Market power

Last updated

In economics, market power refers to the ability of a firm to influence the price at which it sells a product or service by manipulating either the supply or demand of the product or service to increase economic profit. [1] In other words, market power occurs if a firm does not face a perfectly elastic demand curve and can set its price (P) above marginal cost (MC) without losing revenue. [2] This indicates that the magnitude of market power is associated with the gap between P and MC at a firm's profit maximising level of output. The size of the gap, which encapsulates the firm's level of market dominance, is determined by the residual demand curve's form. A steeper reverse demand indicates higher earnings and more dominance in the market. [2] Such propensities contradict perfectly competitive markets, where market participants have no market power, P = MC and firms earn zero economic profit. [3] Market participants in perfectly competitive markets are consequently referred to as 'price takers', whereas market participants that exhibit market power are referred to as 'price makers' or 'price setters'.

Contents

The market power of any individual firm is controlled by multiple factors, including but not limited to, their size, the structure of the market they are involved in, and the barriers to entry for the particular market. A firm with market power has the ability to individually affect either the total quantity or price in the market. This said, market power has been seen to exert more upward pressure on prices due to effects relating to Nash equilibria and profitable deviations that can be made by raising prices. [4] Price makers face a downward-sloping demand curve and as a result, price increases lead to a lower quantity demanded. The decrease in supply creates an economic deadweight loss (DWL) and a decline in consumer surplus. [5] This is viewed as socially undesirable and has implications for welfare and resource allocation as larger firms with high markups negatively effect labour markets by providing lower wages. [5] Perfectly competitive markets do not exhibit such issues as firms set prices that reflect costs, which is to the benefit of the customer. As a result, many countries have antitrust or other legislation intended to limit the ability of firms to accrue market power. Such legislation often regulates mergers and sometimes introduces a judicial power to compel divestiture.

Market power provides firms with the ability to engage in unilateral anti-competitive behavior. [6] As a result, legislation recognises that firms with market power can, in some circumstances, damage the competitive process. In particular, firms with market power are accused of limit pricing, predatory pricing, holding excess capacity and strategic bundling. [7] A firm usually has market power by having a high market share although this alone is not sufficient to establish the possession of significant market power. This is because highly concentrated markets may be contestable if there are no barriers to entry or exit. Invariably, this limits the incumbent firm's ability to raise its price above competitive levels.

If no individual participant in the market has significant market power, anti-competitive conduct can only take place through collusion, or the exercise of a group of participants' collective market power. [4] An example of which was seen in 2007, when British Airways was found to have colluded with Virgin Atlantic between 2004 and 2006, increasing their surcharges per ticket from £5 to £60. [8]

Regulators are able to assess the level of market power and dominance a firm has and measure competition through the use of several tools and indicators. Although market power is extremely difficult to measure, through the use of widely used analytical techniques such as concentration ratios, the Herfindahl-Hirschman index and the Lerner index, regulators are able to oversee and attempt to restore market competitiveness. [9]

Market structure

Different types of market structures Market Structures .jpg
Different types of market structures

In economics, market structure can profoundly affect the behavior and financial performance of firms. [10] Market structure depicts how different industries are characterized and differentiated based upon the types of goods the firms sell (homogenous/heterogenous) and the nature of competition within the industry. [11] The degree of market power firms assert in different markets are relative to the market structure that the firms operate in. There are four main forms of market structures that are observed: perfect competition, monopolistic competition, oligopoly, and monopoly. [11] Perfect competition and monopoly represent the two extremes of market structure, respectively. Monopolistic competition and oligopoly exist in between these two extremes. [10]

Perfect competition power

"Perfect Competition" refers to a market structure that is devoid of any barriers or interference and describes those marketplaces where neither corporations nor consumers are powerful enough to affect pricing. In terms of economics, it is one of the many conventional market forms and the optimal condition of market competition. [12] The concept of perfect competition represents a theoretical market structure where the market reaches an equilibrium that is Pareto optimal. This occurs when the quantity supplied by sellers in the market equals the quantity demanded by buyers in the market at the current price. [13] Firms competing in a perfectly competitive market faces a market price that is equal to their marginal cost, therefore, no economic profits are present. The following criteria need to be satisfied in a perfectly competitive market:

