Shadow price

Last updated

A shadow price is the monetary value assigned to an abstract or intangible commodity which is not traded in the marketplace. [1] This often takes the form of an externality. Shadow prices are also known as the recalculation of known market prices in order to account for the presence of distortionary market instruments (e.g. quotas, tariffs, taxes or subsidies). [2] Shadow prices are the real economic prices given to goods and services after they have been appropriately adjusted by removing distortionary market instruments and incorporating the societal impact of the respective good or service. [3] A shadow price is often calculated based on a group of assumptions and estimates because it lacks reliable data, so it is subjective and somewhat inaccurate. [4]

Contents

The need for shadow prices arises as a result of “externalities” and the presence of distortionary market instruments. An externality is defined as a cost or benefit incurred by a third party as a result of production or consumption of a good or services. Where the external effect is not being accounted for in the final cost-benefit analysis of its production. These inaccuracies and skewed results produce an imperfect market mechanism which inefficiently allocates resources. [3]

Market distortion happens when the market is not behaving as it would in a perfect competition due to interventions by governments, companies, and other economic agents. [5] Specifically, the presence of a monopoly or monopsony, in which firms do not behave in a perfect competition, government intervention through taxes and subsidies, public goods, information asymmetric, and restrictions on labour markets are distortionary effects on the market. [6]

Shadow prices are often utilised in cost-benefit analyses by economic and financial analysts when evaluating the merits of public policy & government projects, when externalities or distortionary market instruments are present. [7] The utilisation of shadow prices in these types of public policy decisions is extremely important given the societal impacts of those decisions. After incorporating shadow prices into the analysis, the impacts resulting from the policy or project may differ from the value obtained using market prices. This is an indication that the market has not properly priced the costs or benefits in the first place, or the market hasn’t priced them at all. [8] By conducting analysis with shadow prices it allows analysts to determining whether doing the project will provide greater benefits than the costs incurred in totality. Not just the private or referent group benefits.

Although traditionally shadow prices have been used in government led research, the use of shadow prices in the private sector is becoming increasingly more common, as companies try to evaluate the social impacts of their decisions. As the desire for environmental, social, and corporate governance (ESG) investing has grown so has the need for companies and investors to evaluate the societal impacts of their production and investment decisions. [9] This trend can be seen with the commitments made by most multinational corporations to reducing their CO2 emissions and acknowledging the impact their business activities have on society. [10]

The figures below illustrate how shadow prices can effect efficient allocation of resources. Figure 1 illustrates a positive shadow price where the social marginal cost is less than the private marginal cost. An example of this is vaccinations, they provide a benefit to other people in society because after receiving one you no longer spread infectious diseases. [11] The Private Marginal Cost (PMC) is simply the cost of producing the vaccines whereas the Social Marginal Cost (SMC) is the PMC less the net social benefit of getting vaccinated.

Figure 2 illustrates a negative shadow price where the social marginal cost is greater than the private marginal cost. An example of this is pollution, discarding toxic waste chemicals into waterways have a negative effect on fish stocks in the region, reducing local fisherman's income. In this instance Private Marginal Cost (PMC) is simply the cost of producing the chemicals whereas the Social Marginal Cost (SMC) is the PMC less the net social cost of discarding toxic waste chemicals.

Figure 1: Illustrates the presence of a positive shadow price. In this case production should increase to meet the socially optimum equilibrium. Positive Externality.png
Figure 1: Illustrates the presence of a positive shadow price. In this case production should increase to meet the socially optimum equilibrium.
Figure 2: Illustrates the presence of a negative shadow price. In this case production should decrease to meet the socially optimum equilibrium. Negative Externality.png
Figure 2: Illustrates the presence of a negative shadow price. In this case production should decrease to meet the socially optimum equilibrium.

Cost-benefit analysis

Although shadow pricing may be inaccurate, it is still often used in cost-benefit analyses. Business owners and policymakers turn to shadow pricing to determine the cost the intangible costs and benefits of the project. There are usually many tools to estimate monetary values of these intangibles. They include contingent valuation, benefit value transfers, and revealed preferences which includes hedonic pricing and travel cost method.

