Villagization (Ethiopia)

Last updated

Villagization was a land reform and resettlement program in Ethiopia implemented by the Derg in 1985 that aimed to systematize and regulate village life and rural agriculture. Villagization typically involved the relocation of rural communities or nomadic groups to planned villages with communal farmland.

Contents

Land reform stood as one of the Derg's foremost priorities, and villagization occurred within the context of broader policies of resettlement and the collectivization of agriculture. A nominally Marxist-Leninist state, the Derg modeled villagization on Soviet and Tanzanian precedents. [1] [2] Villagization policy immediately followed the Famine of 1983-85, and attempted to increase food production, expand social services, and further extend state control over rural populations through a systematic relocation of people into planned communities. [3] [4]

Opponents of the Derg saw villagization programs as thinly-veiled efforts to address security concerns in rural areas, particularly those where support for the Oromo or Western Somali Liberation Fronts was strongest. [5] Rural populations often met villagization campaigns with skepticism or resistance, and in many areas officials relocated groups hastily and violently. [6] [3] Poor conditions in many newly centralized villages exacerbated conditions of poverty and underdevelopment, drawing significant criticism from international human rights groups. [7] In 1990, shortly before its overthrow by the Ethiopian People's Revolutionary Democratic Front, the People's Democratic Republic of Ethiopia (PDRE) shifted to free-market economic policies and abandoned villagization. [8] [9]

Land reform and resettlement

Imperial era

The nature of villagization's motivations and implementation originate from the broader context of land reform under the Derg. Issues of land reform were central to the Derg's rise and the overthrow of Haile Selassie. Prior to the 1974 revolution, an entrenched and complex land-tenure system severely restricted peasants' rights to agricultural land and freedom of movement. [10] Population growth in the 1950s and 1960s increased the economic insecurity of peasant tenants, generating considerable pressure for reform. [11] A long-standing labor surplus in the Highlands also limited a gradual modernization of agriculture in Ethiopia, as there was little incentive to pursue mechanization. Thus traditional farming practices remained widespread into the 1970s. [11] While Selassie's regime made some effort to redress overpopulation by resettling groups from the Highlands region, the Derg was able to gain significant support with a pledge to abolish the land-tenure system, calling for "land to the tiller." Land reform became the central issue the revolution. [12]

Revolutionary period

Emblem of the Derg, featuring a plow Emblem of the Provisional Military Government of Socialist Ethiopia.svg
Emblem of the Derg, featuring a plow

After coming to power in 1975, the Derg accelerated resettlement policies and implemented substantial agricultural reforms. Most private holdings were nationalized, land was redistributed from landlords to peasants, and worker cooperatives were encouraged. Peasant associations based on socialist principles quickly became the foundation of the new rural life. [13] [8] [10] The 1975 Rural Land Proclamation No. 31 mandated that peasant associations undertake 8 specific tasks, among which was the encouragement of villagization. This was the first instance in which villagization appeared in the Derg's land reform policy. [14]

However, peasant associations were rarely eager to implement villagization themselves, and devoted most of their energies to the redistribution of land. [13] Because the regime initially made little effort to seriously implement the policy, no serious attempts were made until 1985. Through the 1970s the Derg invested most heavily in resettlement programs, with the goal of relocating 1.5 million people to previously uncultivated land. [8] [15] The Land Reform Proclamation of 1975 gave the state full authority to dictate and implement resettlement. As part of Qey Shibir terror campaign, tactics of violence and intimidation to force populations into new settlements were common. Poor planning and negligence often meant that resettled groups were left without proper food, shelter, or services, leading to thousands of deaths from starvation and disease. [9] Despite international criticism, the Derg resorted to similar methods when implementing villagization in the 1980s.

1983-1985 Famine

In the mid 1980s Ethiopia experienced its worst famine of the 20th century, leaving 1.2 million dead and 2.5 million internally displaced. [6] While record low rainfall and severe drought were the most immediate cause of the famine, rapid land reform, misguided policy, and years of underproduction created a disproportionate crisis. [16] Government policies during the famine also played a significant role in exacerbating its effects. Resettlement often led to a decline in agricultural production, and most new settlements had still not yet become self-sufficient. [17] Furthermore, international humanitarian organizations such as Oxfam and Human Rights Watch have alleged that Mengistu Haile Mariam's regime intentionally weaponized the famine in its fight against rebel insurgencies during the Civil War, withholding food aid from Tigray and Welo regions. [7] Villagization emerged as one of the Derg's emergency policies to address the famine, with the intention of organizing underproductive agricultural sectors. Addressing the famine became the regime's singular justification for villagization to the public. In an interview with the German journalist Hannelore Gadatsch on December 16, 1986, Mengistu stated that the regime had intended to carry out villagization in stages over a longer period of time, but the drought necessitated a rapid implementation of the program. [18] Some familiar with the regime's development plan instead saw this as a calculated act to gain political advantage from the crisis. [15]