  1. Producers sell homogenous goods
  2. All firms are price takers
  3. Perfect information
  4. No barriers to enter and exit
  5. All firms have relatively small market share and cannot influence price

As all firms in the market are price takers, they essentially hold zero market power and must accept the price given by the market. A perfectly competitive market is logically impossible to achieve in a real world scenario as it embodies contradiction in itself and therefore is considered an idealised framework by economists. [14]

Monopolistic competition power

Monopolistic competition can be described as the "middle ground" between perfect competition and a monopoly as it shares elements present in both market structures that are on different ends of the market structure spectrum. [15] Monopolistic competition is a type of market structure defined by many producers that are competing against each other by selling similar goods which are differentiated, thus are not perfect substitutes. [16] In the short term, firms are able to obtain economic profits as a result of differentiated goods providing sellers with some degree of market power; however, profits approaches zero as more competitive toughness increases in the industry. [17] The main characteristics of monopolistic competition include:

  1. Differentiated products
  2. Many sellers and buyers
  3. Free entry and exit

Firms within this market structure are not price takers and compete based on product price, quality and through marketing efforts, setting individual prices for the unique differentiated products. [18] Examples of industries with monopolistic competition include restaurants, hairdressers and clothing.

Monopoly power

The word monopoly is used in various instances referring to a single seller of a product, a producer with an overwhelming level of market share, or refer to a large firm. [19] All of these treatments have one unifying factor which is the ability to influence the market price by altering the supply of the good or service through its own production decisions. The most discussed form of market power is that of a monopoly, but other forms such as monopsony and more moderate versions of these extremes exist. A monopoly is considered a 'market failure' and consists of one firm that produces a unique product or service without close substitutes. Whilst pure monopolies are rare, monopoly power is far more common and can be seen in many industries even with more than one supplier in the market. [20] Firms with monopoly power can charge a higher price for products (higher markup) as demand is relatively inelastic. [21] They also see a falling rate of labour share as firms divest from expensive inputs such as labour. [22] Often, firms with monopoly power exist in industries with high barriers to entry, which include, but are not limited to:

  1. Economies of scale
  2. Predatory pricing [20]
  3. Control of key resources (required in production of the good)
  4. Legal regulations [21]

A well-known example of monopolistic market power is Microsoft's market share in PC operating systems. The United States v. Microsoft case dealt with an allegation that Microsoft illegally exercised its market power by bundling its web browser with its operating system. In this respect, the notion of dominance and dominant position in EU Antitrust Law is a strictly related aspect. [23]

Oligopoly power

Another form of market power is that of an oligopoly or oligopsony. Within this market structure, the market is highly concentrated and several firms control a significant share of market sales. [24] The emergence of oligopoly market forms is mainly attributed to the monopoly of market competition, i.e., the market monopoly acquired by enterprises through their competitive advantages, and the administrative monopoly due to government regulations, such as when the government grants monopoly power to an enterprise in the industry through laws and regulations and at the same time imposes certain controls on it to improve efficiency. [25] The main characteristics of an oligopoly are:

  1. A few sellers and many buyers.
  2. Homogenous or differentiated products.
  3. High barriers to entry. This includes, but is not limited to, 'technology challenges, government regulations, patents, start-up costs, or education and licensing requirements'. [26]
  4. Interaction/strategic behaviour.

It is salient to note that only a few firms make up the market share. Hence, their market power is large as a collective and each firm has little or no market power independently. [27] For firms trying to enter these industries, unless they can start with a large production scale and capture a significant market share, the high average costs will make it impossible for them to compete with the existing firms. [28] Generally, when a firm operating in an oligopolistic market adjusts prices, other firms in the industry will be directly impacted.

The graph below depicts the kinked demand curve hypothesis which was proposed by Paul Sweezy who was an American economist. [29] It is important to note that this graph is a simplistic example of a kinked demand curve.

Kinked Demand Curve KinkedDemandCurve.gif
Kinked Demand Curve

Oligopolistic firms are believed to operate within the confines of the kinked demand function. This means that when firms set prices above the prevailing price level (P*), prices are relatively elastic because individuals are likely to switch to a competitor's product as a substitute. Prices below P* are believed to be relatively inelastic as competitive firms are likely to mimic the change in prices, meaning less gains are experienced by the firm. [30]

An oligopoly may engage in collusion, either tacit or overt to exercise market power and manipulate prices to control demand and revenue for a collection of firms. A group of firms that explicitly agree to affect market price or output is called a cartel, with the organization of petroleum-exporting countries (OPEC) being one of the most well known example of an international cartel.

