman Lord Derby examining paintings at Christie's, by James Gillray Peep-at-Christies-Gillray.jpeg
A Peep at Christies (1796) – caricature of actress Elizabeth Farren and huntsman Lord Derby examining paintings at Christie's, by James Gillray
A late 19th Century auction at the Hotel Drouot, Paris (painting by Albert Bettannier). An Auction at the Hotel Drouot, Paris.jpg
A late 19th Century auction at the Hôtel Drouot, Paris (painting by Albert Bettannier).

The first mention of "auction", according to the Oxford English Dictionary, appeared in 1595. [5] In some parts of England during the 17th and 18th centuries, auctions by candle began to be used for the sale of goods and leaseholds. [12] In a candle auction, the end of the auction was signaled by the expiration of a candle flame, which was intended to ensure that no one could know exactly when the auction would end and make a last-second bid. Sometimes, other unpredictable events, such as a footrace, were used instead of the expiration of a candle. This type of auction was first mentioned in 1641 in the records of the House of Lords. [13] The practice rapidly became popular, and in 1660 Samuel Pepys' diary recorded two occasions when the Admiralty sold surplus ships "by an inch of candle". Pepys also relates a hint from a highly successful bidder who had observed that, just before expiring, a candle-wick always flares up slightly: on seeing this, he would shout his final – and winning – bid.

The London Gazette began reporting on the auctioning of artwork in the coffeehouses and taverns of London in the late 17th century. The first known auction house in the world was the Stockholm Auction House, Sweden (Stockholms Auktionsverk), founded by Baron Claes Rålamb in 1674. [14] [15] Sotheby's, currently the world's second-largest auction house, [14] was founded in London on 11 March 1744, when Samuel Baker presided over the disposal of "several hundred scarce and valuable" books from the library of an acquaintance. Christie's, now the world's largest auction house, [14] was founded by James Christie in 1766 in London [16] and published its first auction catalog that year, although newspaper advertisements of Christie's sales dating from 1759 have been found. [17]

Other early auction houses that are still in operation include Göteborgs Auktionsverk (1681), Dorotheum (1707), Uppsala auktionskammare (1731), Mallams (1788), Bonhams (1793), Phillips de Pury & Company (1796), Freeman's (1805) and Lyon & Turnbull (1826). [18]

By the end of the 18th century, auctions of art works were commonly held in taverns and coffeehouses. These auctions were held daily, and auction catalogs were printed to announce available items. In some cases, these catalogs were elaborate works of art themselves, containing considerable detail about the items being auctioned. At the time, Christie's established a reputation as a leading auction house, taking advantage of London's status as the major centre of the international art trade after the French Revolution. The Great Slave Auction took place in 1859 and is recorded as the second largest single sale of enslaved people in U.S. history — with 436 men, women and children being sold. [19] During the American Civil War, goods seized by armies were sold at auction by the Colonel of the division. Thus, some of today's auctioneers in the U.S. carry the unofficial title of "colonel". [8] Tobacco auctioneers in the southern United States in the late 19th century had a style that mixed traditions of 17th century England with chants of slaves from Africa. [20]

Rise of the internet

The development of the internet has led to a significant rise in the use of auctions, as auctioneers can solicit bids via the internet from a wide range of buyers in a much larger variety of commodities than was previously practical. [21] In the 1990s, the multi-attribute auction was invented to negotiate extensive conditions of construction and electricity contracts via auction. [22] [23] Also during this time, OnSale.com developed the Yankee auction as its trademark. [24] In the early 2000s, the Brazilian auction was invented as a new type of auction to trade gas through electronic auctions for Linde plc in Brazil. [25] [26] With the emergence of the internet, online auctions have developed, with eBay being the most typical example. For example, if someone owns a rare item, they can display the item through an online auction platform. Interested parties may place bids, with the highest bidder winning the opportunity to purchase the item. Online auctions allow more people to participate and also make traditional auction theory more complex. [27]

Economic significance

Artemis, Ancient Greek marble sculpture. In 2007, a Roman-era bronze sculpture of "Artemis and the Stag" was sold at Sotheby's in New York for US$28.6 million, by far exceeding its estimates and at the time setting the new record as the most expensive sculpture as well as work from antiquity ever sold at auction. East pediment G Parthenon BM.jpg
Artemis, Ancient Greek marble sculpture. In 2007, a Roman-era bronze sculpture of "Artemis and the Stag" was sold at Sotheby's in New York for US$28.6 million, by far exceeding its estimates and at the time setting the new record as the most expensive sculpture as well as work from antiquity ever sold at auction.

By increasing visibility of an item and therefore demand, auctions can make an extremely rare item more likely to sell for a higher price. [30]

In 2008, the US National Auctioneers Association reported that the gross revenue of the auction industry for that year was approximately $268.4 billion, with the fastest growing sectors being agricultural, machinery, equipment, and residential real estate auctions. [31]

The auctions with the largest revenue for the government are often spectrum auctions (typical revenue is estimated in billions of euros) and quota auctions. In 2019, Russia's crab quota was auctioned for €2 billion. [32] Between 1999 and 2002, the British government auctioned off their gold reserves, raising approximately $3.5 billion. [33]

The most expensive item to ever be sold in an auction is Leonardo da Vinci's Salvator Mundi in 2017 ($450.3 million). [34]

In 2018, the yearly revenues of the two biggest auction houses were $5 billion (Christie's) and $4 billion (Sotheby's). [35]

Types

Auctions come in a variety of types and categories, which are sometimes not mutually exclusive. Typification of auctions is considered to be a part of Auction theory. [36] The economists Paul Milgrom and Robert B. Wilson were awarded the 2020 Nobel Prize for the introduction of new auction types (or formats). [37] Auction types share features, which can be summarized into the following list.

Participants

Forward auction Reverse auction Double auction
Purchaseauction.svg
Supplyauction.svg
Doubleauction.svg
stand for sellers and for buyers

Auctions can differ in the number and type of participants. There are two types of participants: a buyer and a seller. A buyer pays to acquire a certain good or service, while a seller offers goods or services for money or barter exchange. There can be single or multiple buyers and single or multiple sellers in an auction. If just one seller and one buyer are participating, the process is not considered to be an auction. [38] [39] [40]

Single SellerMultiple Sellers
Single Buyer Trade Reverse auction
Multiple Buyers Forward auction Double auction

The forward auction is the most common type of auction — a seller offers item(s) for sale and expects the highest price. A reverse auction is a type of auction in which the roles of the buyer and the seller are reversed, with the primary objective to drive purchase prices downward. [41] While ordinary auctions provide suppliers the opportunity to find the best price among interested buyers, reverse auctions and buyer-determined auctions give buyers a chance to find the lowest-price supplier. During a reverse auction, suppliers may submit multiple offers, usually as a response to competing suppliers' offers, bidding down the price of a good or service to the lowest price they are willing to receive. A reverse price auction is not necessarily 'descending-price' — the reverse Dutch auction is an ascending-price auction because forward Dutch auctions are descending. [42] By revealing the competing bids in real-time to every participating supplier, reverse auctions promote "information transparency". This, coupled with the dynamic bidding process, improves the chances of reaching the fair market value of the item. [43]

A double auction is a combination of both forward and reverse auctions. A Walrasian auction or Walrasian tâtonnement is a double auction in which the auctioneer takes bids from both buyers and sellers in a market of multiple goods. [44] The auctioneer progressively either raises or drops the current proposed price depending on the bids of both buyers and sellers, the auction concluding when supply and demand exactly balance. [45] As a high price tends to dampen demand while a low price tends to increase demand, in theory there is a particular price somewhere in the middle where supply and demand will match. [44] A Barter double auction is an auction where every participant has a demand and an offer consisting of multiple attributes and no money is involved. [46] For the mathematical modelling of satisfaction level, Euclidean distance is used, where the offer and demand are treated as vectors.

Price development

Auctions can be categorized into three types of procedures for auctions depending on the occurrence of a price development [40] during an auction run and its causes.