Policy goals

Mengistu Haile Mariam, Chairman of the Derg and President of Ethiopia Mengistu Haile Mariam 3.jpg
Mengistu Haile Mariam, Chairman of the Derg and President of Ethiopia

Villagization aimed to radically transform rural life in Ethiopia while combatting drought and increasing agricultural productivity. The Mengistu regime saw villagization as a way to quickly achieve the collectivization of agriculture and rural modernization. By relocating dispersed communities and nomadic groups into larger, planned villages, the state could more easily supply modern services such as clean water, clinics, schools, and electricity. [19] [15] With state assistance villages would also act as hubs for technological improvements in agriculture. Each new village would be organized under a single peasant association approved by the state. Villages and their respective associations would function as producer cooperatives, forming the basis for the development of future collective farms. [8] [14]

The regime was also concerned that peasant associations were becoming mechanisms of private wealth accumulation, antithetical to the revolution's mission. Villagization would extend state reach further into the countryside, allowing for better regulation of these associations. [2] Another function of the policy was to force peasants into an official, regulated agricultural market. Villagization would allow the government's agricultural bureau, the Agricultural Marketing Corporation, to easily extract goods and produce from the rural sector at fixed prices. [20] [21]

The Derg also pursued villagization with security concerns in mind, as the new villages could more easily be organized into defensive military units or monitored for rebel activity. [8] Such concerns were especially salient in Bale and Hararghe provinces, where the Ogaden War had severely undermined state control. Some argue that security concerns, rather than agricultural development, were the primary concerns motivating villagization. [15] [2] Villages in border regions were likened to "strategic hamlets" that formed a barrier between insurgents and the general population. [14] Villagization also directly targeted political tensions in the Shebelle valley, where new state farms had displaced a large number of smallholding farmers. [2]

Policy implementation

Starting in 1985 the government began directly forcing peasant associations to implement villagization. Mengistu charged Starting in 1985 the government began directly forcing peasant associations to implement villagization. Impressed by a model villagization program in Harar, Mengistu charged Legesse Asfaw with orchestrating a new villagization policy. [15] The Ten Year Perspective Plan made villagization central to rural development, with the goal of relocating 33 million rural people by 1994. [14]

Traditional tukuls Pic 5 ethiopia traditional houses.jpg
Traditional tukuls

Peasant associations were encouraged to compete for Mengistu's praise by speedily establishing the most villages. According to official policy, each peasant association was to establish a village in a location suitable for habitation and farming. [19] However, the regime often hastily forced associations onto particular sites with no consideration of local knowledge or preferences. Furthermore, physical and agricultural surveys of new sites were rarely taken, resulting in numerous villages located on unproductive land. The Central Planning Committee only began investigating the long-term consequences of villagization well after the initiative was underway. [15] Farmers were typically required to dismantle their huts, or tukuls, and transport the materials to the new village site, where they would rebuild their tukul on a designated plot. [19] [14] Each village typically consisted of 500 families. [15] Peasant associations seized farmers' tools and livestock for communal use. [22] Many farmers perceived that the better, more fertile tracts were distributed to the wealthier heads of the peasant associations or to those able to pay bribes. [8]

Because peasant associations often lacked personnel and administrative capacity, the Derg recruited over 60,000 high school and university students--the so called zemacha--to help organize rural communities and assist with villagization. [8] [14] The Derg compelled students to root out enemies of the revolution and permitted them to use coercion and physical violence against peasants. Those who resisted villagization were often abused, jailed or executed. At times student groups attempted to implement changes on a more radical level than the regime's villagization policy, undermining government legitimacy in rural areas. [8] Peasants were particularly resistant to villagization in Gojjam and western Shewa, where traditional practice remained strong, and faced severe government retaliation. [14] By 1986 more than 3.5 million lived in the new villages. [22] By 1989 the regime had established over 4,500 villages and relocated about 13 million peasants in Shewa, Arsi, and Hararge provinces alone. [8]

Results of villagization

Villagization had immediate effects on rural agricultural life in Ethiopia. The rapid, haphazard nature of its implementation severely disrupted farmers' daily lives, impacting their ability to tend to their crops. Poorly planned and forced relocations often wasted farmers' valuable time and resources. [19] New homestead plots were often located far from land designated for cultivation, placing a greater burden on farmers. The promised clinics, schools, and other services of the new villages typically remained unrealized. [21] Furthermore, farmers often earned lower incomes in the new villages, as they were unable to sell their goods at a higher value on black-markets. [20] Villagization often did not end traditional agricultural practice, as peasants saw little evidence that government mandates improved production. [15]