Shadow pricing is frequently used to figure out the monetary values of intangibles which are hard to quantify factors during cost-benefit analyses. In the context of public economics, shadow pricing is very useful for governments and policymakers to evaluate whether a public project should be pursued. This is because public goods are very rarely exchanged in the market, making it difficult to determine its price. [12] To help determine the monetary value of these goods, these three tools are often used. Take the example of a government determining whether it wants to undertake a freeway project that would save commuters 500,000 hours a year, save 5 lives a year, and reduce air pollution due to decreased congestion but with a present value cost of $250 million.

Contingent valuation

Contingent valuation is a stated preferences technique. [13] Contingent valuation estimates the value a person places on a good by asking him or her directly. [14] It is essentially surveys for individuals on how much they would be willing to pay for some intangible benefits or to avoid some intangible harms. Typically, these surveys contain detailed descriptions of hypothetical public goods or services, ask respondents how much they would pay for it, and collect relevant demographic data of these respondents. Some common types of these survey questions include: open-ended, referendum-type, payment-card type, and double-bounded referendum-type. [15]

The advantage of contingent valuation is that it is sometimes the only feasible method for valuing a public good. This is especially the case when there is no obvious market price that one can use to determine the value. [16] On the other hand, there are also many disadvantages of this method. For instance, how the survey is structured and how the questions are framed can lead to widely varying results and can induce bias into the results. [17] Other times, the respondents may simply have no idea how much they value the public good in question.

In the freeway project example, policymakers can design a survey that asks respondents on how much they would pay to save a certain period of time or to spend less time in traffic. However, respondents may find it difficult or uncomfortable to put a value on a life.

Benefit value transfers

Benefit value transfer method estimates the value or benefit of a project by using the data, model, functions, and results from a similar project or study with similar characteristics. [18] There are two approaches for benefit value transfer: value transfer and function transfer. [18] Value transfer involves transferring individual unit value from a former project or site to estimate for the new project. Correspondence or the identification of similar and accurate research is critical for the result estimation. [19] In contrast, function transfer uses valuation functions derived from a number of studies. [19] Meta-analysis can be used for creating valuation transfer. [18] As such, using function transfer can provide a more accurate result. [19]

Nonetheless, common errors in the benefit transfer method are measurement error and transfer error. [18] Measurement errors can arise from bias in the selection of studies and assumptions made. [18] Transfer errors are found in the similarity, accuracy, or correspondence in values. [18] [19] However, the benefit transfer method provides an economically efficient way to calculate economic value of a project when there are limitations in conducting original research, including time constraints and costs. [18]

Revealed preferences

Revealed preferences are based on observations on real world behaviors to determine how much individuals place on non-monetary outcomes. In other words, observing individuals' purchasing behaviors is the best way to determine their preferences. It assumes that individuals have made their purchasing decisions over other alternatives – making their final purchases the preferred one. It also allows room for the preferred choice to vary depending on the prices and the budgetary constraints. As such, by varying prices and budgetary constraints, a schedule can be created of an individual's/individuals' preferred choices under certain prices and constraints. [20]

The advantage of revealed preferences is that it reduces biases that contingent valuation may bring. [16] As it is based on real-world behaviors, it is much harder for individuals to manipulate or guess-work their answers. On the other hand, this tool also has its limits. For example, it is difficult to control for other factors that may make one prefer a choice over another. It also fails to fully incorporate indifference between two equally preferred choices. [21]

In the freeway project example, where contingent valuation may fall short in determining how much individuals value lives, revealed preferences may be better suited. For instance, policymakers can look at how much more individuals need to be paid to take on riskier jobs that increase the probability of fatality. However, the drawbacks with revealed preferences also arise – in this case, if the riskier jobs increase the probability of not only death but also injury, or are also unpleasant in other respects, the higher wages may incorporate the other factors, misrepresenting the result.