Driven by bidders only

An auctioneer and assistants scan the crowd for bidders Auction.jpg
An auctioneer and assistants scan the crowd for bidders
  • English auction, also known as an open ascending price auction. This type of auction is arguably the most common form of auction in use today. [1] Participants bid openly against one another, with each subsequent bid required to be higher than the previous bid. [2] An auctioneer may announce prices, bidders may call out their bids themselves (or have a proxy call out a bid on their behalf), or bids may be submitted electronically with the highest current bid publicly displayed. [2] In some cases a maximum bid might be left with the auctioneer, who may bid on behalf of the bidder according to the bidder's instructions. [2] The auction ends when no participant is willing to bid further, at which point the highest bidder pays their bid. [2] Alternatively, if the seller has set a minimum sale price in advance (the 'reserve' price) and the final bid does not reach that price the item will remain unsold. [2] Sometimes the auctioneer sets a minimum amount, sometimes known as a bidding increment, by which the next bid must exceed the current highest bid. [2] The most significant distinguishing factor of this auction type is that the current highest bid is always available to potential bidders, [2] although at that time there may be higher absentee bids held by the auctioneer which are not known to potential bidders. The English auction is commonly used for selling goods, most prominently antiques and artwork, [2] but also secondhand goods and real estate.
  • Auction by the candle. A type of auction, used in England for selling ships, in which the highest bid laid on the table wins after a burning candle goes out.
  • Scottish auction is an auction where all bidding should be completed within a certain time interval, which allows bidders an appropriate amount of time for consideration and avoids precipitate actions. [47]

Partially driven by time

A 1957 Dutch auction in Germany to sell fruit. Bundesarchiv B 145 Bild-F004491-0002, Kirschenversteigerung an der Mosel.jpg
A 1957 Dutch auction in Germany to sell fruit.
  • Dutch auction also known as an open descending price auction. [1] In the traditional Dutch auction the auctioneer begins with a high asking price for some quantity of like items; the price is lowered until a participant is willing to accept the auctioneer's price for some quantity of the goods in the lot or until the seller's reserve price is met. [2] If the first bidder does not purchase the entire lot, the auctioneer continues lowering the price until all of the items have been bid for or the reserve price is reached. Items are allocated based on bid order; the highest bidder selects their item(s) first followed by the second highest bidder, etc. In a modification, all of the winning participants pay only the last announced price for the items that they bid on. [1] The Dutch auction is named for its best known example, the Dutch tulip auctions. ("Dutch auction" is also sometimes used to describe online auctions where several identical goods are sold simultaneously to an equal number of high bidders). [48] In addition to cut flower sales in the Netherlands, Dutch auctions have also been used for perishable commodities such as fish and tobacco. [2] The Dutch auction is not widely used, except in market orders in stock or currency exchanges, which are functionally identical. [1]
  • Japanese auction is a variation of the Dutch auction with a low initial price that increases over time. As the price rises, participants must either signal intent to continue bidding or drop out of the auction, and no participant may enter or re-enter the auction once it has begun. Once only one participant remains in the auction, the auction ends and that participant wins the item at the current price. It has similarities to the ante in Poker. [49]

Single shot

  • First-price sealed-bid auction , [50] or a sealed-bid first-price auction/blind auction, is a type of auction where all bidders simultaneously submit sealed bids so that no bidder knows the bid of any other participant. The highest bidder pays the price they submitted. [1] [2] This type of auction is distinct from the English auction, in that bidders can only submit one bid each. Furthermore, as bidders cannot see the bids of other participants they cannot adjust their own bids accordingly. [2] From the theoretical perspective, this kind of bid process has been argued to be strategically equivalent to the Dutch auction. [51] However, empirical evidence from laboratory experiments has shown that Dutch auctions with high clock speeds yield lower prices than FPSB auctions. [52] [53] What are effectively sealed first-price auctions are commonly called tendering for procurement by companies and organisations, particularly for government contracts and auctions for mining leases. [2]
  • Vickrey auction, also known as a sealed-bid second-price auction. [54] This is identical to the sealed first-price auction except that the winning bidder pays the second-highest bid rather than their own. [55] Vickrey auctions are extremely important in auction theory, and commonly used in automated contexts such as real-time bidding for online advertising, but rarely in non-automated contexts. [2]

Properties of auctioned goods

The auction in Oulu, Finland in September 1962. Auctioneer shows a table lamp with a final price of FIM 6,100. The auction in Oulu 1962 (JOKAKAL3B-12356).tif
The auction in Oulu, Finland in September 1962. Auctioneer shows a table lamp with a final price of FIM 6,100.

Multiunit auctions sell more than one identical item at a time, rather than having separate auctions for each. This type can be further classified as either a uniform price auction or a discriminatory price auction. An example for them is spectrum auctions.

A combinatorial auction is any auction for the simultaneous sale of more than one item where bidders can place bids on an "all-or-nothing" basis on "packages" rather than just individual items. That is, a bidder can specify that they will pay for items A and B, but only if they get both. [56] In combinatorial auctions, determining the winning bidder(s) can be a complex process where even the bidder with the highest individual bid is not guaranteed to win. [56] For example, in an auction with four items (W, X, Y and Z), if Bidder A offers $50 for items W & Y, Bidder B offers $30 for items W & X, Bidder C offers $5 for items X & Z and Bidder D offers $30 for items Y & Z, the winners will be Bidders B & D while Bidder A misses out because the combined bids of Bidders B & D is higher ($60) than for Bidders A and C ($55). Deferred-acceptance auction is a special case of a combinatorial auction. [57]

Another special case of a combinatorial auction is the combinatorial clock auction (CCA), which combines a clock auction, during which bidders may provide their confirmations in response to the rising prices, with a subsequantial sealed bid auction, in which bidders submit sealed package bids. The auctioneer uses the final bids to compute the best value allocation and the Vickrey payments. [58] [59]

Generalized first-price auctions and Generalized second-price auctions offer slots for multiple bidders instead of making a single deal. The bidders get the slots according to the ranking of their bids. The second-price ruling is derived from the Vickrey auction and means the final deal sealing for the number one bidder is based on the second bidder's price.

Reserve price

A No-reserve auction (NR), also known as an absolute auction, is an auction in which the item for sale will be sold regardless of price. [60] [61] From the seller's perspective, advertising an auction as having no reserve price can be desirable because it potentially attracts a greater number of bidders due to the possibility of a bargain. [60] If more bidders attend the auction, a higher price might ultimately be achieved because of heightened competition from bidders. [61] This contrasts with a reserve auction, where the item for sale may not be sold if the final bid is not high enough to satisfy the seller. In practice, an auction advertised as "absolute" or "no-reserve" may nonetheless still not sell to the highest bidder on the day, for example, if the seller withdraws the item from the auction or extends the auction period indefinitely, [62] although these practices may be restricted by law in some jurisdictions or under the terms of sale available from the auctioneer.

A reserve auction is an auction where the item for sale may not be sold if the final bid is not high enough to satisfy the seller; that is, the seller reserves the right to accept or reject the highest bid. [61] In these cases, a set 'reserve' price known to the auctioneer, but not necessarily to the bidders, may have been set, below which the item may not be sold. [60] If the seller announces to the bidders the reserve price, it is a public reserve price auction. [63] In contrast, if the seller does not announce the reserve price before the sale, it is a secret reserve price auction. [64] However, potential bidders may be able to deduce an approximate reserve price, if one exists at all, from any estimate given in advance by the auction house. The reserve price may be fixed or discretionary. In the latter case, the decision to accept a bid is deferred to the auctioneer, who may accept a bid that is marginally below it. A reserve auction is safer for the seller than a no-reserve auction as they are not required to accept a low bid, but this could result in a lower final price if less interest is generated in the sale. [61]

Price of bidding

An all-pay auction is an auction in which all bidders must pay their bids regardless of whether they win. The highest bidder wins the item. All-pay auctions are primarily of academic interest, and may be used to model lobbying or bribery (bids are political contributions) or competitions such as a running race. [65] Bidding fee auction, a variation of all-pay auction, also known as a penny auction, often requires that each participant must pay a fixed price to place each bid, typically one penny (hence the name) higher than the current bid. When an auction's time period expires, the highest bidder wins the item and must pay a final bid price. [66] Unlike in a conventional auction, the final price is typically much lower than the value of the item, but all bidders (not just the winner) will have paid for each bid placed; the winner will buy the item at a very low price (plus price of rights-to-bid used), all the losers will have paid, and the seller will typically receive significantly more than the value of the item. [67] A senior auction is a variation on the all-pay auction, and has a defined loser in addition to the winner. The top two bidders must pay their full final bid amounts, and only the highest wins the auction. The intent is to make the high bidders bid above their upper limits. In the final rounds of bidding, when the current losing party has hit their maximum bid, they are encouraged to bid over their maximum (seen as a small loss) to avoid losing their maximum bid with no return (a very large loss). Another variation of all-pay auction, the top-up auction is primarily used for charity events. Losing bidders must pay the difference between their bid and the next lowest bid. The winning bidder pays the amount bid for the item, without top-up. In a Chinese auction, bidders make sealed bids in advance and their probability of winning grows with the relative size of their bids. [68]

Structure of a bid

In usual auctions like the English one, bids are prices. In Dutch and Japanese auctions, the bids are confirmations. In a version of the Brazilian auction, bids are numbers of units being traded. Structure elements of a bid are called attributes. If a bid is one number like price, it is a single-attribute auction. If bids consists of multiple-attributes, it is a multi-attribute auction. [69] [70]

A Yankee auction is a single-attribute multiunit auction running like a Dutch auction, where the bids are the portions of a total amount of identical units. [71] [72] [73] The amount of auctioned items is firm in a Yankee auction unlike a Brazilian auction. The portions of the total amount, bidders can bid, are limited to lower numbers than the total amount. Therefore, only a portion of the total amount will be traded for the best price and the rest to the suboptimal prices.

