Demographic economics

Last updated

Demographic economics or population economics is the application of economic analysis to demography, the study of human populations, including size, growth, density, distribution, and vital statistics. [1] [2]

Contents

Aspects

Aspects of the subject include

Other subfields include measuring value of life [53] [54] and the economics of the elderly [55] [56] [57] and the handicapped [58] [59] [60] and of gender, [61] [62] [63] race, minorities, and non-labor discrimination. [64] [65] In coverage and subfields, it complements labor economics [66] [67] and implicates a variety of other economics subjects. [68] [69] [70]

Subareas

The Journal of Economic Literature classification codes are a way of categorizing subjects in economics. There, demographic economics is paired with labour economics as one of 19 primary classifications at JEL: J. [71] It has eight subareas:

General
Demographic Trends and Forecasts
Marriage; Marital Dissolution; Family Structure
Fertility; Family Planning; Child Care; Children; Youth
Economics of the Elderly; Economics of the Handicapped
Economics of Minorities and Races; Non-labor Discrimination
Economics of Gender; Non-labor Discrimination
Value of life; Foregone Income
Public Policy

See also

Related:

Notes

  1. 1 2 3 4 Kelley, Allen C.; Schmidt, Robert M. (2008). "Economic Demography". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 655. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0428. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  2. van Praag, Bernard M. S. (1988). "The notion of population economics". Journal of Population Economics. Vol. 1. pp. 5–16. doi:10.1007/bf00171507. JSTOR   20007247. PMID   12342564.
  3. 1 2 Foster, Andrew (2008). "Marriage Markets". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 356. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1044. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  4. Schultz, T. Paul (2008). "Fertility in Developing Countries". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (PDF). London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 291. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0560. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  5. Galor, Oded (2008). "Economic Growth in the Very Long Run". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (PDF). London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 685. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0434. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  6. Adsera, Alicia (2008). "Fertility in Developed Countries". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 286. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0559. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  7. Montgomery, Mark; Trussell, James (1986). Models of marital status and childbearing. Handbook of Labor Economics. Vol. 1. pp. 205–71. doi:10.1016/S1573-4463(86)01006-4. ISBN   978-0-444-87856-4.
  8. Galor, Oded (2005). "The Demographic Transition and the Emergence of Sustained Economic Growth" (PDF). Journal of the European Economic Association. 3 (2–3): 494–504. doi:10.1162/jeea.2005.3.2-3.494. hdl: 10419/80187 . JSTOR   40004992.
  9. Hanushek, Eric A (1992). "The Trade-Off between Child Quantity and Quality" (PDF). Journal of Political Economy. 100 (1): 84–117. doi:10.1086/261808. JSTOR   2138807. S2CID   154820218.
  10. Lehrer, Evelyn L. (1996). "Religion as a determinant of marital fertility". Journal of Population Economics. 9 (2): 173–96. doi:10.1007/s001480050013. JSTOR   20007500. PMID   12320501. S2CID   24326107.
  11. Ermisch, John (2008). "Family Economics". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 260. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0550. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  12. Ermisch, John (2003). An Economic Analysis of the Family . Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN   978-0-691-09667-4.[ page needed ]
  13. Becker, Gary S. (2008). "Family". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 1. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.2528. ISBN   9780333786765.
  14. Becker, Gary S. (1991) [1981]. A Treatise on the Family. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. ISBN   978-0-674-90698-3.[ page needed ]
  15. Becker, Gary S. (1988). "Family Economics and Macro Behavior" (PDF). American Economic Review. 78 (1): 1–13.
  16. Lehrer, Evelyn (2007). Religion, Economics and Demography: The Effects of Religion on Education, Work, and the Family. Routledge. ISBN   978-0-415-70194-5.[ page needed ]
  17. Lehrer, Evelyn L. (2004). "Religion as a Determinant of Economic and Demographic Behavior in the United States". Population and Development Review. 30 (4): 707–726. doi:10.1111/j.1728-4457.2004.00038.x. hdl: 10419/20687 . JSTOR   3657335. S2CID   4981446.
  18. Weiss, Yoram (2008). "Marriage and Divorce". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 347. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1043. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  19. Lehrer, Evelyn L.; Chiswick, Carmel U. (August 1993). "Religion as a Determinant of Marital Stability". Demography. 30 (3): 385–404. doi: 10.2307/2061647 . JSTOR   2061647. PMID   8405605.