Hedonic pricing

Hedonic pricing is a model that uses regression analysis to isolate the value of a specific intangible cost or benefit. It is based on the premise that that price is determined by both internal characteristics and external factors. [22] It also assumes that individuals value the characteristics of a good rather than the good itself, which implies that price will reflect a set of internal and external characteristics. It is most often used to calculate variances in housing prices that reflect the value of local environmental factors. The model is based on widely-available and relatively accurate market data, making this method uncontroversial and inexpensive to use. [23]

As such, one of hedonic pricing's main advantages is that it can be used to estimate values on actual choices. This method is also very versatile and can be adapted to incorporate multiple other interactions with other factors. However, one of its major downfalls is that it is rather limited – it can mostly only measure things that are related to housing prices. It also assumes that individuals have the freedom and power to select the preferred combination given their income but in actuality, this may not be the case as the market may be influenced by changes in taxes and interest rates. [24]

In the freeway project example, hedonic pricing may be useful to value the benefits of reduced air pollution. It can run a regression of home values on clean air with a variety of control variables that can include home size, age of home, number of bedrooms and bathrooms, crime statistics, school qualities, etc. Hedonic pricing may also be considered in quantifying the monetary value of time saved. It can run a regression of home values on proximity to work with a similar set of control variables.

Illustration #1

Suppose a consumer with utility function faces prices and is endowed with income Then the consumer's problem is:

Forming the Lagrangian auxiliary function taking first-order conditions and solving for its saddle point we obtain which satisfy

This gives us a clear interpretation of the Lagrange multiplier in the context of consumer maximization. If the consumer is given an extra unit of income (the budget constraint is relaxed) at the optimal consumption level where the marginal utility per unit of income for each good is equal to as above, then the change in maximal utility per unit of additional income will be equal to since at the optimum the consumer gets the same amount of marginal utility per unit of income from spending his additional income on either good.

Illustration #2

Holding prices fixed, if we define the indirect utility function as

then we have the identity

where are the demand functions, i.e.

Now define the optimal expenditure function

Assume differentiability and that is the solution at , then we have from the multivariate chain rule:

Now we may conclude that

This again gives the obvious interpretation, one extra unit of optimal expenditure will lead to units of optimal utility.

Travel cost method

Travel cost method is used to estimate the economic value of a recreation site [25] using the travel cost each individual incur to travel to a recreational site. [26] Costs include the opportunity costs of the time it takes to get to the site, transportation cost, accommodation costs, any parking fees, and so on. Additionally, the area from which the individuals are from are classified into zones. [26] Therefore, costs incurred by each individual differ from one another. Moreover, the number of visits per year is also taken into account to indicate the willingness to pay.[ citation needed ]With the data, an aggregate demand curve is created.[ citation needed ]

There are two approaches: individual travel cost method and zonal travel cost method. [27] The first one puts an emphasis on individual travel costs, number of visits a year, and other variables. The latter focuses on the number of annual visits from different zones.

However, it can be challenging to get data on the costs accurately incurred. the travel cost method does not accommodate the value or pleasure individuals have in the journey. [26] Also, the method does not consider multi-purpose journeys,[ citation needed ] marginal costs, and only estimates the value of the site as a whole. [26]

Constrained optimization

In constrained optimization in economics, the shadow price is the change, per infinitesimal unit of the constraint, in the optimal value of the objective function of an optimization problem obtained by relaxing the constraint. If the objective function is utility, it is the marginal utility of relaxing the constraint. If the objective function is cost, it is the marginal cost of strengthening the constraint. In a business application, a shadow price is the maximum price that management is willing to pay for an extra unit of a given limited resource. [28] For example, if a production line is already operating at its maximum 40-hour limit, the shadow price would be the maximum price the manager would be willing to pay for operating it for an additional hour, based on the benefits he would get from this change.

More formally, the shadow price is the value of the Lagrange multiplier at the optimal solution, which means that it is the infinitesimal change in the objective function arising from an infinitesimal change in the constraint. This follows from the fact that at the optimal solution the gradient of the objective function is a linear combination of the constraint function gradients with the weights equal to the Lagrange multipliers. Each constraint in an optimization problem has a shadow price or dual variable.