Sources of market power

By remaining consistent with the strict definition of market power as any firm with a positive Lerner index, the sources of market power is derived from distinctiveness of the good and or seller. [31] For a monopolist, distinctiveness is a necessary condition that needs to be satisfied but this is just the starting point. Without barriers to entries, above normal profits experienced by monopolists would not persist as other sellers of homogenous or similar goods would continue to enter the industry until above normal profits are diminished until the industry experiences perfect competition [31]

There are several sources of market power including:

  1. High barriers to entry. These barriers include the control of scarce resources, increasing returns to scale, technological superiority and government created barriers to entry. [32] OPEC is an example of an organization that has market power due to control over scarce resources — oil.
  2. Increasing returns to scale. Firms that experience increasing returns to scale also experience decreasing average total costs and therefore become more profitable with size and higher demand levels. [32]
  3. High start-up costs. This barrier makes it difficult for new entrants to succeed as the initial creation costs are ingrained within the industry. Firms like power, cable television and telecommunication companies fall within this category. A firm seeking to enter such industries require the ability to spend millions of dollars before starting operations and generating revenue.
  4. Brand loyalty of consumers and value placed by consumers on reputation. Incumbent firms often have a competitive advantage over new entrants as customers are familiar with the product and service. An incumbent firm can engage in several entry-deterring strategies such as limit pricing, predatory pricing and strategic bundling. Microsoft has substantial pricing or market power due to technological superiority in its design and production processes. [32]
  5. Government policies/regulations. One significant technique of governmental action to create monopolies is the granting of franchises and operating licenses. This is due to the fact that no other businesses are permitted by law to operate without a franchise. [33] A prime example are patents granted to pharmaceutical companies which prevent competitors from creating and selling their specific goods. These patents give the drug companies a virtual monopoly in the protected product for the term of the patent.
  6. Factors of Production Barriers. An important influencing factor of market power is the control of the supply of factors of production to produce the good. Factors of production can be divided into tangible land, capital, and intangible human resources, intelligence, etc. As the industrial economy changes to a knowledge-based economy, the control of the supply of intangible factors of production such as talent, intelligence, information, etc. will become more and more of a barrier to entry for companies with unlimited market power. [34]

Measurement of market power

Measuring market power is inherently complex because the most widely used measures are sensitive to the definition of a market and the range of analysis.

Magnitude of a firm's market power is shown by a firm's ability to deviate from an elastic demand curve and charge a higher price (P) above its marginal cost (C), commonly referred to as a firm's mark-up or margin. [35] The higher a firm's mark-up, the larger the magnitude of power. This said, markups are complicated to measure as they are reliant on a firm's marginal costs and as a result, concentration ratios are the more common measures as they require only publicly accessible revenue data.

Concentration ratios

Market concentration, also referred to as industry concentration, refers to the extent of which market shares of the largest firms in the market account for a significant portion of the economic activities quantifiable by various metrics such as sales, employment, active users. [36] Recent macroeconomic market power literature indicates that concentration ratios are the most frequently used measure of market power. [2] Measures of concentration summarise the share of market or industry activity accounted for by large firms. An advantage of using concentration as an empirical tool to quantify market power is the requirement of only needing revenue data of firms which results in the corresponding disadvantage of the inconsideration of costs or profits. [35]

N-firm concentration ratio

The N-firm concentration ratio gives the combined market share of the largest N firms in the market. For example, a 4-firm concentration ratio measures the total market share of the four largest firms in an industry. In order to calculate the N-firm concentration ratio, one usually uses sales revenue to calculate market share, however, concentration ratios based on other measures such as production capacity may also be used. For a monopoly, the 4-firm concentration ratio is 100 per cent whilst for perfect competition, the ratio is zero. [37] Moreover, studies indicate that a concentration ratio of between 40 and 70 percent suggests that the firm operates as an oligopoly. [38] These figures are viable but should be used as a 'rule of thumb' as it is important to consider other market factors when analysing concentration ratios.

