Electricity market

Last updated

An electricity market is a system that enables the exchange of electrical energy, through an electrical grid. [1] Historically, electricity has been primarily sold by companies that operate electric generators, and purchased by consumers or electricity retailers.

Contents

The electric power industry began in the late 19th century in the United States and United Kingdom. Throughout the 20th century, and up to the present, there have been deep changes in the economic management of electricity. Changes have occurred across different regions and countries, for many reasons, ranging from technological advances (on supply and demand sides) to politics and ideology.

Around the turn of the 21st century, several countries restructured their electric power industries, replacing the vertically integrated and tightly regulated "traditional" electricity market with market mechanisms for electricity generation, transmission, distribution, and retailing. [2] The traditional and competitive market approaches loosely correspond to two visions of industry: the deregulation was transforming electricity from a public service (like sewerage) into a tradable good (like crude oil). [3] As of 2020s, the traditional markets are still common in some regions, including large parts of the United States and Canada. [4]

In recent years, governments have reformed electricity markets to improve management of variable renewable energy and reduce greenhouse gas emissions. [5] [6]

Services

The structure of an electricity market is quite complex. [7] Markets often include mechanisms to manage a variety of relevant services alongside energy. Services may include:

A simple "energy-only" wholesale electricity market would only facilitate the sale of energy, without regard for other services that may support the system, and experienced problems once implemented alone. To account for this, the electricity market structure typically includes: [7]

The competitive retail electricity markets were able to maintain their simple structure. [7]

In addition, for most major operators, there are markets for transmission rights [ citation needed ] and electricity derivatives such as electricity futures and options, which are actively traded.

The market externality of greenhouse gas emissions is sometimes dealt with by carbon pricing. [11]

Economic theory

Electricity market is characterized by unique features [12] that are atypical in the markets for commodities or consumption goods.

Although few somewhat similar markets exist (for example, airplane tickets and hotel rooms, like electricity, cannot be stored and the demand for them varies by season), [13] the magnitude of peak pricing (peak price can be 100 times higher than an off-peak one) sets the electricity market apart (the summer price for a beachfront hotel room can be 3–4 times higher than the off-season one), [14] the hotel/airline markets can also use retail price discrimination, unavailable in the wholesale electricity market. [15] The peculiarities of the electricity market make it fundamentally incomplete. [16]

Generation

Electricity is typically available on demand. [17] In order to achieve this, the supply must match the demand very closely at any time despite the continuous variations of both (so called grid balancing). Frequently, the only safety margins are the ones provided by the kinetic energy of the physically rotating machinery (synchronous generators and turbines). If there is a mismatch between supply and demand the generators absorb extra energy by speeding up or produce more power by slowing down causing the utility frequency (either 50 or 60 hertz) to increase or decrease. However, the frequency cannot deviate too much from the target: many units of the electrical equipment can be destroyed by the out-of-bounds frequency and thus will automatically disconnect from the grid to protect themselves, potentially triggering a blackout. [17]

There are many other physical and economic constraints affecting the electricity network and the market, with some creating non-convexity: [18]

Networks

Electricity networks are natural monopolies, because it is not feasible to build multiple networks competing against one another. In order to address this, many electricity networks are regulated to address the risk of price gouging. The two main types of network price regulation are: [19]

The design of transmission network limits the amount of electricity that can be transmitted from one tighly-coupled area ("node") to another, so a generator in one node might be unable to service a load in another node (due to "transmission congestion"), potentially creating fragments of the market that have to be served with local generation ("load pockets").

History

Traditional industries

After its first few years of existence, the electricity supply industry was regulated by the various levels of government. By the 1950s, a wide variety of arrangements had evolved with substantial differences between countries and even at the regional level, for example: [20]

These diverse structures had a few unifying features: very little reliance on competitive markets, [21] no formal wholesale markets, and customers unable to choose their suppliers. [22]

The diversity and sheer size of the US market made the potential trade gains large enough to justify some wholesale transactions: [23]

On the retail side, customers were charged fixed regulated prices that did not change with marginal costs, retail tariffs almost entirely relied on volumetric pricing (based on the meter readings recorded monthly), and fixed cost recovery was included into the per-kWh price. [23]

The traditional market arrangement was designed for the state of the electric industry common pre-restructuring (and still common in some regions, including large parts of the US and Canada [4] ). Richard L. Schmalensee calls this state historical (as opposed to post-restructuring emerging one). In the historical regime almost all generation sources can be considered dispatchable (available on demand, unlike the emerging variable renewable energy). [21]

Evolution of deregulated markets

Chile had become a pioneer in deregulation in the early 1980s (the law of 1982 had codified the changes that were started in 1979). [24] Only few years later the new market approach to electricity was formulated in the US, [24] popularized in the influential work by Joskow and Schmalensee, [25] "Markets for Power: An Analysis of Electrical Utility Deregulation" (1983). [26] At the same time in the UK, Energy Act of 1983 made provisions for common carriage in the electricity networks, enabling a choice of supplier for electricity boards and very large customers (analogous to "wheeling" in the US). [27]

The incorporation of distributed energy resources (DERs) has inspired innovative electricity markets that emerge from a hierarchical deregulated market structure, such as local flexibility markets, with upstream aggregating entities representing multiple DERs (e.g., aggregators). Flexibility Markets refer to the markets in which Distribution System Operators (DSOs) procure services from assets linked to their distribution system, aiming to guarantee the operational safety of the distribution network. This concept is relatively new, and its design is currently a subject of active research. [28] In this sense, different entities can act as aggregators, e.g. demand response aggregators, community managers, electricity service providers, and more, depending on the characteristics of the set of assets being represented. [29]

Wholesale electricity market

A wholesale electricity market, also power exchange or PX, (or energy exchange especially if they also trade gas) is a system enabling purchases, through bids to buy; sales, through offers to sell. Bids and offers use supply and demand principles to set the price. Long-term contracts are similar to power purchase agreements and generally considered private bi-lateral transactions between counterparties.

A wholesale electricity market exists when competing generators offer their electricity output to retailers. The retailers then re-price the electricity and take it to market. While wholesale pricing used to be the exclusive domain of large retail suppliers, increasingly markets like New England are beginning to open up to end-users. Large end-users seeking to cut out unnecessary overhead in their energy costs are beginning to recognize the advantages inherent in such a purchasing move. Consumers buying electricity directly from generators is a relatively recent phenomenon.

Buying wholesale electricity is not without its drawbacks (market uncertainty, membership costs, set up fees, collateral investment, and organization costs, as electricity would need to be bought on a daily basis), however, the larger the end user's electrical load, the greater the benefit and incentive to make the switch.

For an economically efficient electricity wholesale market to flourish it is essential that a number of criteria are met, namely the existence of a coordinated spot market that has "bid-based, security-constrained, economic dispatch with nodal prices". These criteria have been largely adopted in the US, Australia, New Zealand and Singapore. [30]

Markets for power-related commodities required and managed by (and paid for by) market operators to ensure reliability, are considered ancillary services and include such names as spinning reserve, non-spinning reserve, operating reserves, responsive reserve, regulation up, regulation down, and installed capacity.