Control theory

In optimal control theory, the concept of shadow price is reformulated as costate equations, and one solves the problem by minimization of the associated Hamiltonian via Pontryagin's minimum principle.

See also

Related Research Articles

The Black–Scholes or Black–Scholes–Merton model is a mathematical model for the dynamics of a financial market containing derivative investment instruments, using various underlying assumptions. From the parabolic partial differential equation in the model, known as the Black–Scholes equation, one can deduce the Black–Scholes formula, which gives a theoretical estimate of the price of European-style options and shows that the option has a unique price given the risk of the security and its expected return. The equation and model are named after economists Fischer Black and Myron Scholes. Robert C. Merton, who first wrote an academic paper on the subject, is sometimes also credited.

In mathematical optimization, the method of Lagrange multipliers is a strategy for finding the local maxima and minima of a function subject to equation constraints. It is named after the mathematician Joseph-Louis Lagrange.

The principle of maximum entropy states that the probability distribution which best represents the current state of knowledge about a system is the one with largest entropy, in the context of precisely stated prior data.

The costate equation is related to the state equation used in optimal control. It is also referred to as auxiliary, adjoint, influence, or multiplier equation. It is stated as a vector of first order differential equations

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Optimal control</span> Mathematical way of attaining a desired output from a dynamic system

Optimal control theory is a branch of control theory that deals with finding a control for a dynamical system over a period of time such that an objective function is optimized. It has numerous applications in science, engineering and operations research. For example, the dynamical system might be a spacecraft with controls corresponding to rocket thrusters, and the objective might be to reach the Moon with minimum fuel expenditure. Or the dynamical system could be a nation's economy, with the objective to minimize unemployment; the controls in this case could be fiscal and monetary policy. A dynamical system may also be introduced to embed operations research problems within the framework of optimal control theory.

Lookback options, in the terminology of finance, are a type of exotic option with path dependency, among many other kind of options. The payoff depends on the optimal underlying asset's price occurring over the life of the option. The option allows the holder to "look back" over time to determine the payoff. There exist two kinds of lookback options: with floating strike and with fixed strike.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Mechanism design</span> Field in game theory

Mechanism design is a field in economics and game theory that takes an objectives-first approach to designing economic mechanisms or incentives, toward desired objectives, in strategic settings, where players act rationally. Because it starts at the end of the game, then goes backwards, it is also called reverse game theory. It has broad applications, from economics and politics in fields such as market design, auction theory and social choice theory to networked-systems.

Pontryagin's maximum principle is used in optimal control theory to find the best possible control for taking a dynamical system from one state to another, especially in the presence of constraints for the state or input controls. It states that it is necessary for any optimal control along with the optimal state trajectory to solve the so-called Hamiltonian system, which is a two-point boundary value problem, plus a maximum condition of the control Hamiltonian. These necessary conditions become sufficient under certain convexity conditions on the objective and constraint functions.

Economic order quantity (EOQ), also known as financial purchase quantity or economic buying quantity, is the order quantity that minimizes the total holding costs and ordering costs in inventory management. It is one of the oldest classical production scheduling models. The model was developed by Ford W. Harris in 1913, but the consultant R. H. Wilson applied it extensively, and he and K. Andler are given credit for their in-depth analysis.

The Ramsey problem, or Ramsey pricing, or Ramsey–Boiteux pricing, is a second-best policy problem concerning what prices a public monopoly should charge for the various products it sells in order to maximize social welfare while earning enough revenue to cover its fixed costs.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Regularization (mathematics)</span> Technique to make a model more generalizable and transferable

In mathematics, statistics, finance, computer science, particularly in machine learning and inverse problems, regularization is a process that changes the result answer to be "simpler". It is often used to obtain results for ill-posed problems or to prevent overfitting.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Samuelson condition</span>

The Samuelson condition, due to Paul Samuelson, in the theory of Public Economics, is a condition for optimal provision of public goods.

In mathematical optimization, the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker (KKT) conditions, also known as the Kuhn–Tucker conditions, are first derivative tests for a solution in nonlinear programming to be optimal, provided that some regularity conditions are satisfied.

