Economics of digitization

Last updated

The economics of digitization is the field of economics that studies how digitization, digitalisation and digital transformation affects markets and how digital data can be used to study economics. Digitization is the process by which technology lowers the costs of storing, sharing, and analyzing data. This has changed how consumers behave, how industrial activity is organized, and how governments operate. The economics of digitization exists as a distinct field of economics for two reasons. First, new economic models are needed because many traditional assumptions about information no longer hold in a digitized world. Second, the new types of data generated by digitization require new methods for their analysis.

Contents

Research in the economics of digitization touches on several fields of economics including industrial organization, labor economics, and intellectual property. Consequently, many of the contributions to the economics of digitization have also found an intellectual home in these fields. An underlying theme in much of the work in the field is that existing government regulation of copyright, security, and antitrust is inappropriate in the modern world. For example, information goods, such as news articles and movies, now have zero marginal costs of production and sharing. This has made the redistribution without permission common and has increased competition between providers of information goods. Research in the economics of digitization studies how policy should adapt in response to these changes.

Information technology and access to networks

Technological standards

The Internet is a multi-layered network which is operated by a variety of participants. The Internet has come to mean a combination of standards, networks, and web applications (such as streaming and file-sharing), among other components, that have accumulated around networking technology. The emergence of the Internet coincided with the growth of a new type of organizational structure, the standards committee. [1] [2] Standards committees are responsible for designing critical standards for the Internet such as TCP/IP, HTML, and CSS. These committees are composed of representatives from firms, academia, and non-profit organizations. Their goal is to make decisions that advance technology while retaining interoperability between Internet components. Economists are interested in how these organizational structures make decisions and whether those decisions are optimal.

The supply of Internet access

The commercial supply of Internet access began when the National Science Foundation removed restrictions for using the Internet for commercial purposes. During the 90's internet access was provided by numerous regional and national Internet service providers (ISPs). However, by 2014, the provision of high-speed broadband access was consolidated. About 80% of Americans can only buy 25 Mbit/s from one provider and a majority only have a choice of two providers for 10 Mbit/s service. Economists are particularly interested by competition and network effects within this industry. [3] Furthermore, the availability of broadband may affect other economic outcomes such as the relative wages of skilled and unskilled workers. [4]

Demand for the Internet

A key issue in the economics of digitization is the economic value of Internet-based services. The motivation for this question is two-fold. First, economists are interested in understanding digitization related policies such as network infrastructure investment and subsidies for Internet access. Second, economists want to measure the gains to consumers from the Internet. The revenues of Internet Service Providers provided one direct measure of the growth in the Internet economy. [5] [6] This is an important topic because many economists believe that traditional measures of economic growth, such as GDP, understate the true benefits of improving technology. The modern digital economy also tends to lead to reliance on inputs with zero price. [7]

The effects of digitization on industrial organization

Platforms and online marketplaces

Digitization has coincided with the increased prominence of platforms and marketplaces that connect diverse agents in social and economic activity. A platform is defined by Bresnahan and Greenstein (1999) [8] as "a reconfigurable base of compatible components on which users build applications". Platforms are most readily identified with their technical standards, i.e., engineering specifications for hardware and standards for software. The pricing and product strategies that platforms use differ from those of traditional firms because of the presence of network effects. Network effects arise within platforms because participation by one group affects the utility of another group. Many online platforms replicate identical process or algorithms at virtually no cost, allowing them to scale the network effect without encountering diminishing returns. Large scale network effects make the analysis of competition between platforms more complex than the analysis of competition between traditional firms. Much work in the economics of digitization studies the question of how these firms should operate and how they compete with each other. [9] [10] A particularly important issue is whether markets for online platforms have a tendency towards "winner-takes-all" competitive outcomes, and should be subject to antitrust actions.

Online platforms often drastically reduce transactions costs, especially in markets where the quality of a good or trading partner is uncertain. [11] For example, eBay drastically increased the market for used consumer goods by offering a search engine, reputation system, and other services that make trade less risky. Other online marketplaces of this type include Airbnb for accommodations, Prosper for lending, and Odesk for labor. Economists are interested in quantifying the gains from these marketplaces and studying how they should be designed. For example, eBay, Odesk, and other marketplaces have adapted the use of auctions as a selling mechanisms. This has prompted a large literature on the comparative advantages of selling goods via auction versus using a fixed price. [12] [13] [14] [15]

User-generated content and open source production

Digitization has coincided with the production of software and content by users who are not directly compensated for their work. Furthermore, those goods are typically distributed for free on the Internet. Prominent examples of open-source software include the Apache HTTP Server, Mozilla Firefox, and the Linux operating system. Economists are interested in the incentives of users to produce this software and how this software either substitutes or complements existing production processes. [16] Another area of study is estimating the degree to which GDP and other measures of economic activity are mis-measured due to open source software. For example, Greenstein and Nagle (2014) [17] estimate that Apache alone accounts for a mis-measurement between $2 billion and $12 billion.