Market clearing

Wholesale transactions (bids and offers) in electricity are typically cleared and settled by the market operator or a special-purpose independent entity charged exclusively with that function. Market operators may or may not clear trades, but often require knowledge of the trade to maintain generation and load balance.[ citation needed ]

Markets for electricity trade net generation output for a number of intervals usually in increments of 5, 15 and 60 minutes.[ citation needed ]

Two types of auction can be used to determine which producers are dispatched:

To determine payments, the clearing can use one of two arrangements: [33]

In PAB, strategic bidding can lead producers to bid much higher than their true cost, because they will be dispatched as long as their bid is below the clearing price.

In the absence of collusion, it is expected that MPS incentivizes producers to bid close to their short run marginal cost to avoid the risk of missing out altogether. MPS is also more transparent, as the new bidder already knows the market price and can estimate the profitability with his marginal cost, to do well with the PAB, the bidder needs information about other bids, too. [33] Due to higher risks of the PAB, it gives an extra advantage to the large players that are better equipped to estimate the market and take the risk (for example, by gambling with a high bid for some of their units). However, MPS results in producers being paid more than their bidding prices by design, leading to calls to replace it with PAB despite the incentive for strategic bidding. [34]

Centralized and decentralized markets

To handle all the constraints while keeping the system in balance, a central agency, the transmission system operator (TSO), is required to coordinate the unit commitment and economic dispatch. [36] If the frequency falls outside a predetermined range the system operator will act to add or remove either generation or load.

Unlike the real-time decisions that are necessarily centralized, the electricity market itself can be centralized or decentralized. In the centralized market the TSO decides which plant should run and how much is it supposed to produce way before the delivery (during the "spot market" phase, or day-ahead operation). In a decentralized market the producer only commits to the delivery of electricity, but the means to do that are left to the producer itself (for example, it can enter the agreement with another producer to provide the actual energy). Centralized markets make it easier to accommodate non-convexities, while the decentralized allow intra-day trading to correct the possibly suboptimal decisions made day-ahead, for example, accommodating improved weather forecasts for renewables. [36] Due to the difference in the grid construction (US had weaker transmission networks), the design of wholesale markets in the US and Europe had diverged, even though initially the US was followed the European (decentralized) example. [37]

To accommodate the transmission network constraints centralized markets typically use locational marginal pricing (LMP) where each node has its own local market price (thus another name for the practice, nodal pricing). Political considerations sometimes make it unpalatable to force consumers in the same territory, but connected to different nodes, to pay different prices for electricity, so a modified generator nodal pricing (GNP) model is used: the generators are still being paid the nodal prices, while the load serving entities are charging the end users prices that are averaged over the territory. Many decentralized markets do not use the LMP and have a price established over a geographic area ("zone", thus the name zonal pricing) or a "region" (regional pricing, the term is used primarily for very large zones of the National Electricity Market of Australia, where five regions cover the continent). [38]

In the beginning of 2020s there was no clear preference for any of the two market designs, for example, the North American markets went through centralization, while the European ones moved in the opposite direction: [38]

Wholesale markets
Day-ahead marketNodal pricing
US markets
PJM CentralizedYes
Texas (ERCOT)Centralized (since 2010)Yes (GNP)
Midwest ISO (MISO)CentralizedYes
California (CAISO)CentralizedYes
ISO New England CentralizedYes (GNP)
Other markets
Nord Pool DecentralizedNo (zonal)
Great BritainDecentralized (since 2001)No
GermanyDecentralizedNo (zonal)
IrelandDecentralized (since 2018)No (zonal)
SpainSemi-decentralizedNo (zonal)
ItalySemi-decentralizedNo (zonal)
NEM, Australia DecentralizedNo (regional)
New ZealandDecentralizedYes
ChileCost-basedYes

Centralized market

A transmission system operator in a centralized electricity market obtains the cost information (usually three components: start-up costs, no-load costs, marginal production costs [39] ) for each unit of generation ("unit-based bidding") and makes all the decisions in the day-ahead and real-time (system redispatch) markets. This approach allows the operator to take into consideration the details of the configuration of the transmission system. The centralized market normally uses the LMP, and the dispatch goal is minimizing the total cost in each node[ clarification needed ] (which in a large network count in hundreds or even thousands). The centralized markets use some procedures resembling the vertically integrated electric utilities of the era before the deregulation, so the centralized markets are also called integrated electricity markets. [38]

Due to the centralized and detailed nature of the day-ahead dispatch, it stays feasible and cost-efficient at the time of delivery, unless some unexpected adverse events occur. Early decisions help to efficiently schedule the plants with the long ramp-up times. [38]

The drawbacks of the centralized design with LMP are: [40]

Price of a unit of electricity with LMP is based on the marginal cost, so the start-up and no-load costs are not included. Centralized markets therefore typically pay a compensation for these costs to the producer (so called make-whole or uplift payments), financed in some way by the market participants (and, ultimately, the consumers). [38]

Inflexibility of the centralized market manifests itself in two ways: [41]

Market clearing algorithms are complex (some are NP-complete) and have to be executed in limited time (5–60 minutes). The results are thus not necessarily optimal, are hard to replicate independently, and require the market participants to trust the operator (due to the complexity sometimes a decision by the algorithm to accept or reject the bid appears entirely arbitrary to the bidder). [41]

If the transmission system operator owns the actual transmission network, it would be incentivized to profit by increasing the congestion rents. Thus in the US the operator typically does not own any capacity and is frequently called an independent system operator (ISO). [41]

Cost-based market

The higher degree of centralization of the market involves the direct cost calculations by the market operator (producers no longer submit bids). Despite the obvious problem with generation companies incentivized to inflate their costs (this can be hidden through transactions with affiliated companies), this cost-based electricity market arrangement eliminates the market power of the providers and is used in situation when an abuse of market power is possible (e. g., Chile with its preponderance of hydro power, in the US when the local market power is sufficiently high, some European markets[ which? ]). A less-obvious issue is the tendency of market participants under these conditions to concentrate on investments in the peaker plants to the detriment of the baseload power. [41] One of the advantages of the cost-based market is the relatively low cost to set it up. [42] The cost-based approach is popular in Latin America: in addition to Chile, it is used in Bolivia, Peru, Brazil, and countries in Central America. [43]

A system operator performs an audit of parameters of each generator unit (including heat rate, minimum load, ramping speed, etc.) and estimates the direct marginal costs of its operation. Based on this information, an hour-by-hour dispatch schedule is put in place to minimize the total direct cost. In the process, the hourly shadow prices are obtained for each node that might be used to settle the market sales. [43]

Decentralized market

Decentralized markets allow the generation companies to choose their own way to provide energy for their day-ahead bid (that specifies price and location). The provider can use any unit at its disposal (so called "portfolio-based bidding") or even pay another company to deliver the energy. The market still has the central operator that exclusively controls the system in real-time, but with significantly diminished powers to intervene ahead of delivery (frequently just the ability to schedule the transmission network for day-ahead operation). This arrangement makes operator's ownership of the transmission capacity less of an issue, and European countries, with the exception of UK, permit it (following the independent transmission system operator or ITSO model). [42]

While some operators in Europe are involved in structuring the day-ahead and intra-day markets, the other ones are not. For example, the UK market after the New Electricity Trading Arrangements in UK and the market in New Zealand let the markets sort out all the frictions before real-time. This reliance on financial instruments leads to the additional names for the decentralized markets: exchange-based, unbundled, bilateral. [42]

Bid-based, security-constrained, economic dispatch with nodal prices

The system price in the day-ahead market is, in principle, determined by matching offers from generators to bids from consumers at each node to develop a classic supply and demand equilibrium price, usually on an hourly interval, and is calculated separately for subregions in which the system operator's load flow model indicates that constraints will bind transmission imports.