Roy's identity is a major result in microeconomics having applications in consumer choice and the theory of the firm. The lemma relates the ordinary (Marshallian) demand function to the derivatives of the indirect utility function. Specifically, denoting the indirect utility function as the Marshallian demand function for good can be calculated as

In mathematics and economics, the envelope theorem is a major result about the differentiability properties of the value function of a parameterized optimization problem. As we change parameters of the objective, the envelope theorem shows that, in a certain sense, changes in the optimizer of the objective do not contribute to the change in the objective function. The envelope theorem is an important tool for comparative statics of optimization models.

A Lindahl tax is a form of taxation conceived by Erik Lindahl in which individuals pay for public goods according to their marginal benefits. In other words, they pay according to the amount of satisfaction or utility they derive from the consumption of an additional unit of the public good. Lindahl taxation is designed to maximize efficiency for each individual and provide the optimal level of a public good.

The Hamiltonian is a function used to solve a problem of optimal control for a dynamical system. It can be understood as an instantaneous increment of the Lagrangian expression of the problem that is to be optimized over a certain time period. Inspired by—but distinct from—the Hamiltonian of classical mechanics, the Hamiltonian of optimal control theory was developed by Lev Pontryagin as part of his maximum principle. Pontryagin proved that a necessary condition for solving the optimal control problem is that the control should be chosen so as to optimize the Hamiltonian.

The value function of an optimization problem gives the value attained by the objective function at a solution, while only depending on the parameters of the problem. In a controlled dynamical system, the value function represents the optimal payoff of the system over the interval [t, t1] when started at the time-t state variable x(t)=x. If the objective function represents some cost that is to be minimized, the value function can be interpreted as the cost to finish the optimal program, and is thus referred to as "cost-to-go function." In an economic context, where the objective function usually represents utility, the value function is conceptually equivalent to the indirect utility function.

Gossen's Second “Law”, named for Hermann Heinrich Gossen (1810–1858), is the assertion that an economic agent will allocate his or her expenditures such that the ratio of the marginal utility of each good or service to its price is equal to that for every other good or service. Formally,

The Atkinson–Stiglitz theorem is a theorem of public economics. It implies that no indirect taxes need to be employed where the utility function is separable between labor and all commodities. Non-linear income taxation can be used by the government and was in a seminal article by Joseph Stiglitz and Anthony Atkinson in 1976. The Atkinson–Stiglitz theorem is generally considered one of the most important theoretical results in public economics and spawned a broad literature that delimited the conditions under which the theorem holds For example, Saez (2002) demonstrated that the Atkinson–Stiglitz theorem does not hold if households have heterogeneous preferences rather than homogeneous ones. In practice, the Atkinson–Stiglitz theorem has often been invoked in the debate on optimal capital income taxation. Because capital income taxation can be interpreted as the taxation of future consumption over the taxation of present consumption, the theorem implies that governments should abstain from capital income taxation if non-linear income taxation is an option since capital income taxation would not improve equity by comparison to the non-linear income tax, while additionally distorting savings.