In addition, open source production can be used for hardware, known as open hardware, normally by sharing digital designs such as CAD files. [18] Sharing of open hardware designs can generate significant value because of the ability to digitally replicate products for approximately the cost of materials using technologies such as 3D printers. [19] [20]

Another active area of research studies the incentives to produce user-generated content such as Wikipedia articles, digital videos, blogs, podcasts, etc. For example, Zhang and Zhu (2011) [21] show that Wikipedia contributors are motivated by the social interaction with other contributors. Greenstein and Zhu (2012) [22] show that while many Wikipedia articles exhibit slant, the overall level of slant across articles on Wikipedia has diminished over time.

Advertising

Advertising is an important source of revenue for information goods, both online and offline. Given the prevalence of advertising-supported information goods online, it is important to understand how online advertising works. Economists have spent much effort in trying to quantify the returns to online advertising. One especially interesting aspect of online advertising is its ability to target customers using fine demographic and behavioral data. [23] This ability potentially affects the ability of new and small firms to gain exposure to customers and to grow. Targeted advertising is controversial because it sometimes uses private data about individuals obtained through third-party sources. Quantifying the costs and benefits of using this type of data is an active research area in the field.

The effects of digitization on consumer choice

Search, search engines and recommendation systems

Perhaps the oldest and largest stream of research on the Internet and market frictions emphasizes reduced search costs. This literature builds on an older theory literature in economics [24] [25] [26] that examines how search costs affect prices. Digitization of retail and marketing meant that consumers could easily compare prices across stores, so the empirical work on Internet pricing examined the impact on prices and price dispersion. Initially hypothesized by Bakos (1997), [27] the first wave of this research empirically documented lower prices, but still substantial dispersion. [28] [29] [30]

The newest wave of this research collects data about online searches to examine the actual search process that consumers undertake when looking for a product online. [31] [32] This question also emphasizes that the final stage of purchase is often controlled by a more familiar retail environment, and it raises questions about the growing importance of standards and platforms in the distribution of creative content.

As noted earlier, near-zero marginal costs of distribution for information goods might change where and how information goods get consumed. Geographic boundaries might be less important if information can travel long distances for free. [33] [34] [35] One open question concerns the incidence of the impact of low distribution costs. The benefits might vary by location, with locations with fewer offline options generating a larger benefit from digitization. [36] [37]

Furthermore, online retailers of digital goods can carry many more products and never worry about running out of inventory. Even if a song only sells a handful of times, it is still profitable to be offered for sale on the Internet. At the same time, the zero marginal costs of distribution mean that top-selling (superstar) items never go out of stock and therefore can achieve even higher sales (Anderson, 2006). Several papers in the literature attempt to quantify the economic impact of increased product variety made available through electronic markets. [38] [39] Bar-Isaac et al. (2012) [40] derive a theory of when lower search costs will result in 'superstar' and 'long-tail' effects.

Reputation systems

One particularly important aspect of digitization for consumers is the increased use of reputation systems on retail websites and online marketplaces. Sixty-eight percent of respondents in a 2013 Nielsen survey said that they trusted online reviews. Numerous papers have shown that these review systems affect consumer demand for restaurants [41] books, [42] and hotels. A key area of research in digitization studies whether online reputations accurately reveal both the vertical and horizontal quality of a good. For example, Forman et al. (2008) [43] show that local reviews have more effect than reviews from distant reviewers, suggesting that reviews provide information about both vertical and horizontal differentiation. On the other hand, several show that online review are biased because not everyone leaves reviews, [44] because reviewers are afraid of retaliation, [45] and because sellers may promote their own products using the review system. [46] Newer research proposes designs for reputation systems that more efficiently aggregate information about the experiences of users. [47]

The effects of digitization on labor markets

Digitization has partially or fully replaced many tasks that were previously done by human laborers. At the same time, computers have made some workers much more productive. Economists are interested in understanding how these two forces interact in determining labor market outcomes. For example, a large literature studies the magnitude and causes of skill-biased technical change, the process by which technology improves wages for educated workers. Alternatively, Autor (2014) [48] describes a framework for classifying jobs into those more or less prone to replacement by computers. Furthermore, the use of information technology only increases productivity when it's complemented by organization changes. For example, Garicano and Heation (2010) [49] show that IT increases the productivity of police departments only when those police departments increased training and expanded support personnel. Work by Bresnahan, Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2002) [50] found evidence of organizational complementarities with information technology and boosted the demand for skilled labor.