The theoretical prices of electricity at each node on the network is a calculated "shadow price", in which it is assumed that one additional kilowatt-hour is demanded at the node in question, and the hypothetical incremental cost to the system that would result from the optimized redispatch of available units establishes the hypothetical production cost of the hypothetical kilowatt-hour. This is known as locational marginal pricing (LMP) or nodal pricing and is used in some deregulated markets, most notably in the Midcontinent Independent System Operator (MISO), PJM Interconnection, ERCOT, New York, and ISO New England markets in the United States, [44] New Zealand, [45] and in Singapore. [46]

In practice, the LMP algorithm described above is run, incorporating a security-constrained (defined below), least-cost dispatch calculation with supply based on the generators that submitted offers in the day-ahead market, and demand based on bids from load-serving entities draining supplies at the nodes in question.

Due to various non-convexities present in wholesale electricity markets, in the form of economies of scale, start-up and/or shut-down costs, avoidable costs, indivisibilities, minimum supply requirements, etc., some suppliers may incur losses under LMP, e.g., because they may fail to recover their fixed cost through commodity payments only. To address this problem, various pricing schemes that lift the price above marginal cost and/or provide side-payments (uplifts) have been proposed. Liberopoulos and Andrianesis (2016) [47] review and compare several of these schemes on the price, uplifts, and profits that each scheme generates.

While in theory the LMP concepts are useful and not evidently subject to manipulation, in practice system operators have substantial discretion over LMP results through the ability to classify units as running in "out-of-merit dispatch", which are thereby excluded from the LMP calculation. In most systems, units that are dispatched to provide reactive power to support transmission grids are declared to be "out-of-merit" (even though these are typically the same units that are located in constrained areas and would otherwise result in scarcity signals). System operators also normally bring units online to hold as "spinning-reserve" to protect against sudden outages or unexpectedly rapid ramps in demand, and declare them "out-of-merit". The result is often a substantial reduction in clearing price at a time when increasing demand would otherwise result in escalating prices.

Researchers have noted that a variety of factors, including energy price caps set well below the putative scarcity value of energy, the effect of "out-of-merit" dispatch, the use of techniques such as voltage reductions during scarcity periods with no corresponding scarcity price signal, etc., results in a missing money problem. The consequence is that prices paid to suppliers in the "market" are substantially below the levels required to stimulate new entry. The markets have therefore been useful in bringing efficiencies to short-term system operations and dispatch, but have been a failure in what was advertised as a principal benefit: stimulating suitable new investment where it is needed, when it is needed.[ citation needed ]

In LMP markets, where constraints exist on a transmission network, there is a need for more expensive generation to be dispatched on the downstream side of the constraint. Prices on either side of the constraint separate giving rise to congestion pricing and constraint rentals.

A constraint can be caused when a particular branch of a network reaches its thermal limit or when a potential overload will occur due to a contingent event (e.g., failure of a generator or transformer or a line outage) on another part of the network. The latter is referred to as a security constraint. Transmission systems are operated to allow for continuity of supply even if a contingent event, like the loss of a line, were to occur. This is known as a security constrained system.

In most systems the algorithm used is a "DC" model rather than an "AC" model, so constraints and redispatch resulting from thermal limits are identified/predicted, but constraints and redispatch resulting from reactive power deficiencies are not.[ citation needed ] Some systems take marginal losses into account. The prices in the real-time market are determined by the LMP algorithm described above, balancing supply from available units. [48] This process is carried out for each 5-minute, half-hour or hour (depending on the market) interval at each node on the transmission grid. The hypothetical redispatch calculation that determines the LMP must respect security constraints and the redispatch calculation must leave sufficient margin to maintain system stability in the event of an unplanned outage anywhere on the system. This results in a spot market with "bid-based, security-constrained, economic dispatch with nodal prices".

Many established markets do not employ nodal pricing, examples being the UK, EPEX SPOT (most European countries), and Nord Pool Spot (Nordic and Baltic countries).

Risk management

Financial risk management is often a high priority for participants in deregulated electricity markets due to the substantial price and volume risks that the markets can exhibit. A consequence of the complexity of a wholesale electricity market can be extremely high price volatility at times of peak demand and supply shortages. The particular characteristics of this price risk are highly dependent on the physical fundamentals of the market such as the mix of types of generation plant and relationship between demand and weather patterns. Price risk can be manifest by price "spikes" which are hard to predict and price "steps" when the underlying fuel or plant position changes for long periods.

Volume risk is often used to denote the phenomenon whereby electricity market participants have uncertain volumes or quantities of consumption or production. For example, a retailer is unable to accurately predict consumer demand for any particular hour more than a few days into the future and a producer is unable to predict the precise time that they will have plant outage or shortages of fuel. A compounding factor is also the common correlation between extreme price and volume events. For example, price spikes frequently occur when some producers have plant outages or when some consumers are in a period of peak consumption. The introduction of substantial amounts of intermittent power sources such as wind energy may affect market prices.

Electricity retailers, who in aggregate buy from the wholesale market, and generators who in aggregate sell to the wholesale market, are exposed to these price and volume effects and to protect themselves from volatility, they will enter into "hedge contracts" with each other. The structure of these contracts varies by regional market due to different conventions and market structures. However, the two simplest and most common forms are simple fixed price forward contracts for physical delivery and contracts for differences where the parties agree a strike price for defined time periods. In the case of a contract for difference, if a resulting wholesale price index (as referenced in the contract) in any time period is higher than the "strike" price, the generator will refund the difference between the "strike" price and the actual price for that period. Similarly a retailer will refund the difference to the generator when the actual price is less than the "strike price". The actual price index is sometimes referred to as the "spot" or "pool" price, depending on the market.

Many other hedging arrangements, such as swing contracts,[ clarification needed ] virtual bidding, financial transmission rights,[ clarification needed ] call options and put options are traded in sophisticated electricity markets. In general they are designed to transfer financial risks between participants.