Visibility of bids

In an English auction, all current bids are visible to all bidders and in a sealed-bid auction, bidders only get to know if their bid was the best. Best/not best auctions are sealed-bid auctions with multiple bids, where the bidders submit their prices like in English auction and get responses about the leadership of their bid. [74] Rank auction is an extension of best/not best auction, where the bidders also see the rank of their bids. [75] Traffic-light auction shows traffic lights to bidders as a response to their bids. [76] These traffic lights depend on the position of the last bid in the distribution of all bids.

Buyout option

A buyout auction is an auction with an additional set price (the 'buyout' price) that any bidder can accept at any time during the auction, thereby immediately ending the auction and winning the item. This means that if an item offers its buyout price at the beginning, one participant can stop all other potential participants from bidding at all, or stop the bidding process before the bid price has reached the buyout price. [77] If no bidder chooses to utilize the buyout option before the end of bidding, the highest bidder wins and pays their bid. [77] Buyout options can be either temporary or permanent. [77] In a temporary-buyout auction the option to buy out the auction is not available after the first bid is placed. [77] In a permanent-buyout auction the buyout option remains available throughout the entire auction until the close of bidding. [77] The buyout price can either remain the same throughout the entire auction, or vary throughout according to rules or simply as decided by the seller. [77]

Winner selection

The winner selection in most auctions selects the best bid. Unique bid auctions offer a special winner selection: [78] the winner is the bidder with the lowest unique bid. The Chinese auction selects a winner partially based on randomness. [68]

The final price for the selected winner is not always conducted according to their final bid. In the case of the second-price ruling as in a Vickrey auction, the final price for the winner is based on the second bidder's price. A Proxy bid is a special case of second-price ruling used by eBay, where a predefined increment is added to the second highest bid in response to a yet higher bid.

Auctions with more than one winner are called multi-winner auctions. [79] Multiunit auction, Combinatorial auction, Generalized first-price auction and Generalized second-price auction are multi-winner auctions.

Cascading

Auctions can be cascaded, one after the other. For instance, an Amsterdam auction is a type of premium auction which begins as an English auction. Once only two bidders remain, each submits a sealed bid. The higher bidder wins, paying either the first or second price. Both finalists receive a premium: a proportion of the excess of the second price over the third price (at which English auction ended). [80] An Anglo-Dutch auction starts as an English or Japanese auction and then continues as a Dutch auction with a reduced number of bidders. [81] [82] A French auction is a preliminary sealed-bid auction before the actual auction, whose reserve price it determines. A sequential auction is an auction where the bidders can participate in a sequence of auctions. A Calcutta auction is a subtype of sequential auction, where the ordering in the sequence is determined by random. [83] A simultaneous ascending auction is an opposite of a sequential auction, where the auctions are run in parallel. [84]

Other features

The silent auction is a variant of the English auction in which bids are written on a sheet of paper. At the predetermined end of the auction, the highest listed bidder wins the item. [85] This auction is often used in charity events, with many items auctioned simultaneously and "closed" at a common finish time. [85] [86] The auction is "silent" in that there is no auctioneer selling individual items; [85] the bidders write their bids on a bidding sheet often left on a table near the item. [87] At charity auctions, bid sheets usually have a fixed starting amount, predetermined bid increments, and a "guaranteed bid" amount which works the same as a "buy now" amount. Other variations of this type of auction may include sealed bids. [85] The highest bidder pays the price they submitted. [85]

In private value auctions, every bidder has their own valuation of the auctioned good. [88] A common value auction is opposite, where the valuation of the auctioned good is identical among the bidders.

Contexts

The range of auctions' contexts is extremely wide and one can buy almost anything, from a house to an endowment policy and everything in between. Some of the recent developments have been the use of the Internet both as a means of disseminating information about various auctions and as a vehicle for hosting auctions themselves.

Human commodity auctions

A slave auction A Slave Auction.jpg
A slave auction

As already mentioned in the history section, auctions have been used to trade commodified people from the very first. Auctions have been used in slave markets throughout history until modern times in the post-Gaddafi era Libya. [89] [90] [91] The word for slave auction in the Atlantic slave trade was scramble. A child auction is a Swedish and Finnish historical practice of selling children into slavery-like conditions by authorities using a descending English auction. [92] Fattigauktion is a similar Swedish practice involving poor people being auctioned to church organizations. [93] Trade of wives by auctions was also a common practice throughout history. For instance, in the old English custom of wife selling, a wife was divorced by selling her in a public auction for the highest bid. [94] ISIS conducted slave auctions to sell up to 7,000 Yazidi women as reported in 2020. [95] [96]

A virginity auction is the voluntary practice of individuals seeking to sell their own virginity to the highest bid. [97] Cricket players are routinely put up for auction, whereby cricket teams can bid for their services. [98] [99] Indian Premier League (IPL) started annual public auctioning of cricket players in 2008 as an entertainment for mass consumption. [100] Also, Bangladesh Premier League conducts cricket player auctions, starting in 2012. [101]

Real estate auctions

An estate agent conducting an auction of real estate in Melbourne, Victoria, Australia. Melbourne Real Estate Auctioneer.jpg
An estate agent conducting an auction of real estate in Melbourne, Victoria, Australia.

In some countries, such as Australia, auctioning is a common method for the sale of real estate. Auctions were traditionally used as an alternative to the private sale/treaty method to sell property that, due to their unique characteristics, were difficult to determine a price for. The law does not require a vendor to disclose their reserve price prior to the auction. During the 1990s and 2000s, auctions became the primary method for the sale of real estate in the two largest cities, Melbourne and Sydney. This was largely due to the fact that in a private sale the vendor has disclosed the price that they want, and potential purchasers would attempt to low-ball the price, whereas in an auction purchasers do not know what the vendor wants, and thus need to keep lifting the price until the reserve price is reached.

The method has been the subject of increased controversy during the twenty-first century as house prices sky-rocketed. The rapidly rising housing market saw many homes, especially in Victoria and New South Wales, selling for significantly more than both the vendors' reserve price and the advertised price range. Subsequently, the auction systems' lack of transparency about the value of the property was brought into question, with estate agents and their vendor clients being accused of "under-quoting". Significant attention was given to the matter by the Australian media, with the government in Victoria eventually bowing to pressure and implementing changes to legislation in an effort to increase transparency. [102]

In the UK, historically, auction houses were perceived to sell properties which may have been repossessedwhere a home owner fails to make regular mortgage paymentsor were probate sales (i.e.,a family home being sold by the heirs). However, more recently, selling at auction has become an alternative to a normal property sale, due to the speedy nature of the entire process. [103]

In China, land auctions are under the sole control of local government officials. Because some developers may use bribes to please government officials to obtain the right to purchase the land, the central government requires that future land auctions be conducted using a spectrum auction in order to prevent the spread of corruption. Although this method cannot completely solve the problem of corruption, it is still a significant contribution to the auction. [104]

Auctions by authorities

Pima County, Arizona delinquent property tax list for auction by the County Treasurer Delinquent property tax lien list.jpg
Pima County, Arizona delinquent property tax list for auction by the County Treasurer

A government auction is simply an auction held on behalf of a government body generally at a general sale. Items for sale are often surplus needed to be liquidated. Auctions ordered by estate executors enter the assets of individuals who have perhaps died intestate (those who have died without leaving a will), or in debt. In legal contexts where forced auctions occur, as when one's farm or house is sold at auction on the courthouse steps. Property seized for non-payment of property taxes, or under foreclosure, is sold in this manner. Police auctions are generally held at general auctions, although some forces use online sites including eBay, to dispose of lost and found and seized goods. Debt auctions, in which governments issue and sell debt obligations, such as bonds, to investors. The auction is usually sealed and the uniform price paid by the investors is typically the best non-winning bid. In most cases, investors can also place so-called non-competitive bids, which indicates interest to purchase the debt obligation at the resulting price, whatever it may be. Some states use courts to run such auctions. In spectrum auctions conducted by the government, companies purchase licenses to use portions of the electromagnetic spectrum for communications (e.g., mobile phone networks). In certain jurisdictions, if a storage facility's tenant fails to pay rent, the contents of their locker(s) may be sold at a public auction. Several television shows focus on such auctions, including Storage Wars and Auction Hunters .