An advantage of concentration ratios as an empirical tool for studying market power is that it requires only data on revenues and is thus easy to compute. The corresponding disadvantage is that concentration is about relative revenue and includes no information about costs or profits.

Herfindahl-Hirschman index

The Herfindahl-Hirschman index (HHI) is another measure of concentration and is the sum of the squared market shares of all firms in a market. [39] The HHI is a more widely used indicator in economics and government regulation. The index reflects not only the market share of large firms within the market, but also the market structure outside of large firms, and therefore, more accurately reflects the degree of influence of large firms on the market. [40] For example, in a market with two firms, each with 50% market share, the HHI is = 0.502 + 0.502 = 0.50. The HHI for a monopoly is 1 whilst for perfect competition, the HHI is zero. Unlike the N-firm concentration ratio, large firms are given more weight in the HHI and as a result, the HHI conveys more information. However the HHI has its own limitations as it is sensitive to the definition of a market, therefore meaning you cannot use it to cross-examine different industries, or do analysis over time as the industry changes. [22]

Relationship between the Herfindahl-Hirschman index and market structure. The greater the Herfindahl-Hirschman value, the greater the market power. Herfindahls index.jpg
Relationship between the Herfindahl-Hirschman index and market structure. The greater the Herfindahl-Hirschman value, the greater the market power.

Lerner index

The Lerner index is a widely accepted and applied method of estimating market power in a monopoly. It compares a firm's price of output with its associated marginal cost where marginal cost pricing is the "socially optimal level" achieved in market with perfect competition. [41] Lerner (1934) believes that market power is the monopoly manufacturers' ability to raise prices above their marginal cost. [42] This notion can be expressed by using the formula:

Where P represents the price of the good set by the firm and MC representing the firm's marginal cost.The formula focuses on the nature of monopoly and emphasising welfare economic implications of the Pareto optimal principle. [43] Although Lerner is usually credited for the price/cost margin index, the generalized version was fully derived prior to WWII by Italian neoclassical economist, Luigi Amaroso. [44]

Connection with Competition Law

Market power within competition law can be used to determine whether or not a firm has unfairly manipulated the market in their favour, or to the detriment of entrants. The Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890 under section 2 restricts firms from engaging in anticompetitive conduct by utilising an individual firm's power to manipulate the market or partake in anticompetitive acts. [45] A firm can be found in breach of the act if they have leveraged their market power to unfairly gain further market power in a manner that is detrimental to the market and consumers. The measurement of market power is key in determining a breach of the act and can be determined from multiple measurements as discussed in measurements of market power above.

In Australia, consumer law allows for firms to have significant market power and utilise it, as long as it is determined to not have “the purpose, effect or likely effect of substantially lessening competition” [46]

Elasticity of demand

The degree to which a firm can raise its price above marginal cost depends on the shape of the demand curve at a firm's profit maximising level of output. [47] Consequently, the relationship between market power and the price elasticity of demand (PED) can be summarised by the equation:

The ratio is always greater than 1 and the higher the ratio, the more market power the firm possesses. As PED increases in magnitude, the ratio approaches 1 and market power approaches zero. The equation is derived from the monopolist pricing rule:

Nobel Memorial Prize

Jean Tirole was awarded the 2014 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his analysis of market power and economic regulation. [48]

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Microeconomics</span> Behavior of individuals and firms

Microeconomics is a branch of economics that studies the behavior of individuals and firms in making decisions regarding the allocation of scarce resources and the interactions among these individuals and firms. Microeconomics focuses on the study of individual markets, sectors, or industries as opposed to the national economy as a whole, which is studied in macroeconomics.

A monopoly, as described by Irving Fisher, is a market with the "absence of competition", creating a situation where a specific person or enterprise is the only supplier of a particular thing. This contrasts with a monopsony which relates to a single entity's control of a market to purchase a good or service, and with oligopoly and duopoly which consists of a few sellers dominating a market. Monopolies are thus characterised by a lack of economic competition to produce the good or service, a lack of viable substitute goods, and the possibility of a high monopoly price well above the seller's marginal cost that leads to a high monopoly profit. The verb monopolise or monopolize refers to the process by which a company gains the ability to raise prices or exclude competitors. In economics, a monopoly is a single seller. In law, a monopoly is a business entity that has significant market power, that is, the power to charge overly high prices, which is associated with a decrease in social surplus. Although monopolies may be big businesses, size is not a characteristic of a monopoly. A small business may still have the power to raise prices in a small industry.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Monopolistic competition</span> Imperfect competition of differentiated products that are not perfect substitutes