  20. de la Croix, David; Mariani, Fabio (2015-01-07). "From Polygyny to Serial Monogamy: a Unified Theory of Marriage Institutions*". The Review of Economic Studies. 82 (2): 565–607. doi:10.1093/restud/rdv001. hdl:2078.1/110739. ISSN   0034-6527.
  21. Canning, David; Bloom, David E. (2008). "Population Health, Economic Implications of". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 516. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1310. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  22. Vaupel, James W.; Von Kistowski, Kristín G.; Rau, Roland (2008). "Mortality". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 781. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1141. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  23. Preston, Samuel H. (1975). "The Changing Relation between Mortality and level of Economic Development". Population Studies. 29 (2): 231–248. doi:10.1080/00324728.1975.10410201. PMC   2572360 . PMID   11630494.
  24. Bloom, D. E; Canning, D. (2007). "Commentary: The Preston Curve 30 years on: Still sparking fires". International Journal of Epidemiology. 36 (3): 498–9, discussion 502–3. doi: 10.1093/ije/dym079 . PMID   17550948.
  25. Kelley, AC; Schmidt, RM (1996). "Saving, dependency and development". Journal of Population Economics. 9 (4): 365–86. doi:10.1007/BF00573070. PMID   12292225. S2CID   1440355.
  26. Weil, David N. (May 1999). "Population Growth, Dependency, and Consumption". The American Economic Review. 89 (2): 251–5. doi:10.1257/aer.89.2.251. JSTOR   117115.
  27. Denton, Frank T.; Spencer, Byron G. (2010). "Population Aging and Its Economic Costs: A Survey of the Issues and Evidence". Canadian Journal on Aging. 19: 1–31. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.613.1972 . doi:10.1017/S071498080001463X. S2CID   79567183.
  28. Ioannides, Yannis M.; Rossi-Hansberg, Esteban (2008). "Urban Growth". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 544. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1772. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  29. Walker, James R. (2008). "Internal Migration". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 421. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0824. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  30. Borjas, George J. (2008). "International Migration". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. p. 453. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0830. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  31. Lee, Ronald D. (2008). "Population Dynamics". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 512. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1309. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  32. Galor, Oded (2008). "Human Capital, Fertility and Growth". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (PDF). London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 109. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0755. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  33. Galor, Oded; Weil, David N. (September 2000). "Population, Technology, and Growth: From Malthusian Stagnation to the Demographic Transition and beyond". The American Economic Review. 90 (4): 806–28. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.195.5342 . doi:10.1257/aer.90.4.806. JSTOR   117309.
  34. Johnson, David Gale; Lee, Ronald Demos, eds. (1987). Population Growth and Economic Development: Issues and Evidence. University of Wisconsin Press. ISBN   978-0-299-11130-4.[ page needed ]
  35. Kelley, Allen C. (1988). "Economic Consequences of Population Change in the Third World". Journal of Economic Literature. December (4): 1685–728. JSTOR   2726858.
  36. Brander, James A.; Dowrick, Steve (1994). "The role of fertility and population in economic growth". Journal of Population Economics. 7 (1): 1–25. doi:10.1007/BF00160435. PMID   12287546. S2CID   20943767.
  37. Kremer, Michael (August 1993). "Population Growth and Technological Change: One Million B.C. to 1990". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 108 (3): 681–716. doi:10.2307/2118405. JSTOR   2118405.
  38. Dasgupta, Partha (December 1995). "The Population Problem: Theory and Evidence". Journal of Economic Literature. 33 (4): 1879–902. JSTOR   2729316.
  39. Arrow, K.; Bolin, B.; Costanza, R.; Dasgupta, P.; Folke, C.; Holling, C. S.; Jansson, B.-O.; Levin, S.; Mäler, K.-G.; Perrings, C.; Pimentel, D. (1995). "Economic Growth, Carrying Capacity, and the Environment". Science. 268 (5210): 520–1. Bibcode:1995Sci...268..520A. doi:10.1126/science.268.5210.520. PMID   17756719.
  40. Cohen, J. (1995). "Population growth and earth's human carrying capacity". Science. 269 (5222): 341–6. Bibcode:1995Sci...269..341C. doi:10.1126/science.7618100. PMID   7618100.
  41. Cohen, Joel E. (1995). How Many People Can the Earth Support?. Norton. ISBN   978-0-393-31495-3.[ page needed ]
  42. Currie, Janet (2008). "Child Health and Mortality". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 769. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0228. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  43. National Research Council (1986). Population Growth and Economic Development: Policy Questions . National Academies Press. ISBN   978-0-309-03641-2.[ page needed ]
  44. Theodore W. Schultz, 1981. Investing in People: The Economics of Population Quality, University of California Press. Description and chapter-preview links.