Price capping and cross subsidy

Due to high gas prices because of the 2022 Russia–European Union gas dispute, in late 2022 the EU capped non-gas power prices at 180 euros per megawatt hour [49] and the UK is considering price capping. [50] Fossil fuels, especially gas, may be price capped higher than renewables, with revenue above the cap subsidizing some consumers, as in Turkey.[ citation needed ] Academic study of an earlier price cap in that market concluded that it reduced welfare, [51] and another study said that an EU-wide price cap would risk "a never-ending spiral of higher import prices and higher subsidies". [52] It has been academically argued via game theory that a cap on the price of imported Russian gas (some of which is used to generate electricity) could be beneficial, [53] however politically this is difficult. [54]

Wholesale electricity markets

Electric power exchanges

An electric power exchange is a commodities exchange dealing with electric power:

International trading

Electricity itself, or products made with a lot of electricity, exported to another country may be charged a carbon tariff if the exporting country has no carbon price: for example as the UK has the UK ETS it would not be charged the EU Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism whereas Turkey has no carbon price so might be charged. [83]

Possible future changes

Rather than the traditional merit order based on cost, when there is excess generation ramping down the plants which most damage health has been suggested. [84] Due to the growth of renewables and the 2021–2022 global energy crisis some countries are considering changing their electricity markets. [85] [86] [87] For example, some Europeans suggest decoupling electricity prices from natural gas prices. [88]

Retail electricity market

A retail electricity market exists when end-use customers can choose their supplier from competing electricity retailers; one term used in the United States for this type of consumer choice is 'energy choice'. A separate issue for electricity markets is whether or not consumers face real-time pricing (prices based on the variable wholesale price) or a price that is set in some other way, such as average annual costs. In many markets, consumers do not pay based on the real-time price, and hence have no incentive to reduce demand at times of high (wholesale) prices or to shift their demand to other periods. Demand response may use pricing mechanisms or technical solutions to reduce peak demand.

Generally, electricity retail reform follows from electricity wholesale reform. However, it is possible to have a single electricity generation company and still have retail competition. If a wholesale price can be established at a node on the transmission grid and the electricity quantities at that node can be reconciled, competition for retail customers within the distribution system beyond the node is possible. In the German market, for example, large, vertically integrated utilities compete with one another for customers on a more or less open grid.

Although market structures vary, there are some common functions that an electricity retailer has to be able to perform, or enter into a contract for, to compete effectively. Failure or incompetence in the execution of one or more of the following has led to some dramatic financial disasters:

The two main areas of weakness have been risk management and billing. In the United States in 2001, California's flawed regulation of retail competition led to the California electricity crisis and left incumbent retailers subject to high spot prices but without the ability to hedge against these. [89] In the UK a retailer, Independent Energy, with a large customer base went bust when it could not collect the money due from customers. [90]

Competitive retail needs open access to distribution and transmission wires. This in turn requires that prices must be set for both these services. They must also provide appropriate returns to the owners of the wires and encourage efficient location of power plants. There are two types of fees, the access fee and the regular fee. The access fee covers the cost of having and accessing the network of wires available, or the right to use the existing transmission and distribution network. The regular fee reflects the marginal cost of transferring electricity through the existing network of wires.

New technology is available and has been piloted by the US Department of Energy that may be better suited to real-time market pricing. A potential use of event-driven SOA (service-oriented architecture) could be a virtual electricity market where home clothes dryers can bid on the price of the electricity they use in a real-time market pricing system. [91] The real-time market price and control system could turn home electricity customers into active participants in managing the power grid and their monthly utility bills. [92] Customers can set limits on how much they would pay for electricity to run a clothes dryer, for example, and electricity providers willing to transmit power at that price would be alerted over the grid and could sell the electricity to the dryer. [93]

On one side, consumer devices can bid for power based on how much the owner of the device were willing to pay, set ahead of time by the consumer. [94] On the other side, suppliers can enter bids automatically from their electricity generators, based on how much it would cost to start up and run the generators. Further, the electricity suppliers could perform real-time market analysis to determine return-on-investment for optimizing profitability or reducing end-user cost of goods. The effects of a competitive retail electricity market are mixed across states, but generally appear to lower prices in states with high participation and raise prices in states that have little customer participation. [95]

Event-driven SOA software could allow homeowners to customize many different types of electricity devices found within their home to a desired level of comfort or economy. The event-driven software could also automatically respond to changing electricity prices, in as little as five-minute intervals. For example, to reduce the home owner's electricity usage in peak periods (when electricity is most expensive), the software could automatically lower the target temperature of the thermostat on the central heating system (in winter) or raise the target temperature of the thermostat on the central cooling system (in summer).

Deregulated market experience

Comparisons between the traditional and competitive market designs experience have provide mixed results. The US experience where the deregulated utilities operate alongside the vertically integrated ones, there is some evidence of the increased efficiencies: [96]

Schmalensee concludes that it is plausible that the restructuring resulted in lower wholesale prices, at least in the US and the UK. [97] MacKay and Mercadal in a large-scale analysis of the US market between 1994 and 2016, while confirming Schmalensee's findings on lower costs, reached the opposite conclusion on the prices: deregulated utilities realized significantly higher prices due to higher markup of the generation facilities and double extraction of the profit margin by the two vertically separated companies. [98]

Regarding resource adequacy, the US market at the start of restructuring had excess generating capacity, confirming the expectation that regulated prices provide an incentive for the generators to overinvest. Initial hope that the revenue stream would be sufficient to continue building up the capacity did not materialize: faced with abuse of market power, all US markets introduced wholesale price caps that in many case were much lower than the value of lost load thus creating the "missing money problem" (capping revenue at the time of relatively infrequent shortages causes the shortage of money to build the infrastructure that is only used during these shortages); the problem of over-investment was replaced by underinvestment, dragging down the grid reliability. In response, major transfer payments for capacity were instituted (in the US in 2018 the payments were getting as high as 47% of the new unit's revenue). [97] EU markets followed the American lead in the 2010s. Schmalensee notes that while the process of determining the amount of compensation for new capacity in the US is in principle similar to the integrated resource planning of the traditional markets, the new version is less transparent and provides less certainty due to frequent rule changes (the traditional scheme guaranteed the cost recovery), so an efficiency improvement in this area is unlikely. [99]

The introduction of the choice of supplier and variable pricing in the retail market was enthusiastically supported by larger consumers (businesses) that can employ the time of consumption-shifting techniques to benefit from the time-of-use pricing and have access to hedging against very high prices. [99] Acceptance among residential customers in the US was minimal. [100]

Many regional markets have achieved some success, and the ongoing trend continues to be towards deregulation and introduction of competition. However, in 2000/2001 [101] major failures such as the California electricity crisis and the Enron debacle caused a slow down in the pace of change and in some regions an increase in market regulation and reduction in competition. However, this trend is widely regarded as a temporary one against the longer-term trend towards more open and competitive markets. [102]

Notwithstanding the favorable light in which market solutions are viewed conceptually, the "missing money" problem has to date proved intractable.[ citation needed ] If electricity prices were to move to the levels needed to incentivize new merchant (i.e., market-based) transmission and generation, the costs to consumers would be politically difficult.