Monopolistic competition is a type of imperfect competition such that there are many producers competing against each other, but selling products that are differentiated from one another and hence are not perfect substitutes. In monopolistic competition, a company takes the prices charged by its rivals as given and ignores the impact of its own prices on the prices of other companies. If this happens in the presence of a coercive government, monopolistic competition will fall into government-granted monopoly. Unlike perfect competition, the company maintains spare capacity. Models of monopolistic competition are often used to model industries. Textbook examples of industries with market structures similar to monopolistic competition include restaurants, cereals, clothing, shoes, and service industries in large cities. The "founding father" of the theory of monopolistic competition is Edward Hastings Chamberlin, who wrote a pioneering book on the subject, Theory of Monopolistic Competition (1933). Joan Robinson published a book The Economics of Imperfect Competition with a comparable theme of distinguishing perfect from imperfect competition. Further work on monopolistic competition was undertaken by Dixit and Stiglitz who created the Dixit-Stiglitz model which has proved applicable used in the sub fields of international trade theory, macroeconomics and economic geography.

An oligopoly is a market in which control over an industry lies in the hands of a few large sellers who own a dominant share of the market. Oligopolistic markets have homogenous products, few market participants, and inelastic demand for the products in those industries. As a result of their significant market power, firms in oligopolistic markets can influence prices through manipulating the supply function. Firms in an oligopoly are also mutually interdependent, as any action by one firm is expected to affect other firms in the market and evoke a reaction or consequential action. As a result, firms in oligopolistic markets often resort to collusion as means of maximising profits.

In economics, specifically general equilibrium theory, a perfect market, also known as an atomistic market, is defined by several idealizing conditions, collectively called perfect competition, or atomistic competition. In theoretical models where conditions of perfect competition hold, it has been demonstrated that a market will reach an equilibrium in which the quantity supplied for every product or service, including labor, equals the quantity demanded at the current price. This equilibrium would be a Pareto optimum.

In economics, imperfect competition refers to a situation where the characteristics of an economic market do not fulfil all the necessary conditions of a perfectly competitive market. Imperfect competition causes market inefficiencies, resulting in market failure. Imperfect competition usually describes behaviour of suppliers in a market, such that the level of competition between sellers is below the level of competition in perfectly competitive market conditions.

The Herfindahl index is a measure of the size of firms in relation to the industry they are in and is an indicator of the amount of competition among them. Named after economists Orris C. Herfindahl and Albert O. Hirschman, it is an economic concept widely applied in competition law, antitrust regulation, and technology management. HHI has continued to be used by antitrust authorities, primarily to evaluate and understand how mergers will affect their associated markets. HHI is calculated by squaring the market share of each competing firm in the industry and then summing the resulting numbers. The result is proportional to the average market share, weighted by market share. As such, it can range from 0 to 1.0, moving from a huge number of very small firms to a single monopolistic producer. Increases in the HHI generally indicate a decrease in competition and an increase of market power, whereas decreases indicate the opposite. Alternatively, the index can be expressed per 10,000 "points". For example, an index of .25 is the same as 2,500 points.

In theories of competition in economics, a barrier to entry, or an economic barrier to entry, is a fixed cost that must be incurred by a new entrant, regardless of production or sales activities, into a market that incumbents do not have or have not had to incur. Because barriers to entry protect incumbent firms and restrict competition in a market, they can contribute to distortionary prices and are therefore most important when discussing antitrust policy. Barriers to entry often cause or aid the existence of monopolies and oligopolies, or give companies market power. Barriers of entry also have an importance in industries. First of all it is important to identify that some exist naturally, such as brand loyalty. Governments can also create barriers to entry to meet consumer protection laws, protecting the public. In other cases it can also be due to inherent scarcity of public resources needed to enter a market.