  45. Sen, Amartya (1995). "Authoritarianism versus Cooperation" (PDF). International Lecture Series on Population Issues. John D. and Catherine T. MacArthur Foundation. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2016-06-23. Republished as Sen, Amartya (1997). "Population policy: Authoritarianism versus cooperation". Journal of Population Economics. 10 (1): 3–22. doi:10.1007/s001480050029. JSTOR   20007525. S2CID   154992419.
  46. Birdsall, Nancy; Kelley, Allen C.; Sinding, Steven W., eds. (2001). Population Matters: Demographic Change, Economic Growth, and Poverty in the Developing World. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ISBN   978-0-19-152953-5.[ page needed ]
  47. Samuelson, Paul A. (December 1958). "An Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest with or without the Social Contrivance of Money". Journal of Political Economy. 66 (6): 467–82. doi:10.1086/258100. JSTOR   1826989. S2CID   153586213.
  48. Gokhale, Jagadeesh (2008). "Generational Accounting". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 630. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0627. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  49. Tuljapurkar, Shripad (2008). "Stable Population Theory". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 826. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1602. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  50. Greenwood, Jeremy; Seshadri, Ananth; Vandenbroucke, Guillaume (2005). "The Baby Boom and Baby Bust". American Economic Review. 95: 183–207. doi:10.1257/0002828053828680.
  51. Mosk, Carl (2008). "Historical Demography". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 38. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0738. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  52. Lee, Ronald D. (2008). "Demographic Transition". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 433. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0374. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  53. Kip Viscusi, W. (2008). "Value of Life". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 586. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1784. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  54. Becker, Gary S; Philipson, Tomas J; Soares, Rodrigo R (2005). "The Quantity and Quality of Life and the Evolution of World Inequality". American Economic Review. 95 (1): 277–291. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.589.702 . doi:10.1257/0002828053828563. PMID   29120118. S2CID   12760521.
  55. Hurd, Michael (2008). "Retirement". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 130. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1431. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  56. Weil, David N. (2008). "Population Ageing". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 499. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1307. ISBN   978-0-333-78676-5.
  57. Clark, Robert Louis; Spengler, Joseph John (1998). The Economics of Individual and Population Aging . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN   978-0-521-22883-1.[ page needed ]
  58. Blanchet, Didier; Fleurbaey, Marc (2006). "Selfishness, altruism and normative principles in the economic analysis of social transfers". Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity. Vol. 2. p. 1465. doi:10.1016/S1574-0714(06)02024-0. ISBN   9780444521453.
  59. Tomlinson, Sally (1985). "The Expansion of Special Education". Oxford Review of Education. 11 (2): 157–165. doi:10.1080/0305498850110203. JSTOR   1050498.
  60. Bubolz, Margaret M.; Whiren, Alice P. (January 1984). "The Family of the Handicapped: An Ecological Model for Policy and Practice". Family Relations. 33 (1): 5–12. doi:10.2307/584584. JSTOR   584584.
  61. Galor, Oded; Weil, David N. (June 1996). "The Gender Gap, Fertility, and Growth". The American Economic Review. 86 (3): 374–87. JSTOR   2118202.
  62. Jacobsen, Joyce P. (2008), "gender roles and division of labour", in Durlauf, Steven N.; Blume, Lawrence E. (eds.), The new Palgrave dictionary of economics (2nd ed.), Basingstoke, Hampshire New York: Palgrave Macmillan, p. 582, ISBN   9780333786765. Also available online.
  63. Jacobsen, Joyce P. (2007). The economics of gender (3rd ed.). Malden, Massachusetts: Blackwell Publishing. ISBN   9781405161824.
  64. Sowell, Thomas (1975). Race and Economics. McKay.[ page needed ]
  65. Sowell, Thomas (1995). Race and Culture: A World View . Basic Books. ISBN   978-0-465-06797-8.
  66. JEL classification codes#Labor and demographic economics JEL: J Subcategories.
  67. Labor and Demographic Economics: Demographic Economics, NBER Working Paper abstract links from the National Bureau of Economic Research.
  68. Assaf Razin and Efraim Sadka, 1996. Population Economics. MIT Press. Description & chapter previews.
  69. Rosenzweig, Mark R.; Stark, Oded (1997). "Introduction: Population and family economics". Handbook of Population and Family Economics. Vol. 1. p.  1. doi:10.1016/S1574-003X(97)80018-9. ISBN   9780444826459.
  70. Search of The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online, "population OR demography".
  71. Of which a complete list for JEL: J with corresponding Wikipedia links is at JEL classification codes#Labor and demographic economics JEL: J Subcategories.