Commodity auctions

Wool buyers' room at a wool auction, Newcastle, NSW Wool auction.JPG
Wool buyers' room at a wool auction, Newcastle, NSW
Grass-fed cattle at auction, Walcha, NSW Cattle sale.jpg
Grass-fed cattle at auction, Walcha, NSW
Farm clearing sale, Woolbrook, NSW Clearing sale.JPG
Farm clearing sale, Woolbrook, NSW
Tuna auction at the Tsukiji fish market in Tokyo Auction Tsukiji fishmarket.jpg
Tuna auction at the Tsukiji fish market in Tokyo
Fish auction in Honolulu, Hawaii Fish auction Hawaii.jpg
Fish auction in Honolulu, Hawaii

Auctions are used to trade commodities; for example, fish wholesale auctions. In wool auctions, wool is traded in the international market. [105] The wine auction business offers serious collectors an opportunity to gain access to rare bottles and mature vintages, which are not typically available through retail channels. In livestock auctions, sheep, cattle, pigs and other livestock are sold. Sometimes very large numbers of stock are auctioned, such as the regular sales of 50,000 or more sheep during a day in New South Wales. [106] In timber auctions, companies purchase licenses to log on government land. In timber allocation auctions, companies purchase timber directly from the government. [107] In electricity auctions, large-scale generators and distributors of electricity bid on generating contracts. Produce auctions link growers to localized wholesale buyers (buyers who are interested in acquiring large quantities of locally grown produce). [108]

Online auctions

Online auctions are a form of E-commerce that relies on the advantages of a digital platform's ability to overcome geographical constraints, provide real-time information and reduce transaction costs, bringing greater convenience to people and allowing more people to participate as bidders, as well as being able to view a greater selection of auctions. [109] Websites like eBay provide a potential market of millions of bidders to sellers. Established auction houses, as well as specialist internet auctions, sell many things online, from antiques and collectibles to holidays, air travel, brand new computers, and household equipment. Private electronic markets use combinatorial auction techniques to continuously sell commodities (coal, iron ore, grain, water, etc.) online to a pre-qualified group of buyers (based on price and non-price factors). [110] Furthermore, online auctions facilitate the process for prospective bidders to discover and evaluate items by enabling searches across numerous auctions and employing filters to refine their selections. [111]

On the other hand, an alternative perspective suggests that the format of online auctions could also give rise to collusive conduct and other types of market manipulation, potentially skewing the market and diminishing its efficiency. [109] Firstly, online auctions might enable bidders to obscure their identities, such as utilizing pseudonyms or multiple accounts to maintain anonymity. This concealment could simplify collusion without detection. [112] Secondly, online auctions might ease the implementation of collusive arrangements among bidders. The accessibility of bidding data in online auctions, for instance, allows colluding bidders to monitor each other's bids, guarantee adherence to their agreements, and penalize non-compliance. This enhanced oversight capacity strengthens the stability of collusive agreements. [113]

Unique item auctions

Other contexts

Bidding strategy

By the bidders

An 18th century Chinese meiping porcelain vase. Porcelain has long been a staple at art sales. In 2005, a 14th-century Chinese porcelain piece was sold by Christie's for PS16 million, or US$28 million. It set a world auction record for any ceramic work of art. Vase meiping Musee Guimet 2418.jpg
An 18th century Chinese meiping porcelain vase. Porcelain has long been a staple at art sales. In 2005, a 14th-century Chinese porcelain piece was sold by Christie's for £16 million, or US$28 million. It set a world auction record for any ceramic work of art.

Katehakis and Puranam provided the first model [125] for the problem of optimal bidding for a firm that in each period procures items to meet a random demand by participating in a finite sequence of auctions. In this model an item valuation derives from the sale of the acquired items via their demand distribution, sale price, acquisition cost, salvage value and lost sales. They established monotonicity properties for the value function and the optimal dynamic bid policy. They also provided a model [126] for the case in which the buyer must acquire a fixed number of items either at a fixed buy-it-now price in the open market or by participating in a sequence of auctions. The objective of the buyer is to minimize their expected total cost for acquiring the fixed number of items.

During an auction, the seller might possess more comprehensive knowledge regarding the item on offer compared to the buyer, creating an information asymmetry. [127] This lack of information could lead the bidder to overvalue the item and consequently pay a higher price, resulting in the winner's curse. [128] Nevertheless, bidders may also choose to employ bid shading as a strategy to circumvent this predicament. Bid shading is placing a bid which is below the bidder's actual value for the item. Such a strategy risks losing the auction but has the possibility of winning at a low price. Bid shading can also be a strategy to avoid the winner's curse. In either case, the allocation of resources may be inefficient, as the product will not ultimately be acquired by the individual who values it the most. Instead, it will go to the person who either overvalues it the most or effectively employs bid shading. [129]

Auction cancellation hunters bid minimal amounts on multiple auctions and expect them to be cancelled. If an auction is cancelled by the seller, they will claim for damages in the amount of the difference between the maximum bid at the time of the auction cancellation and the price of a replacement purchase of the offered item in the auction, when the market is in equilibrium, even if the seller has not sold any of the items, the shadow of bidding still exists. This is the self-protection instinct of the auction market. In order to make this transaction fairer. [130] Auction sniping is the practice of placing a bid at the last moment of the auction. According to the analysis of auction data from eBay, in general, experienced bidders are more likely to snipe in auctions, and those who snipe in auctions are more likely to win. [131] Jump bidding is an aggressive tactic of increasing every bid by high amounts. Calor licitantis is also known as "auction fever" and describes the irrational behavior of bidders at auctions. Suicide bidding is practice in reverse auctions, whereby a bidder submits a bid, which ends up in a loss for this bidder. [132]

Collusion

Whenever bidders at an auction are aware of the identity of the other bidders there is a risk that they will form a "ring" or "pool" and thus manipulate the auction result, a practice known as collusion or more specially bid-rigging. [133] [134] [135] By agreeing to bid only against outsiders, never against members of the "ring", competition becomes weaker, which may dramatically affect the final price level. After the end of the official auction, an unofficial auction may take place among the "ring" members. The difference in price between the two auctions could then be split among the members. This form of a ring was used as a central plot device in the opening episode of the 1979 British television series The House of Caradus, 'For Love or Money', uncovered by Helena Caradus on her return from Paris.

In the UK, this auction practice is illegal. [136] It jeopardizes competition on the auction and can demotivate other bidders from participating. It robs the seller of the true value of their good and reduces the auctioneer's commission.

Beyond explicit collusion, a tacit coordination of bidders to keep bids low is at least theoretically possible. In case of spectrum auctions, the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) experimented with precautions restricting visibility of bids, limiting the number of bids, click-box bidding, and anonymous bidding in order to prevent bidders from signalling bidding information by embedding it into digits of the bids. [137] Actions within the auction mechanism serve as a communication channel for collusive behavior, once no other channels are legal.

By the auctioneer

Chandelier or rafter bidding

This is the practice, especially by high-end art auctioneers, [138] of raising false bids at crucial times in the bidding in order to create the appearance of greater demand or to extend bidding momentum for a work on offer. To call out these nonexistent bids auctioneers might fix their gaze at a point in the auction room that is difficult for the audience to pin down. [139] The practice is frowned upon in the industry. [139] In the United States, chandelier bidding is not illegal. In fact, an auctioneer may bid up the price of an item to the reserve price, which is a threshold below which the consignor may refuse to sell the item. However, the auction house is required to disclose this information.

In the United Kingdom this practice is legal on property auctions up to but not including the reserve price, and is also known as off-the-wall bidding. [140]

Collusion involving auctioneer

A ring can also be used to increase the price of an auction lot, in which the owner of the object being auctioned may increase competition by taking part in the bidding themself, but drop out of the bidding just before the final bid. This form of a ring was used as a central plot device in an episode of the British television series Lovejoy (series 4, episode 3), in which the price of a watercolour by the (fictional) Jessie Webb is inflated so that others by the same artist could be sold for more than their purchase price. In an English auction, a dummy bid is a bid made by a dummy bidder acting in collusion with the auctioneer or vendor, designed to deceive genuine bidders into paying more. In a first-price auction, a dummy bid is an unfavourable bid designed so as not to become the winning bid. (The bidder does not want to win this auction, but they want to make sure to be invited to the next auction).

In Britain and many other countries, rings and other forms of bidding on one's own object are illegal. In Australia, a dummy bid or also a shill is a criminal offence, but a vendor bid or a co-owner bid below the reserve price is permitted if clearly declared as such by the auctioneer. These are all official legal terms in Australia but may have other meanings elsewhere. A co-owner is one of two or several owners (who disagree among themselves). In Sweden and many other countries, there are no legal restrictions, but it will severely hurt the reputation of an auction house that knowingly permits any other bids except genuine bids. If the reserve is not reached this should be clearly declared. In South Africa, auctioneers can use their staff or any bidder to raise the price as long as it is disclosed before the auction sale. Rael Levitt's companies The Auction Alliance controversy focused on vendor bidding and led to its downfall in 2012. [141] [142]

Suggested opening bid (SOB)

There will usually be an estimate of what price the lot will fetch. In an ascending open auction, it is considered important to get at least a 50-percent increase in the bids from start to finish. To accomplish this, the auctioneer must start the auction by announcing a suggested opening bid (SOB) that is low enough to be immediately accepted by one of the bidders. [143] Once there is an opening bid, there will quickly be several other, higher bids submitted. Experienced auctioneers will often select an SOB that is about 45 percent of the (lowest) estimate. Thus there is a certain margin of safety to ensure that there will indeed be a lively auction with many bids submitted. Several observations indicate that the lower the SOB, the higher the final winning bid. This is due to the increase in the number of bidders attracted by the low SOB.