The increase in annual costs to consumers in New England alone were calculated at $3 billion during the recent[ when? ] FERC hearings on the NEPOOL market structure. Several mechanisms that are intended to incentivize new investment where it is most needed by offering enhanced capacity payments (but only in zones where generation is projected to be short) have been proposed for NEPOOL, PJM and NYPOOL, and go under the generic heading of "locational capacity" or LICAP (the PJM version is called the "Reliability Pricing Model", or "RPM"). [103]

Capacity market

In a deregulated grid some sort of incentives are necessary for market participants to build and maintain generation and transmission resources that may some day be called upon to maintain the grid balance (supporting the "resource adequacy", or RA), but most of the time these resources are idled and do not produce revenue from the sale of electricity. Since "energy-only markets have the potential to result in an equilibrium point for the market that is not consistent with what users and regulators want to see", [104] all existing wholesale electricity markets rely on offer caps in some form. [8] These caps prevent the suppliers from fully recovering their investment into the reserve capacity through the scarcity pricing, creating a missing money problem for generators. [105] To avoid underinvestment into the generation and transmission capacity, all markets employ some kind of RA transfers. [106]

Typical regulator requires a retailer to purchase firm capacity for 110–120% of its annual peak power. The contracts are either bilateral (between the retailers and generator owners), or are traded on a centralized capacity market (the case, e.g., for the eastern USA grid). [106]

Turkey

The capacity mechanism [107] is claimed to be a mechanism for subsiding coal in Turkey, [108] and has been criticised by some economists, as they say it encourages strategic capacity withholding. [109] It was designed to keep gas plants in the system. Unlike many other markets it is a hybrid system based partly on fixed costs and partly on market clearing price. Many say[ weasel words ] it is not good and should be changed, for example by using regional bidding zones because constraint management is the main problem in the market. [110]

United Kingdom

The Capacity Market is a part of the British government's Electricity Market Reform package. [111] According to the Department for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy "the Capacity Market will ensure security of electricity supply by providing a payment for reliable sources of capacity, alongside their electricity revenues, to ensure they deliver energy when needed. This will encourage the investment we need to replace older power stations and provide backup for more intermittent and inflexible low carbon generation sources". [112]

Auctions

Two Capacity Market Auctions are held each year. The T-4 auction buys capacity to be delivered in four years’ time and the T-1 auction is a top-up auction held just ahead of each delivery year. [113] Capacity Market Auction results have been published for several years. [114] [115] [116]

  • 2023, 7.6 GW for delivery in 2024/25, mostly gas and nuclear [117]
  • 2023, 42.8 GW for delivery in 2027/28, mostly gas [118]

Definitions

The National Grid 'Guidance document for Capacity Market participants' provides the following definitions:

  • "CMU (Capacity Market Unit) – this is the Generating Unit(s) or DSR Capacity that is being prequalified and will ultimately provide Capacity should they secure a Capacity Agreement". [119]
  • "A Generating CMU is a generating unit that provides electricity, is capable of being controlled independently from any other generating unit outside the CMU, is measured by 1 or more half hourly meters and has a connection capacity greater than 2MW". [119]
  • "A DSR CMU is a commitment by a person to provide an amount of capacity by a method of Demand Side Response by either reducing the DSR customers import of electricity, as measured by one or more half hourly meters, exporting electricity generated by one or more permitted on site generating units or varying demand for active power in response to changing system frequency". [119]

Frequency control market

Within many electricity markets, there are specialised markets for the provision of frequency control and ancillary services (FCAS). If the electricity system has supply (generation) in excess of electricity demand, at any instant, then the frequency will increase. By contrast, if there is insufficient supply of electricity to meet demand at any time then the system frequency will fall. If it falls too far, the power system will become unstable. Frequency control markets are in addition to, and separate from, the wholesale electricity pool market. These markets serve to incentivise the provision of frequency raise services or frequency lower services. Frequency raise involves rapid provision of extra electricity generation, so that supply and demand can be more closely matched. [120]

See also

Related Research Articles

The New Zealand electricity market (NZEM) is a decentralised electricity market regulated by the Electricity Industry Participation Code administered by the Electricity Authority (EA). The authority was established in November 2010 to replace the Electricity Commission.

Transpower New Zealand Limited (TPNZ) is the state-owned enterprise responsible for electric power transmission in New Zealand. It performs two major functions in the New Zealand electricity market. As the owner of the National Grid it provides the infrastructure of electric power transmission that allows consumers to have access to generation from a wide range of sources, and enables competition in the wholesale electricity market; as system operator it manages the real-time operation of the grid and the physical operation of the electricity market.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">ScottishPower</span> Scottish energy company

Scottish Power Limited, trading as ScottishPower, is a vertically integrated energy company based in Glasgow, Scotland. It is a subsidiary of Spanish utility firm Iberdrola.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">National Grid (Great Britain)</span> High-voltage electric power transmission network in Great Britain

The National Grid is the high-voltage electric power transmission network supporting the UK's electricity market, connecting power stations and major substations, and ensuring that electricity generated anywhere on the grid can be used to satisfy demand elsewhere. The network serves the majority of Great Britain and some of the surrounding islands. It does not cover Northern Ireland, which is part of the Irish single electricity market.

The National Electricity Market (NEM) is an arrangement in Australia's electricity sector for the connection of the electricity transmission grids of the eastern and southern Australia states and territories to create a cross-state wholesale electricity market. The Australian Energy Market Commission develops and maintains the Australian National Electricity Rules (NER), which have the force of law in the states and territories participating in NEM. The Rules are enforced by the Australian Energy Regulator. The day-to-day management of NEM is performed by the Australian Energy Market Operator.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Regional transmission organization (North America)</span> Electric power coordinator

A regional transmission organization (RTO) in the United States is an electric power transmission system operator (TSO) that coordinates, controls, and monitors a multi-state electric grid. The transfer of electricity between states is considered interstate commerce, and electric grids spanning multiple states are therefore regulated by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC). The voluntary creation of RTOs was initiated by FERC in December 1999. The purpose of the RTO is to promote economic efficiency, reliability, and non-discriminatory practices while reducing government oversight.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Demand response</span> Techniques used to prevent power networks from being overwhelmed

Demand response is a change in the power consumption of an electric utility customer to better match the demand for power with the supply. Until the 21st century decrease in the cost of pumped storage and batteries, electric energy could not be easily stored, so utilities have traditionally matched demand and supply by throttling the production rate of their power plants, taking generating units on or off line, or importing power from other utilities. There are limits to what can be achieved on the supply side, because some generating units can take a long time to come up to full power, some units may be very expensive to operate, and demand can at times be greater than the capacity of all the available power plants put together. Demand response, a type of energy demand management, seeks to adjust in real-time the demand for power instead of adjusting the supply.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Transmission system operator</span> Energy transporter