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economics</span> Social science

Economics is a social science that studies the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Kenneth Arrow</span> American economist (1921–2017)

Kenneth Joseph Arrow was an American economist, mathematician, writer, and political theorist. He was the joint winner of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences with John Hicks in 1972.

A natural experiment is an empirical study in which individuals are exposed to the experimental and control conditions that are determined by nature or by other factors outside the control of the investigators. The process governing the exposures arguably resembles random assignment. Thus, natural experiments are observational studies and are not controlled in the traditional sense of a randomized experiment. Natural experiments are most useful when there has been a clearly defined exposure involving a well defined subpopulation such that changes in outcomes may be plausibly attributed to the exposure. In this sense, the difference between a natural experiment and a non-experimental observational study is that the former includes a comparison of conditions that pave the way for causal inference, but the latter does not.

In the social sciences, methodological individualism is a framework that describes social phenomena as a consequence of subjective personal motivations by individual actors. Class or group dynamics, which operate on systemic explanations, are deemed illusory, and, thus, rejected or de-prioritized. With its bottom-up micro-level approach, methodological individualism is often contrasted with methodological holism, a top-down macro-level approach, and methodological pluralism.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Étienne Laspeyres</span> German economist

Ernst Louis Étienne Laspeyres was a German economist. He was Professor ordinarius of economics and statistics or State Sciences and cameralistics in Basel, Riga, Dorpat, Karlsruhe, and finally for 26 years in Gießen. Laspeyres was the scion of a Huguenot family of originally Gascon descent which had settled in Berlin in the 17th century, and he emphasised the Occitan pronunciation of his name as a link to his Gascon origins.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Overlapping generations model</span>

The overlapping generations (OLG) model is one of the dominating frameworks of analysis in the study of macroeconomic dynamics and economic growth. In contrast, to the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans neoclassical growth model in which individuals are infinitely-lived, in the OLG model individuals live a finite length of time, long enough to overlap with at least one period of another agent's life.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Liquidity preference</span> Interest seen as a reward for parting with liquidity

In macroeconomic theory, liquidity preference is the demand for money, considered as liquidity. The concept was first developed by John Maynard Keynes in his book The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (1936) to explain determination of the interest rate by the supply and demand for money. The demand for money as an asset was theorized to depend on the interest foregone by not holding bonds. Interest rates, he argues, cannot be a reward for saving as such because, if a person hoards his savings in cash, keeping it under his mattress say, he will receive no interest, although he has nevertheless refrained from consuming all his current income. Instead of a reward for saving, interest, in the Keynesian analysis, is a reward for parting with liquidity. According to Keynes, money is the most liquid asset. Liquidity is an attribute to an asset. The more quickly an asset is converted into money the more liquid it is said to be.

Richard Ferdinand Kahn, Baron Kahn, CBE, FBA was a British economist.

Family economics applies economic concepts such as production, division of labor, distribution, and decision making to the family. It is used to explain outcomes unique to family—such as marriage, the decision to have children, fertility, polygamy, time devoted to domestic production, and dowry payments using economic analysis.

In mathematics, a vector measure is a function defined on a family of sets and taking vector values satisfying certain properties. It is a generalization of the concept of finite measure, which takes nonnegative real values only.

Lawrence E. Blume is the Distinguished Arts and Sciences Professor of Economics and Professor of Information Science at Cornell University, US.