A chi-squared distribution shows many low bids but few high bids. Bids "show up together"; without several low bids there will not be any high bids.

Another approach to choosing a SOB: The auctioneer may achieve good success by asking the expected final sales price for the item, as this method suggests to the potential buyers the item's particular value. For instance, an auctioneer is about to sell a $1,000 car at a sale. Instead of asking $100, hoping to entice wide interest, the auctioneer may suggest an opening bid of $1,000; although the first bidder may begin bidding at a mere $100, the final bid may more likely approach $1,000.

Terminology

Duo Yun Xuan auction house in Malacca, Malaysia Duo Yun Xuan Auction House.JPG
Duo Yun Xuan auction house in Malacca, Malaysia
Hammer used in auctions. 2021-04-30 Leilao de Concessao dos Servicos de Saneamento em 35 Municipios do estado do Rio de Janeiro - 22.jpg
Hammer used in auctions.

JEL classification

The Journal of Economic Literature (JEL) classification code for auctions is D44. [150]

See also

Notes

  1. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Krishna, 2002: p2
  2. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 McAfee, R. Preston; McMillan, John (1987). "Auctions and Bidding". Journal of Economic Literature. 25 (2): 699–738. ISSN   0022-0515. JSTOR   2726107.
  3. Krishna, 2002: p1
  4. 1 2 3 Shubik, 2004: p214
  5. 1 2 3 Cassady, Ralph (1967). Auctions and Auctioneering. University of California Press. ISBN   978-0-520-03978-0.
  6. Morcillo, Marta Garcia (2008). "Staging Power and Authority at Roman Auctions". Ancient Society. 38: 153–181. doi:10.2143/AS.38.0.2033274. JSTOR   44080266.
  7. 1 2 3 Shubik, 2004: p215
  8. 1 2 Doyle, Robert A.; Baska, Steve (November 2002), "History of Auctions: From ancient Rome to today's high-tech auctions", Auctioneer, archived from the original on 2008-05-17, retrieved 2008-06-22
  9. Vohra, Rakesh V.; Krishnamurthi, Lakshman (2012-03-05). Principles of Pricing: An Analytical Approach. Cambridge University Press. p. 81. ISBN   978-1-107-01065-9.
  10. Hekster, Olivier (2008-07-03). Rome and its Empire, AD 193-284. Edinburgh University Press. p. 13. ISBN   978-0-7486-2992-3.
  11. Metcalf, William E. (2012-02-23). The Oxford Handbook of Greek and Roman Coinage. Oxford UP. p. 499. ISBN   978-0-19-530574-6.
  12. R.W. Patten. "Tatworth Candle Auction." Folklore 81, No. 2 (Summer 1970), 132-135
  13. William S. Walsh A Handy Book Of Curious Information Comprising Strange Happenings in the Life of Men and Animals, Odd Statistics, Extraordinary Phenomena and Out of the Way Facts Concerning the Wonderlands of the Earth. Philadelphia: J.B. Lippincott Co., 1913. 63-64.
  14. 1 2 3 Varoli, John (2007-10-02), "Swedish Auction House to Sell 8 Million Euros of Russian Art", Bloomberg.com News, Moscow: Bloomberg Finance L.P., retrieved 2008-06-21
  15. About the company, Stockholm, Sweden: Stockholms Auktionsverk, archived from the original on May 22, 2008, retrieved 2008-06-21
  16. "About Us". Christies.com. Retrieved 3 December 2008. James Christie conducted the first sale in London on 5 December 1766.
  17. Gazetteer and London Daily Advertiser (London, England), Saturday, 25 September 1762; Issue 10460
  18. Stoica, Michael (August 2007), The Business of Art, archived from the original on 2008-06-07, retrieved 2008-06-21
  19. Kwesi, DeGraft-Hanson (2010-01-01). "Unearthing the Weeping Time: Savannah's Ten Broeck Race Course and 1859 Slave Sale". Southern Spaces. 2010. doi: 10.18737/M76K6J . ISSN   1551-2754.
  20. Neufeld, Rob (2019-04-28). "Visiting Our Past: Brightleaf tobacco intoxication the 1880s". Asheville Citizen-Times . Retrieved 2019-04-28.
  21. "The Heyday of the Auction", The Economist, vol. 352, no. 8129, pp. 67–68, 1999-07-24, ISSN   0013-0613
  22. Huijun, Feng (1994). "The Application of Multi-objective Optimization to Bid Decision". Systems Engineering --- Theory & Practice. 1994–12.
  23. Cameron, Lisa J.; Cramton, Peter; Wilson, Robert (December 1997). "Using auctions to divest generation assets" (PDF). The Electricity Journal. 10 (10): 22–31. Bibcode:1997ElecJ..10j..22C. doi:10.1016/S1040-6190(97)80317-X. hdl: 1903/7076 .
  24. Hultmark, Christina; Ramberg, Christina; Kuner, Christopher (2002). Internet Marketplaces: The Law of Auctions and Exchanges Online. Oxford University Press. p. 40. ISBN   978-0-19-925429-3.
  25. "Enterprise Sourcing Cockpit 4.5: Höhere Benutzerfreundlichkeit und neue Auktionsform". PortalDerWirtschaft.de (in German).
  26. Bernhard, Andreas. "Elektronische Auktionen und Ausschreibungen bei Linde Gas – Die Spieltheorie im E-Sourcing" (PDF). chemietechnik.de. Archived from the original (PDF) on 29 January 2020. Retrieved 29 January 2020.
  27. Vragov, Roumen (2004). "Why is eBay the King of Internet Auctions? An Institutional Analysis Perspective". E-Service Journal. 3 (3): 5–28. doi:10.2979/esj.2004.3.3.5. S2CID   62190885.
  28. Sotheby's (2007-06-07), Sotheby's Sets a New World Record for Sculpture at Auction (PDF), retrieved 2008-06-20
  29. New York Times (2008-01-10), "Artemis and Stag at Met Museum", The New York Times, retrieved 2008-06-20
  30. Jehiel, Philippe; Moldovanu, Benny; Ottaviani, Marco; Propper, Carol (2003). "An Economic Perspective on Auctions". Economic Policy. 18 (36): 269–308. doi:10.1111/1468-0327.00107. JSTOR   1344658.
  31. "Auction Industry Sees Growth in Real Estate". Realtor Mag. NAR. Retrieved 21 June 2017.
  32. Kalinin, Nikita; Vershinin, Mark (2020-10-25). "Strategic analysis of the Russian crab quota auction in 2019". Marine Policy. 122: 104266. Bibcode:2020MarPo.12204266K. doi:10.1016/j.marpol.2020.104266. ISSN   0308-597X. S2CID   226354742.
  33. Gold: Does Gordon Brown's regret selling half of Britains' gold reserves 10 years ago?, The Daily Telegraph, 8 May 2009
  34. "From the Priciest Painting to the Richest Wine Bottle, Here Are the Most Expensive Objects Ever Sold at Auction". artnet News. 2018-11-28. Retrieved 2020-11-20.
  35. "Leading auction houses worldwide in 2018 by fine art revenue". Statista. Retrieved 2020-11-20.
  36. Klemperer, Paul (July 1999). "Auction Theory: A Guide to the Literature" (PDF). Journal of Economic Surveys. 13 (3): 227–286. doi:10.1111/1467-6419.00083.
  37. Charles Riley. "Nobel Prize in economics awarded to Paul Milgrom and Robert Wilson for auction theory". CNN. Retrieved 13 October 2020.
  38. Ganguly, D.; Chakraborty, Samit (2008). "E Commerce - Forward and Reverse Auction - A Managerial Tool to Succeed over Business Competitiveness". 2008 Ninth ACIS International Conference on Software Engineering, Artificial Intelligence, Networking, and Parallel/Distributed Computing. pp. 447–452. doi:10.1109/SNPD.2008.51. ISBN   978-0-7695-3263-9. S2CID   7466904.
  39. Preist, Chris; Bartolini, Claudio; Byde, Andrew (2003). "Agent-based service composition through simultaneous negotiation in forward and reverse auctions". Proceedings of the 4th ACM conference on Electronic commerce. pp. 55–63. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.1.1755 . doi:10.1145/779928.779936. ISBN   1-58113-679-X. S2CID   1868153.
  40. 1 2 Friedrich, Michael; Ignatov, Dmitry (2019). "General Game Playing B-to-B Price Negotiations" (PDF). CEUR Workshop Proceedings. 2479: 89–99.
  41. Schoenherr, Tobias; Mabert, Vincent A. (September–October 2007), "Online reverse auctions: Common myths versus evolving reality", Business Horizons, 50 (5): 373–384, doi:10.1016/j.bushor.2007.03.003
  42. "The Benefits of a Reverse Dutch Auction". Procurehere Blog. 2018-01-15. Archived from the original on 2019-04-30. Retrieved 2019-04-30.
  43. Moshe, Shalev; Stee, Asbjornsen (Fall 2010). "Electronic reverse auctions and the public sector – factors of success". J. Public Procurement. 10 (3): 428–452. Retrieved 19 January 2014.
  44. 1 2 Milgrom, 2004: p267
  45. Milgrom, 2004: pp. 267-268
  46. Tagiew, Rustam (22 May 2009). "Towards Barter Double Auction as Model for Bilateral Social Cooperations". arXiv: 0905.3709 [cs.GT].
  47. Hultmark, Christina; Ramberg, Christina; Kuner, Christopher (2002). Internet Marketplaces: The Law of Auctions and Exchanges Online. Oxford University Press. ISBN   978-0-19-925429-3 . Retrieved 29 August 2020.