Monopoly profit is an inflated level of profit due to the monopolistic practices of an enterprise.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Marginal revenue</span> Additional total revenue generated by increasing product sales by 1 unit

Marginal revenue is a central concept in microeconomics that describes the additional total revenue generated by increasing product sales by 1 unit. Marginal revenue is the increase in revenue from the sale of one additional unit of product, i.e., the revenue from the sale of the last unit of product. It can be positive or negative. Marginal revenue is an important concept in vendor analysis. To derive the value of marginal revenue, it is required to examine the difference between the aggregate benefits a firm received from the quantity of a good and service produced last period and the current period with one extra unit increase in the rate of production. Marginal revenue is a fundamental tool for economic decision making within a firm's setting, together with marginal cost to be considered.

The Lerner index, formalized in 1934 by British economist of Russian origin Abba Lerner, is a measure of a firm's market power.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Market structure</span> Differentiation of firms by goods and operations

Market structure, in economics, depicts how firms are differentiated and categorised based on the types of goods they sell (homogeneous/heterogeneous) and how their operations are affected by external factors and elements. Market structure makes it easier to understand the characteristics of diverse markets.

In economics, market concentration is a function of the number of firms and their respective shares of the total production in a market. Market concentration is the portion of a given market's market share that is held by a small number of businesses. To ascertain whether an industry is competitive or not, it is employed in antitrust law and economic regulation. When market concentration is high, it indicates that a few firms dominate the market and oligopoly or monopolistic competition is likely to exist. In most cases, high market concentration produces undesirable consequences such as reduced competition and higher prices.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Competition (economics)</span> Economic scenario

In economics, competition is a scenario where different economic firms are in contention to obtain goods that are limited by varying the elements of the marketing mix: price, product, promotion and place. In classical economic thought, competition causes commercial firms to develop new products, services and technologies, which would give consumers greater selection and better products. The greater the selection of a good is in the market, the lower prices for the products typically are, compared to what the price would be if there was no competition (monopoly) or little competition (oligopoly).

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Edward Chamberlin</span> American economist

Edward Hastings Chamberlin was an American economist. He was born in La Conner, Washington, and died in Cambridge, Massachusetts.

A bilateral monopoly is a market structure consisting of both a monopoly and a monopsony.

In neoclassical economics, a market distortion is any event in which a market reaches a market clearing price for an item that is substantially different from the price that a market would achieve while operating under conditions of perfect competition and state enforcement of legal contracts and the ownership of private property. A distortion is "any departure from the ideal of perfect competition that therefore interferes with economic agents maximizing social welfare when they maximize their own". A proportional wage-income tax, for instance, is distortionary, whereas a lump-sum tax is not. In a competitive equilibrium, a proportional wage income tax discourages work.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Profit (economics)</span> Concept in economics

In economics, profit is the difference between revenue that an economic entity has received from its outputs and total costs of its inputs, also known as surplus value. It is equal to total revenue minus total cost, including both explicit and implicit costs.

Joe Staten Bain was an American economist associated with the University of California, Berkeley. Bain was designated a Distinguished Fellow by the American Economic Association in 1982. An accompanying statement referred to him as "the undisputed father of modern Industrial Organization Economics."

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Monopoly price</span> Aspect of monopolistic markets

In microeconomics, a monopoly price is set by a monopoly. A monopoly occurs when a firm lacks any viable competition and is the sole producer of the industry's product. Because a monopoly faces no competition, it has absolute market power and can set a price above the firm's marginal cost.