Another consequence of digitization is that it has drastically reduced the costs of communication between workers across different organizations and locations. This has led to a change in the geographic and contractual organization of production. Economists are interested in the magnitude of this change and its effect on local labor markets. A recent study found that the potential of manufacturing sector jobs to be offshored did not reduce wages in the US. However, survey evidence suggests that 25% of American jobs are potentially offshorable in the future. [51]

Online labor market platforms like Odesk and Amazon Mechanical Turk represent a particularly interesting form of labor production arising out of digitization. Economists who study these platforms are interested in how they compete with or complement more traditional firms. Another active area of research is how to incentivize workers on these platforms to produce more efficiently. [52] While workers engaged in routine, lower-skill tasks such as data entry are particularly susceptible to competition from online labor markets, creative professions are also exposed, as many online platforms now provide opportunities to crowdsource creative work.

Government policy and digitization

Intellectual property and digitization

One main area of policy interest related to digitization concerns intellectual property. The justification for giving copyright and patent right relies on the theory that the potential to gain these rights encourages the production and sharing of intellectual property. However, digitization and ease of copying has made it difficult to defend intellectual property rights, especially in the case of copyright. Varian (2005) [53] supplies a theoretical framework for thinking about this change from an economics perspective. Usually, the economic effect on copyright-holders in the context of free copying is considered to be negative. However, Varian suggests an important counter-argument. If the value a consumer puts on the right to copy is greater than the reduction in sales, a seller can increase profits by allowing that right. Varian also provides a detailed description of several business models which potentially address the greater difficulty of enforcing copyrights as digitization increases. Alternative business models for intellectual property holders include selling complementary goods, subscriptions, personalization, and advertising.

Empirical research in this area studies the effects of Internet file-sharing on the supply and demand for paid content. For example, Danaher et al. 2010 [54] show that the removal of NBC content from iTunes increased the illicit copying of NBC shows by 11.4%. This result shows that licensed and unlicensed content are substitutes. Giorcelli and Moser (2014) [55] show that the spread of copyright in Italy between 1770 and 1900 increased the production of new and better operas. Still, there is little work on how these empirical results should inform copyright rules and security practices.

Net neutrality

Privacy, security, and digitization

Privacy and data security is an area where digitization has substantially changed the costs and benefits to various economic actors. Traditional policies regarding privacy circumscribed the ability of government agencies to access individual data. However, the large-scale ability of firms to collect, parse, and analyze detailed micro-level data about consumers has shifted the policy focus. Now, the concern is whether firms' access consumer data should be regulation and restricted. In the past decade, theoretical work on commercial privacy has tended to focus on behavioral price discrimination as being a potential application of a context where researchers can model privacy concerns from an economics perspective. [56] [57]

Goldfarb and Tucker (2011a) [58] wrote the first paper to empirically study the economic effects of privacy regulation for the advertising-supported Internet. The implementation of privacy regulation in Europe has made it more difficult for firms to collect and use consumer browsing data to target their ads more accurately; the field test data shows these policies are associated with a 65 percent reduction in the influence banner ads have on purchase intent. As well as this main effect, their research also suggests that privacy regulation might change the web landscape in unanticipated ways, with advertising becoming even more intrusive. It also might lead marketers to shift their media buys away from newspapers because of difficulties in finding relevant advertising to show.

Another related concern is what precautions should firms take to prevent data breaches such as those at Target and Staples. Arora et al. (2010) [59] models the firm's effort in securing data from an economics perspective. They find that direct competition reduces the time that a firm takes to patch a vulnerability to its software. Other attempts at measuring the consequences of information security policy from an economics perspective are Miller and Tucker (2011), [60] who look at policies mandating encryption, and Romanosky et al. (2011), [61] who look at mandatory breach notification laws.