Involuntary unemployment occurs when a person is unemployed despite being willing to work at the prevailing wage. It is distinguished from voluntary unemployment, where a person refuses to work because their reservation wage is higher than the prevailing wage. In an economy with involuntary unemployment, there is a surplus of labor at the current real wage. This occurs when there is some force that prevents the real wage rate from decreasing to the real wage rate that would equilibrate supply and demand. Structural unemployment is also involuntary.

Peter Kenneth Newman was an English economist and historian of economic thought. He helped to edit The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, to which he contributed several articles.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Scarcity</span> Concept in economics

In economics, scarcity "refers to the basic fact of life that there exists only a finite amount of human and nonhuman resources which the best technical knowledge is capable of using to produce only limited maximum amounts of each economic good." If the conditions of scarcity didn't exist and an "infinite amount of every good could be produced or human wants fully satisfied ... there would be no economic goods, i.e. goods that are relatively scarce..." Scarcity is the limited availability of a commodity, which may be in demand in the market or by the commons. Scarcity also includes an individual's lack of resources to buy commodities. The opposite of scarcity is abundance. Scarcity plays a key role in economic theory, and it is essential for a "proper definition of economics itself".

"The best example is perhaps Walras' definition of social wealth, i.e., economic goods. 'By social wealth', says Walras, 'I mean all things, material or immaterial, that are scarce, that is to say, on the one hand, useful to us and, on the other hand, only available to us in limited quantity'."

<span class="mw-page-title-main">History of macroeconomic thought</span> Aspect of history

Macroeconomic theory has its origins in the study of business cycles and monetary theory. In general, early theorists believed monetary factors could not affect real factors such as real output. John Maynard Keynes attacked some of these "classical" theories and produced a general theory that described the whole economy in terms of aggregates rather than individual, microeconomic parts. Attempting to explain unemployment and recessions, he noticed the tendency for people and businesses to hoard cash and avoid investment during a recession. He argued that this invalidated the assumptions of classical economists who thought that markets always clear, leaving no surplus of goods and no willing labor left idle.

Ross Marc Starr is an American economist who specializes in microeconomic theory, monetary economics and mathematical economics. He is a professor at the University of California, San Diego.

In economics, non-convexity refers to violations of the convexity assumptions of elementary economics. Basic economics textbooks concentrate on consumers with convex preferences and convex budget sets and on producers with convex production sets; for convex models, the predicted economic behavior is well understood. When convexity assumptions are violated, then many of the good properties of competitive markets need not hold: Thus, non-convexity is associated with market failures, where supply and demand differ or where market equilibria can be inefficient. Non-convex economies are studied with nonsmooth analysis, which is a generalization of convex analysis.

Convexity is an important topic in economics. In the Arrow–Debreu model of general economic equilibrium, agents have convex budget sets and convex preferences: At equilibrium prices, the budget hyperplane supports the best attainable indifference curve. The profit function is the convex conjugate of the cost function. Convex analysis is the standard tool for analyzing textbook economics. Non‑convex phenomena in economics have been studied with nonsmooth analysis, which generalizes convex analysis.

Garett Jones is an American economist and author. His research pertains to the fields of macroeconomics, monetary policy, IQ in relation to productivity, short-term business cycles, and economic development. He is an associate professor at George Mason University and the BB&T Professor for the Study of Capitalism at the Mercatus Center.

B. Douglas Bernheim is an American professor of Economics, currently the Edward Ames Edmunds Professor of Economics at Stanford University; his previous academic appointments have included an endowed chair in Economics and Business Policy at Princeton University and an endowed chair in Insurance and Risk Management at Northwestern University’s J.L. Kellogg Graduate School of Management, Department of Finance. He has published many articles in academic journals, and has received a number of awards recognizing his contributions to the field of economics. He is a partner with Bates White, LLC an economic consulting firm with offices in Washington, D.C., and San Diego, California.

References

"Ageing Populations," pp. 1-3, by Robert L. Clark
"Declining Population," pp. 10-15, by Robin Barlow
"Demographic Transition," pp. 16-23, by Ansley J. Coale
"Extended Family," pp. 58-63, by Oliva Harris
"Family," pp. 65-76, by Gary S. Becker
"Fertility," pp.77-89, by Richard A. Easterlin
"Gender," pp. 95-108, by Francine D. Blau
"Race and Economics," pp. 215-218, by H. Stanback
"Value of Life," pp.289-76, by Thomas C. Schelling

Journals