References

  1. Landes, William M.; Posner, Richard A. (1981). "Market Power in Antitrust Cases". Harvard Law Review. 94 (5): 937–996. doi:10.2307/1340687. JSTOR   1340687.
  2. 1 2 3 Syverson, Chad (2019). "Macroeconomics and Market Power: Context, Implications, and Open Questions". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 33 (3): 23–43. doi: 10.1257/jep.33.3.23 . S2CID   201326865.
  3. Pleatsikas, Christopher (2018). "Perfect Competition". The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management. pp. 1272–1275. doi:10.1057/978-1-137-00772-8_558. ISBN   978-0-230-53721-7.
  4. 1 2 Davis, Douglas D. (2018). "Market Power and Collusion in Laboratory Markets". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. pp. 8260–8263. doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_2836. ISBN   978-1-349-95188-8.
  5. 1 2 Unger, Gabriel; Eeckhout, Jan; De Loecker, Jan (2020). "The Rise of Market Power and the Macroeconomic Implications". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 135 (2): 561–644. doi: 10.1093/qje/qjz041 .
  6. Vatiero, Massimiliano (2010). "The Ordoliberal Notion of Market Power: An Institutionalist Reassessment". European Competition Journal. 6 (3): 689–707. doi:10.5235/ecj.v6n3.689. S2CID   154973650.
  7. Leslie, C. (2013). PREDATORY PRICING AND RECOUPMENT. Columbia Law Review, 113(7), 1695–1771.
  8. Lin, Jing; Ma, Xin; Talluri, Srinivas; Yang, Cheng-Hu (2021-02-09). "Retail channel management decisions under collusion". European Journal of Operational Research. 294 (2): 700–710. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2021.01.046. ISSN   0377-2217.
  9. Borenstein, Severin; Bushnell, James; Knittel, Christopher R. (1999). "Market Power in Electricity Markets: Beyond Concentration Measures". The Energy Journal. 20 (4): 65–88. doi:10.5547/ISSN0195-6574-EJ-Vol20-No4-3. ISSN   0195-6574. JSTOR   41326187.
  10. 1 2 Besanko, David (2013). ECONOMICS OF STRATEGY (6th ed.). Printed in the United States of America 6th Edition. pp. 171–172. ISBN   9781118273630.
  11. 1 2 Lábaj, Martin; Morvay, Karol; Silanič, Peter; Weiss, Christoph; Yontcheva, Biliana (2018-03-28). "Market structure and competition in transition: results from a spatial analysis". Applied Economics. 50 (15): 1694–1715. doi: 10.1080/00036846.2017.1374535 . ISSN   0003-6846.
  12. Robinson, Joan (1934). "What is Perfect Competition?". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 49 (1): 104–120. doi: 10.2307/1883878 . JSTOR   1883878.
  13. Debreu, Gerard (1959). Theory of value; an axiomatic analysis of economic equilibrium. New Haven: Yale University Press. ISBN   0-300-01558-5. OCLC   420976.
  14. McDermott, John F. M. (2015-05-19). "Perfect competition, methodologically contemplated". Journal of Post Keynesian Economics. 37 (4): 687–703. doi:10.1080/01603477.2015.1050335. ISSN   0160-3477. S2CID   154042857.
  15. Barkley, Andrew (2016). The Economics of Food and Agricultural Markets. Minneapolis, MN. ISBN   978-1-944548-22-3. OCLC   1151088067.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  16. Krugman, Paul R.; Maurice Obstfeld (2009). International economics: theory and policy (8th ed.). Boston: Pearson Addison-Wesley. ISBN   978-0-321-49304-0. OCLC   174112719.
  17. d’Aspremont, Claude; Dos Santos Ferreira, Rodolphe (June 2016). "Oligopolistic vs. monopolistic competition: Do intersectoral effects matter?". Economic Theory. 62 (1–2): 299–324. doi:10.1007/s00199-015-0905-8. ISSN   0938-2259. S2CID   155013659.
  18. "Monopolistic Competition - Overview, How It Works, Limitations". Corporate Finance Institute. Retrieved 2021-04-27.
  19. McKenzie, Richard B.; Lee, Dwight R. (2008), "Deadweight-Loss Monopoly", In Defense of Monopoly, How Market Power Fosters Creative Production, University of Michigan Press, pp. 25–53, ISBN   978-0-472-11615-7, JSTOR   j.ctvnjbdsg.5 , retrieved 2021-04-25
  20. 1 2 "Monopoly power as a market failure | Economics Online | Economics Online". 2020-01-29. Retrieved 2021-04-20.
  21. 1 2 "Monopoly Power". xplaind.com. 23 February 2019. Retrieved 2021-04-20.