Other issues

There are many other policies related to digitization that are of interest to economists. For example, digitization may affect government effectiveness and accountability. [62] Digitization also makes it easier for firms in one jurisdiction to supply consumers in another. This creates challenges for tax enforcement. [63] Another issue is that companies with new, Internet based business models, such as Airbnb and Uber, pose challenges for regulation aimed at traditional service providers. Many safety and quality enforcement regulations may no longer be necessary with the advent of online reputation systems. Lastly, digitization is of great importance to health care policy. For example, electronic medical records have the potential to make healthcare more effective but pose challenges to privacy policy. [64] [65]

Books

In May 2015 the National Bureau of Economic Research published a book with University of Chicago Press entitled "Economic Analysis of the Digital Economy." The editors for the book are Avi Goldfarb, Shane Greenstein, and Catherine Tucker. The volume brings together leading scholars to explore this emerging area of research. [66] This follows on a book that collected twenty-five important articles in the area, published by Edward Elgar Publishing, titled "Economics of Digitization." [67]

See also

Related Research Articles

New Keynesian economics is a school of macroeconomics that strives to provide microeconomic foundations for Keynesian economics. It developed partly as a response to criticisms of Keynesian macroeconomics by adherents of new classical macroeconomics.

In psychology and behavioral economics, the endowment effect is the finding that people are more likely to retain an object they own than acquire that same object when they do not own it. The endowment theory can be defined as "an application of prospect theory positing that loss aversion associated with ownership explains observed exchange asymmetries."

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Mental accounting</span>

Mental accounting is a model of consumer behaviour developed by Richard Thaler that attempts to describe the process whereby people code, categorize and evaluate economic outcomes. Mental accounting incorporates the economic concepts of prospect theory and transactional utility theory to evaluate how people create distinctions between their financial resources in the form of mental accounts, which in turn impacts the buyer decision process and reaction to economic outcomes. People are presumed to make mental accounts as a self control strategy to manage and keep track of their spending and resources. People budget money into mental accounts for savings or expense categories. People also are assumed to make mental accounts to facilitate savings for larger purposes. Mental accounting can result in people demonstrating greater loss aversion for certain mental accounts, resulting in cognitive bias that incentivizes systematic departures from consumer rationality. Through increased understanding of mental accounting differences in decision making based on different resources, and different reactions based on similar outcomes can be greater understood.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Sendhil Mullainathan</span> American Professor of Computation and Behavioral science

Sendhil Mullainathan is an American professor of Computation and Behavioral Science at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business and the author of Scarcity: Why Having Too Little Means So Much. He was hired with tenure by Harvard in 2004 after having spent six years at MIT.

User innovation refers to innovation by intermediate users or consumer users, rather than by suppliers. This is a concept closely aligned to co-design and co-creation, and has been proven to result in more innovative solutions than traditional consultation methodologies.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Market sentiment</span> General attitude of investors to market price development

Market sentiment, also known as investor attention, is the general prevailing attitude of investors as to anticipated price development in a market. This attitude is the accumulation of a variety of fundamental and technical factors, including price history, economic reports, seasonal factors, and national and world events. If investors expect upward price movement in the stock market, the sentiment is said to be bullish. On the contrary, if the market sentiment is bearish, most investors expect downward price movement. Market participants who maintain a static sentiment, regardless of market conditions, are described as permabulls and permabears respectively. Market sentiment is usually considered as a contrarian indicator: what most people expect is a good thing to bet against. Market sentiment is used because it is believed to be a good predictor of market moves, especially when it is more extreme. Very bearish sentiment is usually followed by the market going up more than normal, and vice versa. A bull market refers to a sustained period of either realized or expected price rises, whereas a bear market is used to describe when an index or stock has fallen 20% or more from a recent high for a sustained length of time.

A two-sided market, also called a two-sided network, is an intermediary economic platform having two distinct user groups that provide each other with network benefits. The organization that creates value primarily by enabling direct interactions between two distinct types of affiliated customers is called a multi-sided platform. This concept of two-sided markets has been mainly theorised by the French economists Jean Tirole and Jean-Charles Rochet and Americans Geoffrey G Parker and Marshall Van Alstyne.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Susan Athey</span> American economist

Susan Carleton Athey is an American economist. She is the Economics of Technology Professor in the School of Humanities and Sciences at the Stanford Graduate School of Business. Prior to joining Stanford, she has been a professor at Harvard University and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. She is the first female winner of the John Bates Clark Medal. She served as the consulting chief economist for Microsoft for six years and was a consulting researcher to Microsoft Research. She is currently on the boards of Expedia, Lending Club, Rover, Turo, Ripple, and non-profit Innovations for Poverty Action. She also serves as the senior fellow at Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research. She is an associate director for the Stanford Institute for Human-Centered Artificial Intelligence and the director of Golub Capital Social Impact Lab.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Targeted advertising</span> Form of advertising

Targeted advertising is a form of advertising, including online advertising, that is directed towards an audience with certain traits, based on the product or person the advertiser is promoting.