A transmission system operator (TSO) is an entity entrusted with transporting energy in the form of natural gas or electrical power on a national or regional level, using fixed infrastructure. The term is defined by the European Commission. The certification procedure for transmission system operators is listed in Article 10 of the Electricity and Gas Directives of 2009.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Merit order</span> Ranking of available sources of energy

The merit order is a way of ranking available sources of energy, especially electrical generation, based on ascending order of price and sometimes pollution, together with amount of energy that will be generated. In a centralized management scheme, the ranking is such that those with the lowest marginal costs are the first sources to be brought online to meet demand, and the plants with the highest marginal costs are the last to be brought on line. Dispatching power generation in this way, known as economic dispatch, minimizes the cost of production of electricity. Sometimes generating units must be started out of merit order, due to transmission congestion, system reliability or other reasons.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Load management</span> Process of balancing the supply of electricity on a network

Load management, also known as demand-side management (DSM), is the process of balancing the supply of electricity on the network with the electrical load by adjusting or controlling the load rather than the power station output. This can be achieved by direct intervention of the utility in real time, by the use of frequency sensitive relays triggering the circuit breakers, by time clocks, or by using special tariffs to influence consumer behavior. Load management allows utilities to reduce demand for electricity during peak usage times, which can, in turn, reduce costs by eliminating the need for peaking power plants. In addition, some peaking power plants can take more than an hour to bring on-line which makes load management even more critical should a plant go off-line unexpectedly for example. Load management can also help reduce harmful emissions, since peaking plants or backup generators are often dirtier and less efficient than base load power plants. New load-management technologies are constantly under development — both by private industry and public entities.

The electricity sector in New Zealand uses mainly renewable energy, such as hydropower, geothermal power and increasingly wind energy. As of 2021, the country generated 81.2% of its electricity from renewable sources. The strategy of electrification is being pursued to enhance the penetration of renewable energy sources and to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions across all sectors of the economy. In 2021, electricity consumption reached 40 terawatt-hours (TW⋅h), representing a 0.2% increase compared to the consumption levels in 2010.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">ISO New England</span> Oversees the operation of New Englands bulk electric power system

ISO New England Inc. (ISO-NE) is an independent, non-profit regional transmission organization (RTO), headquartered in Holyoke, Massachusetts, serving Connecticut, Maine, Massachusetts, New Hampshire, Rhode Island, and Vermont.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">PJM Interconnection</span> Major electric grid coordinator in northeastern USA

PJM Interconnection LLC (PJM) is a regional transmission organization (RTO) in the United States. It is part of the Eastern Interconnection grid operating an electric transmission system serving all or parts of Delaware, Illinois, Indiana, Kentucky, Maryland, Michigan, New Jersey, North Carolina, Ohio, Pennsylvania, Tennessee, Virginia, West Virginia, and the District of Columbia.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Electrical grid</span> Interconnected network for delivering electricity to consumers

An electrical grid is an interconnected network for electricity delivery from producers to consumers. Electrical grids consist of power stations, electrical substations to step voltage up or down, electric power transmission to carry power over long distances, and finally electric power distribution to customers. In that last step, voltage is stepped down again to the required service voltage. Power stations are typically built close to energy sources and far from densely populated areas. Electrical grids vary in size and can cover whole countries or continents. From small to large there are microgrids, wide area synchronous grids, and super grids. The combined transmission and distribution network is part of electricity delivery, known as the power grid.

Different methods of electricity generation can incur a variety of different costs, which can be divided into three general categories: 1) wholesale costs, or all costs paid by utilities associated with acquiring and distributing electricity to consumers, 2) retail costs paid by consumers, and 3) external costs, or externalities, imposed on society.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Alberta Electric System Operator</span>

The Alberta Electric System Operator (AESO) is the non-profit organization responsible for operating Alberta, Canada's power grid. AESO oversees the planning and operation of the Alberta Interconnected Electric System (AIES) in a "safe, reliable, and economical" manner. It is mandated by provincial legislation to act in the public interest and cannot own any transmission, distribution or generation assets.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Variable renewable energy</span> Class of renewable energy sources

Variable renewable energy (VRE) or intermittent renewable energy sources (IRES) are renewable energy sources that are not dispatchable due to their fluctuating nature, such as wind power and solar power, as opposed to controllable renewable energy sources, such as dammed hydroelectricity or bioenergy, or relatively constant sources, such as geothermal power.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Commission for Regulation of Utilities</span> Republic of Irelands energy and water economic utility regulator

The Commission for Regulation of Utilities, formerly known as the Commission for Energy Regulation, is Ireland's energy and water economic utility regulator.

A load pocket is an area of electric grid that has limited ability to import electricity due to either very high concentration of demand or insufficient transmission capabilities and therefore cannot be entirely provided with power without participation of local electricity generation providers. A typical load pocket includes a major city. Load pocket's existence usually indicates difficulties with building of either new generation or new transmission, or both due to the area constraints or political pressure and despite the pocket being an attractive place for investment. The load pockets represent a problem for the deregulated electricity markets, as in the absence of regulation the captive customers are forced to accept the prices set by the local providers.

In power engineering, transmission congestion occurs when overloaded transmission lines in an electrical grid are unable to carry additional electricity flow due to the risk of overheating. During grid congestion, the transmission system operator (TSO) has to direct the providers to adjust their dispatch levels to accommodate the constraint. In an electricity market a power plant may be able to produce electricity at a competitive price but cannot transmit the power to a willing buyer. Congestion increases the electricity prices for some customers.