  48. eBay, Selling Multiple Items in a Listing (Dutch Auction), archived from the original on 2008-12-17, retrieved 2009-01-09
  49. "Auction Types & Terms". Auctusdev.com. Archived from the original on 2013-01-17. Retrieved 2012-12-26.
  50. Shor, Mikhael, "blind auction" Dictionary of Game Theory Terms Archived 2007-05-04 at the Wayback Machine
  51. Krishna, 2002: p13
  52. Katok, E.; Kwasnica, A.M. (2008). "Time is money: The effect of clock speed on seller's revenue in Dutch auctions" (PDF). Experimental Economics . 11 (4): 344–357. doi:10.1007/s10683-007-9169-x. S2CID   17613279.
  53. Adam, M. T. P.; Krämer, J.; Weinhardt, C. (2012). "Excitement up! Price down! Measuring emotions in Dutch auctions". International Journal of Electronic Commerce. 11 (4): 7–39. doi:10.2753/JEC1086-4415170201. S2CID   31932319.
  54. Krishna, 2002: p9
  55. Krishna, 2002: p3
  56. 1 2 Pekec, Aleksandar; Rothkopf, Michael H. (November 2003), "Combinatorial auction design", Management Science, 49 (11): 1485–1503, Bibcode:2003PNAS..10011153P, doi:10.1287/mnsc.49.11.1485.20585, ISSN   1526-5501, archived from the original on 2007-09-11, retrieved 2008-06-26
  57. Milgromy, Paul; Segal, Ilya (September 11, 2014). "Deferred-Acceptance Auctions and RadioSpectrum Reallocation". CiteSeerX   10.1.1.715.9582 .
  58. Bichler, Martin; Goeree, Jacob K. (26 October 2017). Handbook of Spectrum Auction Design. Cambridge University Press. ISBN   978-1-107-13534-5 . Retrieved 22 October 2020.
  59. Ausubel, Lawrence M.; Baranov, Oleg (1 October 2017). "A Practical Guide to the Combinatorial Clock Auction". The Economic Journal. 127 (605): F334–F350. doi:10.1111/ecoj.12404. ISSN   0013-0133. S2CID   26571660.
  60. 1 2 3 Fisher, Steven (2006), The Real Estate Investor's Handbook: The Complete Guide for the Individual Investor , Ocala, Florida: Atlantic Publishing Company, pp.  89–90, ISBN   978-0-910627-69-6
  61. 1 2 3 4 Good, Steven L.; Lynn, Paul A. (January 2007), "The eBay Effect", Commercial Investment Real Estate, CCIM Institute, archived from the original on 2010-10-31, retrieved 2009-06-25
  62. Leichman, Laurence (1996), 90% off! real estate, Ocala, Florida: Leichman Assoc Pubns, pp. 78–79, ISBN   978-0-9636867-7-0
  63. Riley, J.G.; Samuelson, W.F. (1981). "Optimal Auctions" (PDF). The American Economic Review. 71: 381–392.
  64. Elyakime, B.; Laffont, J.J.; Loisel, P.; Vuong, Q. (1994). "First-Price Sealed-Bid Auctions with Secret Reservation Prices". Annales d'Économie et de Statistique. 34 (34): 115–141. doi:10.2307/20075949. JSTOR   20075949.
  65. Milgrom, 2004: p119
  66. Nasri, Grace (2011-04-07). "The Seduction of the Penny Auction". Huffington Post. Retrieved 2011-04-27.
  67. "QuiBids.com Reviews – Legit or Scam?". Reviewopedia.com. Archived from the original on 1 February 2013. Retrieved 13 November 2012.
  68. 1 2 "Chinese Auction". Fundraising Help. 17 January 2006.
  69. Pla, Albert; López, Beatriz; Murillo, Javier; Maudet, Nicolas (August 2014). "Multi-attribute auctions with different types of attributes: Enacting properties in multi-attribute auctions". Expert Systems with Applications. 41 (10): 4829–4843. doi:10.1016/j.eswa.2014.02.023. hdl: 10256/9601 .
  70. Huang, He; Liu, Liming; Parker, Geoffrey; Tan, Yinliang (Ricky); Xu, Hongyan (26 December 2018). "Multi-Attribute Procurement Auctions in the Presence of Satisfaction Risk". Production and Operations Management. 28 (5): 1206–1221. doi: 10.1111/poms.12979 .
  71. "Yankee Auction". Game Theory .net.
  72. "Cigar Auctioneer".
  73. "E-Auctions in Sourcing: Yankee Auction". eSourcing | Wiki. Archived from the original on 2020-01-27. Retrieved 2020-02-07.
  74. Eichstädt, Tilman (2007). "Designing Reverse Auctions for B-2-B Procurement Evidence from the German Industry". Negotiation and Market Engineering. Dagstuhl Seminar Proceedings. 6461. Internationales Begegnungs- und Forschungszentrum für Informatik (IBFI), Schloss Dagstuhl, Germany: 1–9. doi: 10.4230/DagSemProc.06461.8 .
  75. Eichstädt, Tilman (2008). "Applying Auction Theory to Procurement Auctions – an Empirical Study Among German Corporations". Negotiation, Auctions, and Market Engineering. Lecture Notes in Business Information Processing. Vol. 2. Springer. pp. 58–67. doi:10.1007/978-3-540-77554-6_4. ISBN   978-3-540-77553-9.
  76. Berz, Gregor (2015). "The Commitment of Negotiation Processes". Game Theory Bargaining and Auction Strategies. pp. 144–159. doi:10.1057/9781137475428_11. ISBN   978-1-349-69293-4.
  77. 1 2 3 4 5 6 Gallien, Jérémie; Gupta, Shobhit (May 2007), "Temporary and Permanent Buyout Prices in Online Auctions", Management Science, 53 (5): 814–833, doi:10.1287/mnsc.1060.0650, hdl: 1721.1/7468 , ISSN   1526-5501
  78. Costa-Gomes, Miguel A.; Shimoji, Makoto (May 2014). "Theoretical approaches to lowest unique bid auctions". Journal of Mathematical Economics. 52: 16–24. doi:10.1016/j.jmateco.2014.02.011.
  79. Zhang, Wen-zhu; Wang, Ling-yun (2012). "Dynamic spectrum allocation based on one-band multi-winner auction". Journal on Communications. 2012–02.
  80. "The Amsterdam Auction" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2016-06-29. Retrieved 2016-05-24.
  81. Quint, Dan (Oct 16, 2007). "Lecture 12" (PDF). Econ 805 – Advanced Micro Theory I.
  82. Marszalec, Daniel. "The Anglo-Dutch Auction" (PDF). Retrieved 28 January 2020.
  83. Seshadri, S; Shapira, Z; Tucci, CL (2003). "Venture capital investing and the "Calcutta Auction"". In Ginsberg, Ari; Hasan, Iftekhar (eds.). New Venture Investment: Choices and Consequences. Elsevier. pp. 19–42. ISBN   0-444-51239-X.
  84. Peter, Cramton (2006), "Simultaneous Ascending Auctions", in Cramton, Peter; Shoham, Yoav; Steinberg, Richard (eds.), Combinatorial Auctions, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, ISBN   978-0-262-03342-8
  85. 1 2 3 4 5 Isaac, R. Mark; Schnier, Kurt (October 2005), "Silent auctions in the field and in the laboratory", Economic Inquiry, 43 (4): 715–733, doi:10.1093/ei/cbi050, ISSN   0095-2583, S2CID   153682553
  86. "Best Silent Auction Closing Time For Your Fundraiser". 14 April 2016. Retrieved 2017-03-29.
  87. Milgrom, 2004: p268
  88. "Economic Classroom Experiments/Private Value Auctions – Wikiversity". en.wikiversity.org. Retrieved 2019-07-16.
  89. "What You Need to Know About the Libyan Slave Trade". Time. Retrieved 26 January 2020.
  90. Vonberg, Judith. "UK lawmakers debate Libya slave auction footage". CNN. Retrieved 26 January 2020.
  91. Gladstone, Rick (20 November 2017). "U.N. Chief 'Horrified' by Report of Libya Slave Auction". The New York Times. The New York Times. Retrieved 26 January 2020.
  92. Lundberg, Sofia (2000). "Child Auctions in Nineteenth Century Sweden: An Analysis of Price Differences". The Journal of Human Resources. 35 (2): 279–298. doi:10.2307/146326. JSTOR   146326.
  93. Johansson, Mariette (Spring 2009). Fattigvården i Kristdala socken 1881-1890: en studie av en småländsk landsbygdssocken (Master thesis) (in Swedish). Högskolan på Gotland. Retrieved 4 August 2022.
  94. Cave, Edward; Nichols, John (April 1832), "The Contrast, by the Author of "Yes and No"", The Gentleman's Magazine , 102: 347
  95. "ISIS Terror: Yazidi Woman Recalls Horrors of Slave Auction". NBC News. Retrieved 30 August 2020.
  96. "'I was sold seven times': Yazidi women welcomed back into the faith". The Guardian. 1 July 2017. Retrieved 30 August 2020.
  97. Gordon, Claire (9 February 2010). How Much Is Virginity Worth, Slate (magazine)
  98. "IPL Auction 2020, IPL Auction Players List, Auction Date, Results". Hindustan Times. Retrieved 26 September 2020.
  99. Sportstar, Team. "IPL 2020: Full list of players in auction pool on December 19". Sportstar. Retrieved 26 September 2020.
  100. "Reducing Cricketers into Cattle: The IPL Destroys the Spirit of Sports – The New Leam". thenewleam.com/. Retrieved 5 September 2020.
  101. "Afridi and Gayle fetch highest BPL prices | ESPNcricinfo.com". espncricinfo.com. Retrieved 5 September 2020.
  102. "Understanding underquoting". Consumer Affairs Victoria. CAV. Archived from the original on 28 February 2019. Retrieved 9 December 2018.
  103. ZFN (2021-08-22). "Building Survey of Auction Properties". ZFN. Retrieved 2021-08-27.