Search costs are a facet of transaction costs or switching costs and include all the costs associated with the searching activity conducted by a prospective seller and buyer in a market. Rational consumers will continue to search for a better product or service until the marginal cost of searching exceeds the marginal benefit. Search theory is a branch of microeconomics that studies decisions of this type.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Arun Sundararajan</span> American economist

Arun Sundararajan is the NEC Faculty Fellow, Professor of Technology, Operations, and Statistics and a Doctoral Coordinator at the Stern School of Business, New York University. For 2010–12, he is the Distinguished Academic Fellow at the Center for IT and the Networked Economy, Indian School of Business. Sundararajan is an expert on the economics of digital goods and network effects. He also conducts research about network science and the socioeconomic transformation of India.

Catherine Tucker is the Sloan Distinguished Professor of Management at MIT Sloan, where she is also chair of the PhD program. She is known for her research into the consequences of digital data for electronic privacy, algorithmic bias, digital health, social media and online advertising. She is also a research associate at the NBER, cofounder of the Cryptoeconomics lab at MIT with Christian Catalini and coeditor at Quantitative Marketing Economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Uri Gneezy</span> Israeli-American behavioral economist

Uri Hezkia Gneezy is an Israeli-American behavioral economist, known for his work on incentives. He currently holds the Epstein/Atkinson Endowed Chair in Behavioral Economics at the University of California, San Diego's Rady School of Management. He is also a visiting research professor at the University of Amsterdam and NHH in Bergen.

Marianne Bertrand is a Belgian economist who currently works as Chris P. Dialynas Distinguished Service Professor of Economics and Willard Graham Faculty Scholar at the University of Chicago's Booth School of Business. Bertrand belongs to the world's most prominent labour economists in terms of research, and has been awarded the 2004 Elaine Bennett Research Prize and the 2012 Sherwin Rosen Prize for Outstanding Contributions in the Field of Labor Economics. She is a research fellow of the National Bureau of Economic Research, and the IZA Institute of Labor Economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Rachel Griffith</span> British economist (born 1963)

Dame Rachel Susan Griffith is a British-American academic and educator. She is professor of economics at the University of Manchester and a research director at the Institute for Fiscal Studies.

The Exeter Prize is an economics prize of the University of Exeter Business School, which has been awarded since 2012. The Exeter Prize is awarded to the best paper published in the previous calendar year in a peer-reviewed journal in the fields of Experimental Economics, Decision Theory and Behavioural Economics.

Economists and marketers use the Search, Experience, Credence (SEC) classification of goods and services, which is based on the ease or difficulty with which consumers can evaluate or obtain information. These days most economics and marketers treat the three classes of goods as a continuum. Archetypal goods are:

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Christian Catalini</span>

Christian Catalini is a co-creator of Diem, the Chief Economist of the Diem Association, and the Theodore T. Miller Professor at the MIT Sloan School of Management.

Ravi Bapna is an Indian-born American data scientist, digital transformationalist, business academic, executive educator and speaker. He is the Curtis L. Carlson Chair in Business Analytics and Information Systems, the Associate Dean for Executive Education and the Academic Director of the Carlson Analytics Lab and the Analytics for Good Institute at the University of Minnesota’s Carlson School of Management.

Alok Gupta is an American information scientist, economic engineer, and academic. He is the Professor of Information and Decision, a Senior Associate Dean of Faculty, Research and Administration, and Curtis L. Carlson School Wide Chair in Information Management in the Carlson School of Management at the University of Minnesota.