  22. 1 2 De Loecker, Jan; Eeckhout, Jan; Unger, Gabriel (2020-05-01). "The Rise of Market Power and the Macroeconomic Implications*". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 135 (2): 561–644. doi: 10.1093/qje/qjz041 . ISSN   0033-5533.
  23. Vatiero, M. (2009). An Institutionalist Explanation of Market Dominances. World Competition. Law and Economics Review, 32(2):221–226.
  24. "Oligopoly - characteristics | Economics Online | Economics Online". 2020-01-20. Retrieved 2021-04-18.
  25. Carr, Christopher (2020). Global Oligopoly : a Key Idea for Business and Society (1st ed.). Routledge. ISBN   9780429316050.
  26. "Barriers to Entry - Types of Barriers to Markets & How They Work". Corporate Finance Institute. Retrieved 2021-04-18.
  27. "Section 3: Characteristics of an Oligopoly Industry | Inflate Your Mind" . Retrieved 2021-04-18.
  28. Stigler, George J (May 1950). "Monopoly and Oligopoly by Merger". The American Economic Review. 40 (2): 23–34. JSTOR   1818020 via JSTOR.
  29. "Kinked Demand Curve". Toppr. 17 October 2018. Retrieved 18 April 2021.
  30. "Interdependence in Oligopolies | Revision World". revisionworld.com. Retrieved 2021-04-18.
  31. 1 2 White, Lawrence J. (2013-07-01), Thomas, Christopher R.; Shughart, William F. (eds.), "Market Power: How Does it Arise? How is it Measured?", The Oxford Handbook of Managerial Economics, Oxford University Press, pp. 30–65, doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199782956.013.0003, ISBN   978-0-19-978295-6 , retrieved 2021-04-25
  32. 1 2 3 Krugman & Wells, Microeconomics 2d ed. (Worth 2009)
  33. Kaplow, Louis (2017). "On the Relevance of Market Power". Harvard Law Review. 130 (5): 1303–1407. JSTOR   44865537.
  34. Lutz, Clemens H. M. (July 2010). "Perceptions regarding strategic and structural entry barriers". Small Business Economics. 35 (1): 19–33. doi: 10.1007/s11187-008-9159-1 . JSTOR   40802429. S2CID   67784475.
  35. 1 2 Syverson, Chad (2019-08-01). "Macroeconomics and Market Power: Context, Implications, and Open Questions". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 33 (3): 23–43. doi: 10.1257/jep.33.3.23 . ISSN   0895-3309.
  36. Kvålseth, Tarald O. (2018-10-11). "Relationship between concentration ratio and Herfindahl-Hirschman index: A re-examination based on majorization theory". Heliyon. 4 (10): e00846. Bibcode:2018Heliy...400846K. doi:10.1016/j.heliyon.2018.e00846. ISSN   2405-8440. PMC   6190613 . PMID   30338305.
  37. Samuelson & Nordhaus, Microeconomics, 17th ed. (McGraw-Hill 2001) at 183.
  38. "Glossary: Learn more about IBISWorld's key terms". 2018-12-08. Archived from the original on 2018-12-08. Retrieved 2021-04-18.
  39. Samuelson & Nordhaus, Microeconomics, 17th ed. (McGraw-Hill 2001) at 184.
  40. Calkins, Stephen (Mar 1983). "The New Merger Guidelines and the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index". California Law Review. 71 (2): 402–429. doi:10.2307/3480160. JSTOR   3480160 via JSTOR.
  41. Spierdijk, Laura; Zaouras, Michalis (2017-09-02). "The Lerner index and revenue maximization". Applied Economics Letters. 24 (15): 1075–1079. doi: 10.1080/13504851.2016.1254333 . ISSN   1350-4851.
  42. Sun, Baowen; Jing, Wenjun; Zhao, Xuankai; He, Yi (2017). "Research on market power and market structure". International Journal of Crowd Science. 1 (3): 210–222. doi: 10.1108/IJCS-08-2017-0009 .
  43. Elzinga, Kenneth G.; Mills, David E. (2011). "The Lerner Index of Monopoly Power: Origins and Uses". American Economic Review. 101 (3): 558–564. doi:10.1257/aer.101.3.558. S2CID   154743000.
  44. Giocoli, Nicola (2012). "Who Invented the Lerner Index? Luigi Amoroso, the Dominant Firm Model, and the Measurement of Market Power". Review of Industrial Organization. 41 (3): 181–191. doi:10.1007/s11151-012-9355-7. ISSN   0889-938X. JSTOR   43550398. S2CID   153832234.
  45. See 15 U.S.C.   § 2.
  46. See Competition and Consumer Act 2010.
  47. Perloff, J: Microeconomics Theory & Applications with Calculus page 369. Pearson 2008.
  48. "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2014". NobelPrize.org. Retrieved 2021-04-25.

Further references