  104. Cai, Hongbin; Henderson, J. Vernon; Qinghua, Zhang (2013). "China's land market auctions: evidence of corruption?". The RAND Journal of Economics. 44 (3): 488–521. doi:10.1111/1756-2171.12028. JSTOR   43186429. PMC   4262968 . PMID   25506125. S2CID   16101212.
  105. "Combined factors hit wool auctions hard". ABC Rural. 2003-04-30. Archived from the original on 2005-04-28.
  106. The Land Newspaper, Prime sheep, Rural Press, 13 August 2009.
  107. Forest Auctions
  108. Gray, T. W. (2005). "Local-based, alternative-marketing strategy could help save more small farms". Rural Cooperatives. 72: 20–3.
  109. 1 2 Bajari, Patrick; Hortaçsu, Ali (2004-05-01). "Economic Insights from Internet Auctions". Journal of Economic Literature. 42 (2): 457–486. doi:10.1257/0022051041409075. ISSN   0022-0515.
  110. Zhong, Hong; Li, Song; Cheng, Ting-Fang; Chang, Chin-Chen (2016). "An Efficient Electronic English Auction System with a Secure On-Shelf Mechanism and Privacy Preserving". Journal of Electrical and Computer Engineering. 2016: 1–14. doi: 10.1155/2016/6567146 .
  111. Bakos, J. Yannis (1997-12-01). "Reducing Buyer Search Costs: Implications for Electronic Marketplaces". Management Science. 43 (12): 1676–1692. doi:10.1287/mnsc.43.12.1676. ISSN   0025-1909.
  112. Houser, Daniel; Wooders, John (2006-06-27). "Reputation in Auctions: Theory, and Evidence from eBay". Journal of Economics & Management Strategy. 15 (2): 353–369. doi:10.1111/j.1530-9134.2006.00103.x. ISSN   1058-6407. S2CID   8696236.
  113. Marshall, Robert C.; Marx, Leslie M. (2012-04-27). The Economics of Collusion: Cartels and Bidding Rings. doi:10.7551/mitpress/9011.001.0001. ISBN   9780262301503.
  114. "Canadian Museum of Civilization and Canada Postal Museum – Auction of Fine Art and Stamps". Archived from the original on 2013-11-13. Retrieved 25 May 2018.
  115. Br, Mike (2 June 2010). "On-site versus off-site auctions". Mike Brandly, Auctioneer Blog. Retrieved 26 January 2020.
  116. "Inglis – Australia's Leading Bloodstock Auctioneers – About Us". inglis.com.au. Retrieved 2019-07-16.
  117. d'Arcy, Susan (2010-01-24). "Bag a holiday bargain in an online auction". The Times. London. Archived from the original on May 22, 2010.
  118. Ralph Brody; Marcie Goodman (1988-01-01), Fund-raising events: strategies and programs for success , Human Sciences Press, 1988, ISBN   978-0-89885-362-9
  119. Harold W. Donahue (2005-04-01), The Toastmaster's Manual, Kessinger Publishing, 2005, ISBN   978-1-4191-5636-6
  120. Julia L. Wilkinson (2006), The Ebay Price Guide: What Sells for What, No Starch Press, 2006, ISBN   978-1-59327-055-1
  121. "CryptoKitties explained: Why players have bred over a million blockchain felines". VentureBeat. 6 October 2018. Retrieved 26 November 2020.
  122. "Charity Auctions: The Ultimate Guide". Double the Donation. Retrieved 27 January 2017.
  123. "Lloyd's 2020 Capacity Auction 1 Results, 24 October 2019". Shares Magazine. Archived from the original on 26 January 2020. Retrieved 26 January 2020.
  124. Melikian, Souren (2005-07-26), "Chinese Jar Sets Record for Asian Art", The New York Times, retrieved 2008-06-19
  125. Katehakis, Michael; Puranam, Kartikeya S. (July 2012), "On optimal bidding in sequential procurement auctions", Operations Research Letters, 40 (4): 244–249, doi:10.1016/j.orl.2012.03.012
  126. Katehakis, Michael; Puranam, Kartikeya S. (October 2012), "On bidding for a fixed number of items in a sequence of auctions", European Journal of Operational Research, 222 (1): 76–84, doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2012.03.050
  127. Akerlof, George A. (1970-08-01). "The Market for "Lemons": Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 84 (3): 488–500. doi:10.2307/1879431. JSTOR   1879431. S2CID   6738765.
  128. Milgrom, Paul R.; Weber, Robert J. (1982). "A Theory of Auctions and Competitive Bidding". Econometrica. 50 (5): 1089–1122. doi:10.2307/1911865. hdl: 10419/220807 . ISSN   0012-9682. JSTOR   1911865.
  129. Thaler, Richard H (1988-02-01). "Anomalies: The Winner's Curse". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 2 (1): 191–202. doi: 10.1257/jep.2.1.191 . ISSN   0895-3309.
  130. Zeithammer, Robert (2007). "Research Note—Strategic Bid-Shading and Sequential Auctioning with Learning from Past Prices". Management Science. 53 (9): iv-1519. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1070.0691.
  131. Gonul, Fusun; Leszczyc, Peter (2011). "Snipe bidding behaviour in eBay auctions". International Journal of Electronic Marketing and Retailing. 4: 16–29. doi:10.1504/IJEMR.2011.039894.
  132. Malmendier, Ulrike; Lee, Young Han (2011). "The Bidder's Curse" (PDF). The American Economic Review. 101 (2): 749–787. doi:10.1257/aer.101.2.749. JSTOR   29783689.
  133. Beckmann, Michael (May 2004). "Art Auctions and Bidding Rings: Empirical Evidence from German Auction Data". Journal of Cultural Economics. 28 (2): 125–141. doi:10.1023/B:JCEC.0000019483.38761.63. S2CID   154343127.
  134. Marshall, Robert C.; Marx, Leslie M. (March 2007). "Bidder collusion". Journal of Economic Theory. 133 (1): 374–402. doi:10.1016/j.jet.2005.12.004.
  135. Porter, Robert H.; Zona, J. Douglas (1993-06-01). "Detection of Bid Rigging in Procurement Auctions". Journal of Political Economy. 101 (3): 518–538. doi:10.1086/261885. ISSN   0022-3808. S2CID   153700986 . Retrieved 22 May 2021.
  136. "Changes in the law make auction rings easier to prosecute, but is the regulatory framework still fit for purpose?". Art@Law. 26 February 2014. Retrieved 11 October 2020.
  137. Bajari, Patrick; Yeo, Jungwon (1 June 2009). "Auction design and tacit collusion in FCC spectrum auctions" (PDF). Information Economics and Policy. 21 (2): 90–100. doi:10.1016/j.infoecopol.2009.04.001. ISSN   0167-6245.
  138. Grant, Daniel (4 September 2007). "Legislators Seek to Stop 'Chandelier Bidding' at Auction". ArtNews. Retrieved 27 January 2017.
  139. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Andrew M. Goldstein. "A Beginner's Guide to Art Auctions", artspace.com, 8 November 2012. Retrieved 8 December 2016.
  140. "What is bidding off the wall? | UK Property Auctions". Ukauctions.org.uk. Archived from the original on 2012-02-22. Retrieved 2012-12-26.
  141. "Auction Alliance to probe claims". www.iol.co.za. Retrieved 13 March 2021.
  142. "Billionaire loses legal battle against High Street Auctions over phantom bidders – eProperty News". eProperty News. Retrieved 13 March 2021.
  143. Ma, Mingfan; Gao, Jun; Lu, Ning; Shi, Wenbo (2016). "A Privacy-Preserving Online Reverse Multi-attributes Auction Scheme Based on Degree-Matching". Cloud Computing and Security. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. Vol. 10039. Springer International Publishing. pp. 432–442. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-48671-0_38. ISBN   978-3-319-48670-3.
  144. "Glossary of Auction Terms". GAUK Auctions. 23 May 2018.
  145. "Wine Valuation, Price Guides, Auction results Australia". Wickman's Fine Wine Auctions.
  146. Adam, M.T.P.; Krämer, J.; Jähnig, C.; Seifert, S.; Weinhardt, C. (2011). "Understanding auction fever: A framework for emotional bidding". Electronic Markets . 21 (3): 197–207. doi:10.1007/s12525-011-0068-9. S2CID   11716244.
  147. Adam, M.T.P.; Krämer, J.; Müller, M. (2015). "Auction fever! How time pressure and social competition affect bidders arousal and bids in retail auctions". Journal of Retailing . 91 (3): 468–485. doi:10.1016/j.jretai.2015.01.003.
  148. Hammami, Farouk; Rekik, Monia; Coelho, Leandro C. (2019). "Exact and heuristic solution approaches for the bid construction problem in transportation procurement auctions with a heterogeneous fleet". Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review. 127: 150–177. Bibcode:2019TRPE..127..150H. doi:10.1016/j.tre.2019.05.009. S2CID   182223089.
  149. Song, Jiongjiong; Regan, Amelia (2005). "Approximation algorithms for the bid construction problem in combinatorial auctions for the procurement of freight transportation contracts". Transportation Research Part B: Methodological. 39 (10): 914–933. Bibcode:2005TRPB...39..914S. doi:10.1016/j.trb.2004.11.003. S2CID   17566972.
  150. Journal of Economic Literature Classification System, American Economic Association, archived from the original on 2009-01-06, retrieved 2008-06-25 (D: Microeconomics, D4: Market Structure and Pricing, D44: Auctions)