References

  1. Mowery, D. and Simcoe, T. 2002. The Origins and Evolution of the Internet, in R. Nelson, B. Steil and D. Victor (eds), Technological Innovation and Economic Performance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 229–64.
  2. Simcoe, T (2012). "Standard Setting Committees: Consensus Governance for Shared Technology Platforms". American Economic Review. 102 (1): 305–336. doi:10.1257/aer.102.1.305.
  3. Downes, T.; Greenstein, S. (2002). "Universal access and local Internet markets in the U.S.". Research Policy. 31 (7): 1035–52. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.509.7345 . doi:10.1016/s0048-7333(01)00177-9.
  4. Akerman, Anders & Gaarder, Ingvil & Mogstad, Magne, 2013. "The Skill Complementarity of Broadband Internet," IZA Discussion Papers 7762, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).
  5. Greenstein, S.; McDevitt, R. (2011). "The broadband bonus: estimating broadband Internet's economic value". Telecommunications Policy. 35 (7): 617–32. doi:10.1016/j.telpol.2011.05.001.
  6. Gregory, Rosston; Savage, Scott J.; Waldman, Donald M. (2010). "Household Demand for Broadband Internet in 2010". The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy.
  7. Greenstein, S.; Nagle, F. (2014). "Digital Dark Matter and the Economic Contribution of Apache". Research Policy. 43 (4): 623–631. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2014.01.003. S2CID   14947451.
  8. Bresnahan, T.; Greenstein, S. (1999). "Technological Competition and the Structure of the Computing Industry". Journal of Industrial Economics. 47 (1): 1–40. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.598.252 . doi:10.1111/1467-6451.00088.
  9. Rochet, Jean-Charles; Tirole, Jean (2003). "Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets". Journal of the European Economic Association. 1 (4): 990–1029. doi: 10.1162/154247603322493212 .
  10. Weyl, E. Glen (2010). "A Price Theory of Multi-sided Platforms". American Economic Review. 100 (4): 1642–70. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.212.3377 . doi:10.1257/aer.100.4.1642. S2CID   154969943.
  11. Douma & Schreuder, Economic Approaches to Organizations, 6th edition. Harlow: Pearson
  12. Bajari, P. and A. Hortaçsu. 2003. The winner's curse, reserve prices, and endogenous entry: empirical insights from eBay auctions. RAND Journal of Economics, 34 (2, Summer), 329–55.
  13. Bajari, P.; Hortaçsu, A. (2004). "Economic insights from Internet auctions". Journal of Economic Literature. 42 (2): 457–86. doi:10.1257/0022051041409075.
  14. Lucking-Reiley, D (2000). "Auctions on the Internet: what's being auctioned, and how?". Journal of Industrial Economics. 48 (3): 227–52. doi:10.1111/1467-6451.00122.
  15. Einav, Liran and Farronato, Chiara and Levin, Jonathan and Sundaresan, Neel, Sales Mechanisms in Online Markets: What Happened to Internet Auctions? (May 2013). NBER Working Paper No. w19021.
  16. Athey, S.; Ellison, G. (2014). "Dynamics of Open Source Movements". Journal of Economics & Management Strategy. 23 (2): 294–316. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.186.3077 . doi:10.1111/jems.12053. S2CID   16593183.
  17. Greenstein, Shane; Nagle, Frank (2014). "Digital dark matter and the economic contribution of Apache". Research Policy. 43 (4): 623–631. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2014.01.003. S2CID   14947451.
  18. "What is open hardware?". opensource.com. Retrieved 2 September 2016.
  19. Tankersle, Stephanie. "Measuring the value of open hardware design" . Retrieved 8 September 2016.
  20. "Science for All: How to Make Free, Open Source Laboratory Hardware". Scientific American. Retrieved 8 September 2016.
  21. Zhang, X; Zhu, F (2011). "Group Size and Incentives to Contribute: A Natural Experiment at Chinese Wikipedia". American Economic Review. 101 (4): 1601–1615. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.306.9615 . doi:10.1257/aer.101.4.1601. S2CID   54225955.
  22. Greenstein, S.; Zhu, F. (2012). "Is Wikipedia Biased?". The American Economic Review. 102 (3): 343–348. doi:10.1257/aer.102.3.343. S2CID   15747824.
  23. Goldfarb, Avi; Tucker, Catherine (2011a). "Advertising Bans and the Substitutability of Online and Offline Advertising". Journal of Marketing Research. 48 (2): 207–228. doi:10.1509/jmkr.48.2.207. hdl: 1721.1/68636 . S2CID   15165833.
  24. Stigler, George J (1961). "The Economics of Information". Journal of Political Economy. 69 (3): 213–225. doi:10.1086/258464. S2CID   42724549.