References

  1. Tsaousoglou, Giraldo & Paterakis 2022, p. 3.
  2. Glachant, Joskow & Pollitt 2021, p. 1.
  3. Wollmann et al. 2010, p. 168.
  4. 1 2 Glachant, Joskow & Pollitt 2021, p. 2.
  5. Cunningham, Thomas (15 February 2017). "Energiewende: From Germany's past to Europe's future?". Atlantic Council. Retrieved 9 April 2024.
  6. Axup, Kate (27 September 2023). "Regulatory reform for the energy transition". Allens. Retrieved 9 April 2024.
  7. 1 2 3 4 5 Schmalensee 2021, p. 18.
  8. 1 2 Wolak 2021a, p. 6.
  9. Munoz et al. 2017, p. 51.
  10. Gilbert & Tobin (29 June 2021). "The Energy Regulation and Markets Review - 2021 Edition". Gilbert & Tobin. Retrieved 7 September 2024.
  11. "Carbon Pricing 201: Pricing Carbon in the Electricity Sector". Resources for the Future. Retrieved 10 October 2022.
  12. Joskow & Léautier 2021, p. 37.
  13. Joskow & Léautier 2021, p. 41.
  14. Joskow & Léautier 2021, pp. 36–37.
  15. Joskow & Léautier 2021, p. 40.
  16. Kovacevic, Raimund M. (24 August 2018). "Valuation and pricing of electricity delivery contracts: the producer's view" (PDF). Annals of Operations Research. 275 (2). 423. doi:10.1007/s10479-018-3010-0. eISSN   1572-9338. ISSN   0254-5330. S2CID   53666505.
  17. 1 2 Ahlqvist, Holmberg & Tangerås 2022, p. 1.
  18. Ahlqvist, Holmberg & Tangerås 2022, pp. 1–2.
  19. Australian Energy Market Commission. "Network regulation". AEMC. Retrieved 11 September 2024.
  20. Schmalensee 2021, pp. 13–14.
  21. 1 2 Schmalensee 2021, p. 13.
  22. Schmalensee 2021, p. 14.
  23. 1 2 Schmalensee 2021, p. 15.
  24. 1 2 Rudnick, H. (June 1994). "Chile: Pioneer in deregulation of the electric power sector". IEEE Power Engineering Review. 14 (6): 28. doi:10.1109/MPER.1994.286546. ISSN   0272-1724. S2CID   36585835.
  25. Littlechild 2021, p. 2.
  26. Watson, William F.; Joskow, Paul L.; Schmalensee, Richard (October 1984). "Markets for Power: An Analysis of Electrical Utility Deregulation". Southern Economic Journal. 51 (2): 640. doi:10.2307/1057863. ISSN   0038-4038. JSTOR   1057863.
  27. Littlechild 2021, p. 3.
  28. Tsaousoglou, Georgios, Juan S. Giraldo, and Nikolaos G. Paterakis. "Market mechanisms for local electricity markets: A review of models, solution concepts and algorithmic techniques." Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 156 (2022): 111890. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2021.111890
  29. Jin, Xiaolong, Qiuwei Wu, and Hongjie Jia. "Local flexibility markets: Literature review on concepts, models and clearing methods." Applied Energy 261 (2020): 114387. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2019.114387
  30. Criteria for economically efficient electricity wholesale markets – Criteria for economically efficient wholesale markets
  31. Nielsen, Sorknæs & Østergaard 2011, pp. 4434–4435.
  32. Anders Plejdrup Houmøller. The Nordic Model for a Liberalised Electricity Market. 2010. pp. 6–7
  33. 1 2 Nielsen, Sorknæs & Østergaard 2011, p. 4436.
  34. 1 2 Nielsen, Sorknæs & Østergaard 2011, p. 4437.
  35. Riddervold, Hans Ole; Aasgård, Ellen Krohn; Haukaas, Lisa; Korpås, Magnus (August 2021). "Internal hydro- and wind portfolio optimisation in real-time market operations". Renewable Energy. 173: 676. arXiv: 2102.10098 . doi:10.1016/j.renene.2021.04.001. ISSN   0960-1481. S2CID   231979276.
  36. 1 2 Ahlqvist, Holmberg & Tangerås 2022, p. 2.
  37. Wolak 2021b, p. 77.
  38. 1 2 3 4 5 Ahlqvist, Holmberg & Tangerås 2022, p. 3.
  39. Ahlqvist, Holmberg & Tangerås 2022, p. 4.
  40. Ahlqvist, Holmberg & Tangerås 2022, pp. 3–4.
  41. 1 2 3 4 Ahlqvist, Holmberg & Tangerås 2022, p. 5.
  42. 1 2 3 Ahlqvist, Holmberg & Tangerås 2022, p. 6.
  43. 1 2 Munoz et al. 2017, p. 52.
  44. Neuhoff; Boyd (July 2011). "International Experiences of Nodal Pricing Implementation" (PDF). Climate Policy Initiative .
  45. Alvey, Trevor; Goodwin, Doug; Ma, Xingwang; Streiffert, Dan; Sun, David (1998). "A security-constrained bid-clearing system for the New Zealand wholesale electricity market". IEEE Transactions on Power Systems. 13 (2): 340–346. Bibcode:1998ITPSy..13..340A. doi:10.1109/59.667349.
  46. "Nodal Price Difference by Transmission Loss". www.emcsg.com. Retrieved 26 February 2022.
  47. Liberopoulos, George; Andrianesis, Panagiotis (22 January 2016). "Critical Review of Pricing Schemes in Markets with Non-Convex Costs". Operations Research. 64 (1): 17–31. doi:10.1287/opre.2015.1451. ISSN   0030-364X.
  48. Wang, Q.; Zhang, C.; Ding, Y.; Xydis, G.; Wang, J.; Østergaard, J. (2015). "Review of real-time electricity markets for integrating distributed energy resources and demand response". Applied Energy. 138: 695–706. Bibcode:2015ApEn..138..695W. doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2014.10.048.
  49. Liboreiro, Jorge (30 September 2022). "EU approves mandatory energy savings and cap on company revenues". euronews. Retrieved 10 October 2022.
  50. Elton, Charlotte (12 October 2022). "Why has the UK imposed a 'de facto windfall tax' on renewable energy?". euronews. Retrieved 12 October 2022.
  51. Sirin, Selahattin Murat; Erten, Ibrahim (1 April 2022). "Price spikes, temporary price caps, and welfare effects of regulatory interventions on wholesale electricity markets". Energy Policy. 163: 112816. Bibcode:2022EnPol.16312816S. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2022.112816. ISSN   0301-4215. S2CID   246551211.
  52. "Why Gas Price Caps and Consumer Subsidies are both Extremely Costly and Ultimately Futile" (PDF).
  53. "Introducing a price cap on Russian gas: A game theoretic analysis" (PDF).
  54. Abnett, Kate (12 October 2022). "EU countries seek way out of impasse over gas price caps". Reuters. Retrieved 12 October 2022.
  55. "Energy Exchange Austria". en.exaa.at. Archived from the original on 31 October 2007. Retrieved 22 November 2021.
  56. "OTE, a.s." 22 July 2017. Archived from the original on 3 January 2017. Retrieved 29 August 2010.
  57. 1 2 3 "Power Exchange Central Europe, a. s." 22 July 2017. Archived from the original on 11 August 2017. Retrieved 21 July 2017. For Czech Republic, Slovakia and Hungary.
  58. 1 2 3 "European Energy Exchange AG". 22 July 2017.
  59. "Hungarian Power Exchange (HUPX)". 22 July 2017.
  60. "Power Exchange India Limited (PXIL)". 22 July 2017.
  61. "Single Electricity Market Operator (SEMO)". 22 July 2017. SEMO is a joint venture between EirGrid PLC and SONI Limited.
  62. "Gestore dei Mercati Energetici SpA (GME)". 22 July 2017.
  63. "Japan Electric Power Exchange (JEPX)". Archived from the original on 12 August 2017. Retrieved 21 July 2017.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  64. "Korea Power Exchange (KPX)". 22 July 2017.