References

  1. "Shadow Pricing". Corporate Finance Institute. Retrieved 2022-05-04.
  2. Smith, Alasdair (1987). "Shadow Price Calculations in Distorted Economies". The Scandinavian Journal of Economics. 89 (3): 287–302. doi:10.2307/3440199. ISSN   0347-0520. JSTOR   3440199.
  3. 1 2 Starrett, David A. (2000). "Shadow Pricing in Economics". Ecosystems. 3 (1): 16–20. doi:10.1007/s100210000004. ISSN   1432-9840. JSTOR   3658662. S2CID   8293976.
  4. Staff, Investopedia (2003-11-26). "Shadow Pricing". Investopedia. Retrieved 2018-03-02.
  5. Wuyts, Wendy (2020), Leal Filho, Walter; Azul, Anabela Marisa; Brandli, Luciana; özuyar, Pinar Gökçin (eds.), "Market Distortions Encouraging Wasteful Consumption", Responsible Consumption and Production, Encyclopedia of the UN Sustainable Development Goals, Cham: Springer International Publishing, pp. 443–453, doi:10.1007/978-3-319-95726-5_45, ISBN   978-3-319-95726-5 , retrieved 2023-04-22
  6. "9.2: Imperfections and Distortions Defined". Social Sci LibreTexts. 2020-01-19. Retrieved 2023-04-22.
  7. "Shadow Prices: Meaning, Need, Limitations and Uses". Economics Discussion. 2016-03-02. Retrieved 2022-05-04.
  8. "Shadow Pricing". WallStreetMojo. 2020-05-11. Retrieved 2022-05-04.
  9. Kell, Georg. "The Remarkable Rise Of ESG". Forbes. Retrieved 2022-05-04.
  10. "More than 100 multinational corporations have taken The Climate Pledge". Climate Home News. 2021-04-23. Retrieved 2022-05-04.
  11. Pettinger, Tejvan (21 January 2021). "Positive Externalities". Economics Help. Retrieved 2022-05-04.
  12. International encyclopedia of the social & behavioral sciences. Smelser, Neil J., Baltes, Paul B. (1st ed.). Amsterdam: Elsevier. 2001. p. 13272. ISBN   0080430767. OCLC   47869490.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  13. Brown, Thomas C. (2003), Champ, Patricia A.; Boyle, Kevin J.; Brown, Thomas C. (eds.), "Introduction to Stated Preference Methods", A Primer on Nonmarket Valuation, The Economics of Non-Market Goods and Resources, Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands, vol. 3, pp. 99–110, doi:10.1007/978-94-007-0826-6_4, ISBN   978-94-007-0826-6 , retrieved 2023-04-22
  14. "Applications of the contingent valuation method in developing countries". www.fao.org. Retrieved 2018-03-02.
  15. "What is the contingent valuation method, CVM?" (PDF). 2017-10-31. Retrieved 2018-03-02.
  16. 1 2 Jonathan, Gruber (2015-12-28). Public finance and public policy (Fifth ed.). New York. p. 226. ISBN   9781464143335. OCLC   914290290.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  17. Diamond, Peter A; Hausman, Jerry A (1994). "Contingent Valuation: Is Some Number Better than No Number?". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 8 (4): 45–64. doi: 10.1257/jep.8.4.45 . ISSN   0895-3309.
  18. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Boutwell, James L.; Westra, John V. (2013). "Benefit Transfer: A Review of Methodologies and Challenges". Resources. 2 (4): 517–527. doi: 10.3390/resources2040517 . ISSN   2079-9276.
  19. 1 2 3 4 Plummer, Mark L (2009). "Assessing benefit transfer for the valuation of ecosystem services". Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment. 7 (1): 38–45. doi: 10.1890/080091 . ISSN   1540-9295.
  20. Staff, Investopedia (2010-06-28). "Revealed Preference". Investopedia. Retrieved 2018-03-03.
  21. "Demerits of the Revealed Preference Theory". economics-the-economy.knoji.com. Retrieved 2018-03-03.
  22. Staff, Investopedia (2003-11-20). "Hedonic Pricing". Investopedia. Retrieved 2018-03-03.
  23. "Hedonic Pricing Method". www.ecosystemvaluation.org. Retrieved 2018-03-03.
  24. "Hedonic Pricing – Transportation Benefit-Cost Analysis". bca.transportationeconomics.org. Retrieved 2018-03-03.
  25. Menz, Fredric C.; Wilton, Donald P. (1983). "Alternative Ways to Measure Recreation Values by the Travel Cost Method". American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 65 (2): 332–336. doi:10.2307/1240884. ISSN   0002-9092. JSTOR   1240884.
  26. 1 2 3 4 "Travel Cost Method". www.cbabuilder.co.uk. Retrieved 2023-04-22.
  27. "Travel Cost Method". www.ecosystemvaluation.org. Retrieved 2023-04-22.
  28. Shadow Price: Definition and Much More from Answers.com

Further reading