  25. Diamond, P (1971). "A simple model of price adjustment". Journal of Economic Theory. 3 (2): 156–68. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(71)90013-5.
  26. Varian, H (1980). "A model of sales". American Economic Review. 70: 651–9.
  27. Bakos, J (1997). "Reducing buyer search costs: implications for electronic marketplaces". Management Science. 43 (12): 1676–92. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.3.3579 . doi:10.1287/mnsc.43.12.1676.
  28. Brynjolfsson, Erik; Yu (2003). "Jeffrey" Hu, Michael D. Smith. 2003. Consumer Surplus in the Digital Economy: Estimating the Value of Increased Product Variety" (PDF). Management Science. 49 (11): 1580–1596. doi:10.1287/mnsc.49.11.1580.20580. hdl: 1721.1/3516 .
  29. Baye, Michael; Morgan, John; Scholten, Patrick (2004). "Price Dispersion in the Small and in the Large: Evidence from an Internet Price Comparison Site". Journal of Industrial Economics. 52 (4): 463–96. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.143.6265 . doi:10.1111/j.0022-1821.2004.00236.x. S2CID   16528628.
  30. Ellison, G.; Ellison, S.F. (2009). "Search, obfuscation, and price elasticities on the Internet" (PDF). Econometrica. 77 (2): 427–452. doi:10.3982/ecta5708. hdl:1721.1/64305.
  31. Baye, Michael R., Babur de los Santos, Matthijs R. Wildenbeest, 2013. Searching for Physical and Digital Media: The Evolution of Platforms for Finding Books, in A. Goldfarb, S. Greenstein and C. Tucker, Economics of Digitization: An Agenda. National Bureau of Economic Research.
  32. Fradkin, Andrey. 2014. Search Frictions and the Design of Online Marketplaces. Working paper, Stanford University.
  33. Sunstein, C. 2001. Republic.com. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  34. Sinai, T.; Waldfogel, J. (2004). "Geography and the Internet: Is the Internet a substitute or a complement for cities?" (PDF). Journal of Urban Economics. 56 (1): 1–24. arXiv: cs/0109061 . doi:10.1016/j.jue.2004.04.001. S2CID   3266570.
  35. Blum; Goldfarb, Avi (2006). "Does the Internet Defy the Law of Gravity?". Journal of International Economics. 70 (2): 384–405. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.454.6381 . doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2005.10.002. S2CID   28234465.
  36. Forman, C.; Ghose, A.; Wiesenfeld, B. (2008). "Examining the relationship between reviews and sales: the role of reviewer identity disclosure in electronic markets". Information Systems Research. 19 (3): 291–313. doi:10.1287/isre.1080.0193. S2CID   10239832.
  37. Goldfarb, Avi; Tucker, Catherine (2011a). "Advertising Bans and the Substitutability of Online and Offline Advertising". Journal of Marketing Research. 48 (2): 207–228. doi:10.1509/jmkr.48.2.207. hdl: 1721.1/68636 . S2CID   15165833.
  38. Brynjolfsson, Erik; Yu (2003). "Jeffrey" Hu, Michael D. Smith. 2003. Consumer Surplus in the Digital Economy: Estimating the Value of Increased Product Variety" (PDF). Management Science. 49 (11): 1580–1596. doi:10.1287/mnsc.49.11.1580.20580. hdl: 1721.1/3516 .
  39. Luis Aguiar and Joel Waldfogel. Panning for Gold: The Random Long Tail in Music Production
  40. Bar-Isaac, H.; Caruana, G.; Cunat, V. (2012). "Search, design, and market structure". American Economic Review. 102 (2): 1140–60. doi:10.1257/aer.102.2.1140.
  41. Luca, Michael. 2013. "Reviews, Reputation, and Revenue: The Case of Yelp.com." HBS Working Knowledge.
  42. Chevalier, J.; Mayzlin, D. (2006). "The effect of word of mouth on sales: online book reviews". Journal of Marketing Research. 43 (3): 345–54. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.320.483 . doi:10.1509/jmkr.43.3.345. S2CID   8730789.
  43. Forman, C.; Ghose, A.; Wiesenfeld, B. (2008). "Examining the relationship between reviews and sales: the role of reviewer identity disclosure in electronic markets". Information Systems Research. 19 (3): 291–313. doi:10.1287/isre.1080.0193. S2CID   10239832.
  44. Dellarocas, Chrysanthos; Wood, Charles A. (2007). "The Sound of Silence in Online Feedback: Estimating Trading Risks in the Presence of Reporting Bias". Management Science. 54 (3): 460–476. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1070.0747.
  45. Bolton, Gary; Greiner, Ben; Ockenfels, Axel (2012). "Engineering Trust: Reciprocity in the Production of Reputation Information" (PDF). Management Science. 59 (2): 265–285. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1120.1609.
  46. Mayzlin, Dina; Dover, Yaniv; Chevalier, Judith (2014). "Promotional Reviews: An Em- pirical Investigation of Online Review Manipulation" (PDF). American Economic Review. 104 (8): 2421–2455. doi:10.1257/aer.104.8.2421. S2CID   202253473.