  65. "CENACE (CENACE)". 22 July 2017.
  66. "Philippine Electricity Market Corporation". 22 July 2017.
  67. "Towarowa Giełda Energii". 18 February 2019.
  68. 1 2 "OMI-Polo Español, S.A. (OMIE)". 22 July 2017. Archived from the original on 1 February 2018. Retrieved 21 July 2017.Iberian Electricity Market – day-ahead spot markets.
  69. 1 2 "OMIP – The Iberian Energy Derivatives Exchange". Archived from the original on 17 March 2015. Retrieved 21 July 2017.Iberian Electricity Market – derivatives markets.
  70. 1 2 "Sociedad Rectora del Mercado de Productos Derivados, S.A. (MEFF)". 22 July 2017. Archived from the original on 1 July 2017. Retrieved 21 July 2017.
  71. "The Oman Power and Water Procurement Company (OPWP)". www.omanpwp.om. Retrieved 22 November 2021.
  72. "Trade System Administrator (ATS)" (in Russian). 22 July 2017. Archived from the original on 24 May 2021. Retrieved 16 September 2010.
  73. "Energy Market Authority of Singapore (EMA)". 22 July 2017.
  74. "Energy Market Company (EMC)". 22 July 2017.
  75. "EPİAŞ". www.epias.com.tr. Retrieved 22 November 2021.
  76. "Elexon". 22 July 2017.
  77. Electric Power Markets: National Overview
  78. "Electric Reliability Council of Texas". www.ercot.com. Retrieved 22 November 2021.
  79. "ISO New England". www.iso-ne.com. Retrieved 22 November 2021.
  80. "New York Independent System Operator". 22 July 2017. Archived from the original on 18 July 2017. Retrieved 21 July 2017.
  81. "Southwest Power Pool, Inc". 22 July 2017.Southwest market
  82. "Vietnam Electricity". en.evn.com.vn. Retrieved 22 November 2021.
  83. Acar, Sevil; Aşıcı, Ahmet Atıl; Yeldan, A. Erinç (1 June 2022). "Potential effects of the EU's carbon border adjustment mechanism on the Turkish economy". Environment, Development and Sustainability. 24 (6): 8162–8194. Bibcode:2022EDSus..24.8162A. doi:10.1007/s10668-021-01779-1. ISSN   1573-2975. PMC   8406660 . PMID   34483717.
  84. "Wind energy is healthier for us, here's why". World Economic Forum. 14 December 2022. Retrieved 31 December 2022.
  85. "UK launches review of British electricity market". Reuters. 18 July 2022. Retrieved 31 December 2022.
  86. "Hungarian regulator says electricity market reform will be a priority in 2023 – CEENERGYNEWS". ceenergynews.com. 9 December 2022. Retrieved 31 December 2022.
  87. Yu, Yang; Chen, Lin; Wang, Jianxiao; Zhao, Yue; Song, Jie (10 December 2022). "Implications of power industry marketization for sustainable generation portfolios in China". Journal of Cleaner Production. 378: 134541. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2022.134541. ISSN   0959-6526. S2CID   252792257.
  88. Edwardes-Evans, Henry (23 December 2022). "Europe's electricity market design clash set to intensify in 2023". www.spglobal.com. Retrieved 31 December 2022.
  89. MANIFESTO ON THE CALIFORNIA ELECTRICITY CRISIS, Institute of Management, Innovation and Organization at the University of California, Berkeley, 26 January 2001, archived from the original on 5 February 2012
  90. Independent Energy collapses with customers still owing £119m in bills – The Independent
  91. "Event-driven SOA enables homes to purchase electricity". Searchsoa.techtarget.com. Archived from the original on 13 January 2010. Retrieved 2 February 2012.
  92. IBM Podcast How it works Archived 25 January 2011 at the Wayback Machine
  93. "10 Jan 2008 Grid project lets consumer handle electricity use – United States". IBM. 10 January 2008. Retrieved 2 February 2012.
  94. "PNNL: News – Department of Energy putting power in the hands of consumers through technology". Pacific Northwest National Lab. 9 January 2008. Retrieved 2 February 2012.
  95. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Did Residential Electricity Rates Fall After Retail Competition? A Dynamic Panel Analysis, May 2011
  96. Schmalensee 2021, pp. 19–20.
  97. 1 2 Schmalensee 2021, p. 21.
  98. MacKay & Mercadal 2022, p. 43.
  99. 1 2 Schmalensee 2021, p. 22.
  100. Schmalensee 2021, p. 23.
  101. Power Failure The current scandals pale in comparison to the energy industry's biggest problem: massive debt it can't repay.
  102. "The Bumpy Road to Energy Deregulation". EnPowered. 28 March 2016. Archived from the original on 7 April 2017. Retrieved 6 April 2017.
  103. Markets and Operations PJM
  104. Tezak 2005, p. 3.
  105. Wolak 2021a, p. 5.
  106. 1 2 Wolak 2021a, p. 7.
  107. "ELEKTRİK PİYASASI KAPASİTE MEKANİZMASI YÖNETMELİĞİ," Resmî Gazete Issue:30307 Article 1 and Article 6 Clause 2) h), 20 January 2018
  108. Sabadus, Aura (6 December 2017). "Comment: Turkey, Poland – How politics damage energy markets". Independent Commodity Intelligence Services. Archived from the original on 31 August 2019. Retrieved 22 November 2021.
  109. Durmaz, Tunç; Acar, Sevil; Kizilkaya, Simay (4 October 2021). "Electricity Generation Failures and Capacity Remuneration Mechanism in Turkey". SSRN. Rochester, NY. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3936571. S2CID   240873974. SSRN   3936571.
  110. Korucan, Aysun; Yardimci, Okan (2023). "Capacity Payments in the Turkish Electricity Market: A Necessity or Policy?". International Journal of Energy Economics and Policy. 13 (6): 81–92. doi: 10.32479/ijeep.14833 .
  111. "What is the Capacity Market (CM) and why do we need it?". EMR Settlement Limited. Retrieved 22 November 2021.
  112. "Capacity Market". Gov.UK. Department for Business, Energy & Industrial Strategy. 1 March 2019. Archived from the original on 28 June 2015. Retrieved 22 November 2021.
  113. "Capacity Market". Flexitricity. Archived from the original on 30 April 2021.
  114. Provisional Auction Results T-4 Capacity Market Auction 2014 (PDF) (Report). National Grid. December 2014. Retrieved 22 November 2021.
  115. Final Auction Results – T-4 Capacity Market Auction for 2019/20 (PDF) (Report). National Grid. December 2015. Retrieved 22 November 2021.
  116. Final Auction Results – T-4 Capacity Market Auction for 2020/21 (PDF) (Report). National Grid. December 2016.
  117. "2023 One Year-Ahead Capacity Auction (T-1) Delivery year 2024/25" (PDF). 20 February 2024.
  118. "2023 Four-Year Ahead Capacity Auction (T-4) Delivery year 2027/28" (PDF). 27 February 2024.
  119. 1 2 3 Capacity Market Prequalification User Support Guide (PDF) (Report). National Grid. 8 August 2016. Retrieved 22 November 2021.
  120. AEMO, Australian Energy Market Operator. "Managing frequency in the power system". AEMO. Retrieved 27 May 2020.[ permanent dead link ]

Sources

Further reading