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Dutch auction</span> Type of auction which begins with a high asking price, and lowers it

A Dutch auction is one of several similar types of auctions for buying or selling goods. Most commonly, it means an auction in which the auctioneer begins with a high asking price in the case of selling, and lowers it until some participant accepts the price, or it reaches a predetermined reserve price. This type of price auction is most commonly used for goods that are required to be sold quickly such as flowers, fresh produce, or tobacco. A Dutch auction has also been called a clock auction or open-outcry descending-price auction. This type of auction shows the advantage of speed since a sale never requires more than one bid. It is strategically similar to a first-price sealed-bid auction.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Online auction</span> Auction held over the internet

An online auction is an auction held over the internet and accessed by internet connected devices. Similar to in-person auctions, online auctions come in a variety of types, with different bidding and selling rules.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Vickrey auction</span> Auction priced by second-highest sealed bid

A Vickrey auction or sealed-bid second-price auction (SBSPA) is a type of sealed-bid auction. Bidders submit written bids without knowing the bid of the other people in the auction. The highest bidder wins but the price paid is the second-highest bid. This type of auction is strategically similar to an English auction and gives bidders an incentive to bid their true value. The auction was first described academically by Columbia University professor William Vickrey in 1961 though it had been used by stamp collectors since 1893. In 1797 Johann Wolfgang von Goethe sold a manuscript using a sealed-bid, second-price auction.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">English auction</span> Type of dynamic auction

An English auction is an open-outcry ascending dynamic auction. It proceeds as follows.

A bid price is the highest price that a buyer is willing to pay for some goods. It is usually referred to simply as the "bid". In bid and ask, the bid price stands in contrast to the ask price or "offer", and the difference between the two is called the bid–ask spread. An unsolicited bid or purchase offer is when a person or company receives a bid even though they are not looking to sell.

In economics, a reservationprice is a limit on the price of a good or a service. On the demand side, it is the highest price that a buyer is willing to pay; on the supply side, it is the lowest price a seller is willing to accept for a good or service.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Japanese auction</span>

A Japanese auction is a dynamic auction format. It proceeds in the following way.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Bidding fee auction</span>

A bidding fee auction, also called a penny auction, is a type of all-pay auction in which all participants must pay a non-refundable fee to place each small incremental bid. The auction is extended each time a new bid is placed, typically by 10 to 20 seconds. Once time expires without a new bid being placed, the last bidder wins the auction and pays the amount of that bid. The auctioneer profits from both the fees charged to place bids and the payment for the winning bid; these combined revenues frequently total more than the value of the item being sold. Empirical evidence suggests that revenues from these auctions exceeds theoretical predictions for rational agents. This has been credited to the sunk cost fallacy. Such auctions are typically held over the Internet, rather than in person.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Auction sniping</span> Bidding at the last moment as an auction strategy

Auction sniping is the practice, in a timed online auction, of placing a bid likely to exceed the current highest bid as late as possible—usually seconds before the end of the auction—giving other bidders no time to outbid the sniper. This can be done either manually or by software on the bidder's computer, or by an online sniping service.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Double auction</span> Process of buying and selling goods

A double auction is a process of buying and selling goods with multiple sellers and multiple buyers. Potential buyers submit their bids and potential sellers submit their ask prices to the market institution, and then the market institution chooses some price p that clears the market: all the sellers who asked less than p sell and all buyers who bid more than p buy at this price p. Buyers and sellers that bid or ask for exactly p are also included. A common example of a double auction is stock exchange.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Auction theory</span> Branch of applied economics regarding the behavior of bidders in auctions

Auction theory is a branch of applied economics that deals with how bidders act in auctions and researches how the features of auctions incentivise predictable outcomes. Auction theory is a tool used to inform the design of real-world auctions. Sellers use auction theory to raise higher revenues while allowing buyers to procure at a lower cost. The confluence of the price between the buyer and seller is an economic equilibrium. Auction theorists design rules for auctions to address issues that can lead to market failure. The design of these rulesets encourages optimal bidding strategies in a variety of informational settings. The 2020 Nobel Prize for Economics was awarded to Paul R. Milgrom and Robert B. Wilson "for improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats."

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Multiunit auction</span>

A multiunit auction is an auction in which several homogeneous items are sold. The units can be sold each at the same price or at different prices.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">First-price sealed-bid auction</span> Auction where all participants concurrently submit undisclosed bids

A first-price sealed-bid auction (FPSBA) is a common type of auction. It is also known as blind auction. In this type of auction, all bidders simultaneously submit sealed bids so that no bidder knows the bid of any other participant. The highest bidder pays the price that was submitted.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Bidding</span> Method of competitive price determination used in auctions, stock exchanges, etc.

Bidding is an offer to set a price tag by an individual or business for a product or service or a demand that something be done. Bidding is used to determine the cost or value of something.

Barry v Davies [2000] EWCA Civ 235, [2000] 1 WLR 1962 is an English contract law case which established and confirmed that auction goods being sold without a reserve must be sold to a genuine highest bidder. The principle is subject to exceptions based on illegality, such as illicit goods, a seller without the right to sell the goods, or a buyer without the money or right to buy the goods.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Reverse auction</span> Auction with one buyer and many potential sellers

A reverse auction is a type of auction in which the traditional roles of buyer and seller are reversed. Thus, there is one buyer and many potential sellers. In an ordinary auction also known as a forward auction, buyers compete to obtain goods or services by offering increasingly higher prices. In contrast, in a reverse auction, the sellers compete to obtain business from the buyer and prices will typically decrease as the sellers underbid each other.

PropertyRoom.com is a live online auction website that sells confiscated police goods and approved third party merchant merchandise to the highest winning bidder. PropertyRoom.com is the largest online police auction website in the United States.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Art market</span>

The art market is the marketplace of buyers and sellers trading in commodities, services, and works of art.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Government auction</span> Auction held for state-owned or state-sold property

A government auction or a public auction is an auction held on behalf of a government in which the property to be auctioned is either property owned by the government or property which is sold under the authority of a court of law or a government agency with similar authority.

A sequential auction is an auction in which several items are sold, one after the other, to the same group of potential buyers. In a sequential first-price auction (SAFP), each individual item is sold using a first price auction, while in a sequential second-price auction (SASP), each individual item is sold using a second price auction.

References

Further reading