  47. Bolton, Gary; Greiner, Ben; Ockenfels, Axel (2012). "Engineering Trust: Reciprocity in the Production of Reputation Information" (PDF). Management Science. 59 (2): 265–285. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1120.1609.
  48. Autor, David, Polanyi's Paradox and the Shape of Employment Growth (September 2014). NBER Working Paper No. w20485.
  49. Garicano, Luis; Heaton, Paul (2010). "Information Technology, Organization, and Productivity in the Public Sector: Evidence from Police Departments". Journal of Labor Economics. 28 (1): 167–201. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.188.7970 . doi:10.1086/649844. S2CID   5372068.
  50. Bresnahan, Tim; Brynjolfsson, Erik; Hitt, Lorin (2003). "Information Technology, Workplace Organization, and the Demand for Skilled Labor: Firm-Level Evidence". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 117 (1): 339–376. doi:10.1162/003355302753399526.
  51. Blinder, Alan S.; Krueger, Alan B. (2013). "Alternative Measures of Offshorability: A Survey Approach" (PDF). Journal of Labor Economics. 31 (S1): S97–S128. doi:10.1086/669061. S2CID   154674537.
  52. Agrawal, Ajay, John Horton, Nico Lacetera, Elizabeth Lyons. 2013. Digitization and the Contract Labor Market: A Research Agenda, in A. Goldfarb, S. Greenstein and C. Tucker, Economics of Digitization: An Agenda. National Bureau of Economic Research.
  53. Varian, H (2005). "Copying and Copyright". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 19 (2): 121–138. doi: 10.1257/0895330054048768 .
  54. Danaher, Brett, Samita Dhanasobhon, Michael D. Smith, Rahul Telang. 2013. Understanding Media Markets in the Digital Age: Economics and Methodology, in A. Goldfarb, S. Greenstein and C. Tucker, Economics of Digitization: An Agenda. National Bureau of Economic Research.
  55. Giorcelli, Michela and Moser, Petra, Copyright and Creativity: Evidence from Italian Operas (November 15, 2014).
  56. Acquisti, A.; Varian, H. R. (2005). "Conditioning prices on purchase history". Marketing Science. 24 (3): 367–81. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.418.8722 . doi:10.1287/mksc.1040.0103.
  57. Fudenburg, D. and J. M. Villas-Boas. 2006. ‘Behavior Based Price Discrimination and Customer Recognition,’ in T. Hendershott (ed.), Economics and Information Systems, Bingley, UK: Emerald Group Publishing, pp. 377–435.
  58. Goldfarb, Avi; Tucker, Catherine (2011b). "Privacy Regulation and Online Advertising". Management Science. 57 (1): 57–71. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1100.1246. hdl: 1721.1/64920 .
  59. Arora; Nandkumar, A. A; Forman, C; Telang, R (2010). "Competition and Patching of Security Vulnerabilities: An Empirical Analysis". Information Economics and Policy. 10 (2): 164–177. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.165.4803 . doi:10.1016/j.infoecopol.2009.10.002.
  60. Miller, A.; Tucker, C. (2011). "Encryption and the loss of patient data" (PDF). Journal of Policy Analysis and Management. 30 (3): 534–56. doi:10.1002/pam.20590. hdl: 1721.1/75854 . PMID   21774164.
  61. Romanosky, S.; Telang, R.; Acquisti, A. (2011). "Do data breach disclosure laws reduce identity theft?". Journal of Policy Analysis and Management. 30 (2): 256–86. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.304.2975 . doi:10.1002/pam.20567.
  62. Muralidharan, Karthik, Paul Niehaus, and Sandip Sukhtankar. "Building State Capacity: Evidence from Biometric Smartcards in India." NBER Working Paper No. 19999, October 2014.
  63. Einav, Liran; Knoepfle, Dan; Levin, Jonathan; Sundaresan, Neel (2014). "Sales Taxes and Internet Commerce" (PDF). American Economic Review. 104 (1): 1–26. doi:10.1257/aer.104.1.1. S2CID   6760482.
  64. Miller, A.; Tucker, C. (2009). "Privacy protection and technology diffusion: the case of electronic medical records" (PDF). Management Science. 55 (7): 1077–93. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1090.1014.
  65. Miller, A.; Tucker, C. (2011). "Encryption and the loss of patient data" (PDF). Journal of Policy Analysis and Management. 30 (3): 534–56. doi:10.1002/pam.20590. hdl: 1721.1/75854 . PMID   21774164.
  66. Goldfarb, Avi, Shane Greenstein, and Catherine Tucker. 2015. Economic Analysis of the Digital Economy. University of Chicago Press. Chicago. IL.
  67. Greenstein, Shane, Avi Goldfarb, and Catherine Tucker. 2013. Economics of Digitization (International Library of Critical Writings in Economics series, #280). Edward Elgar Publishing.