In many areas agricultural production rapidly declined. The ratio of farmers to arable land was often less than it had been prior to villagization. In 1988 village service cooperatives accounted for only 5.5% of grain production, despite ostensibly serving 4.4 million households. [23] Mengistu however claimed that poor production levels were the result of a social structure still rooted in individualism and a petit bourgeois capitalist mentality, and the regime did not immediately abandon villagization. [2] The rapid construction of new villages also led to serious deforestation, damaging already vulnerable ecosystems that help combat desertification. [22] Some communities fled rather than face villagization, settling in refuge camps across the Somali border. [14] The new village system became increasingly difficult for the regime to sustain. Villages were often initially dependent on the state for resources and incurred significant organizational costs. [24] Ultimately Mengistu's government abandoned the policy entirely in 1990, bowing to internal and external pressures to switch to free-market economic policies. [8] [9]

Reactions and criticisms

Contemporary critics of villagization noted that the policy often worsened the problems it sought to address. [11] A commissioned report by the Swedish International Development Agency, the first to study villagization, criticized the timing of the policy. [14] Observers of the food crisis in Ethiopia feared that the policy would only further disrupt agricultural production, and criticized the Derg for ignoring actual local concerns. If the regime granted greater autonomy to the peasant associations, villagization could possibly have been carried out more peacefully and with more support from the communities affected. [19]

International agencies and donors generally condemned the policy. [8] Many foreign donors suspended aid flows to Ethiopia, as they were unwilling to support a collectivization drive resemblant of dekulakization and the creation of Soviet state farms. [25] Others donors reluctant to send aid felt that such development programs could no longer be considered "humanitarian activities." [15] In 1988, after considerable pressure from the World Bank, the regime relaxed market regulations within the new village cooperatives. [21]

Those sympathetic to the revolution approved the principle of villagization yet lamented its tumultuous execution. [15] Peasants themselves resented the loss of their property and the militarized feel of the new villages, which lacked any places of worship or traditional cultural institutions. One German observer noted that "these new villages gave the impression of having come straight out of the laboratory." [26] Some scholars have noted the similarities between villagization in Ethiopia and villagization in Tanzania under Nyerere. [2] Despite the Derg's awareness of the particular failures of the Tanzanian precedent, lessons on excessive centralization and coercion were not drawn. [2]

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">1983–1985 famine in Ethiopia</span> Famine in Ethiopia during the Derg rule

A widespread famine affected Ethiopia from 1983 to 1985. The worst famine to hit the country in a century, it affected 7.75 million people and left approximately 300,000 to 1.2 million dead. 2.5 million people were internally displaced whereas 400,000 refugees left Ethiopia. Almost 200,000 children were orphaned.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Mengistu Haile Mariam</span> Leader of Ethiopia from 1977 to 1991

Mengistu Haile Mariam is an Ethiopian politician and former army officer who was the head of state of Ethiopia from 1977 to 1991 and General Secretary of the Workers' Party of Ethiopia from 1984 to 1991. He was the chairman of the Derg, the socialist military junta that governed Ethiopia, from 1977 to 1987, and the president of the People's Democratic Republic of Ethiopia (PDRE) from 1987 to 1991.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Collectivization in the Soviet Union</span> Forced economic reforms of collective ownership of the means of production

The Soviet Union introduced the collectivization of its agricultural sector between 1928 and 1940 during the ascension of Joseph Stalin. It began during and was part of the first five-year plan. The policy aimed to integrate individual landholdings and labour into collectively-controlled and state-controlled farms: Kolkhozes and Sovkhozes accordingly. The Soviet leadership confidently expected that the replacement of individual peasant farms by collective ones would immediately increase the food supply for the urban population, the supply of raw materials for the processing industry, and agricultural exports via state-imposed quotas on individuals working on collective farms. Planners regarded collectivization as the solution to the crisis of agricultural distribution that had developed from 1927. This problem became more acute as the Soviet Union pressed ahead with its ambitious industrialization program, meaning that more food needed to be produced to keep up with urban demand.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Tafari Benti</span> Military leader of Ethiopia from 1974 to 1977

Brigadier General Tafari Benti was an Ethiopian military officer and politician who served as head of state of Ethiopia from 1974 to 1977 in his role as second chairman of the Derg, the ruling military junta. His official title was Chairman of the Provisional Military Administrative Council.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Derg</span> 1974–1987 ruling military junta of Ethiopia

The Derg, officially the Provisional Military Administrative Council (PMAC), was the military junta that ruled Ethiopia, then including present-day Eritrea, from 1974 to 1987, when the military leadership formally "civilianized" the administration but stayed in power until 1991.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">People's Democratic Republic of Ethiopia</span> 1987–1991 socialist state existed in Ethiopia and Eritrea

The People's Democratic Republic of Ethiopia (PDRE) was a socialist state that existed in Ethiopia and present day Eritrea from 1987 to 1991.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Ethiopian Civil War</span> 1974–1991 conflict in Ethiopia

The Ethiopian Civil War was a civil war in Ethiopia and present-day Eritrea, fought between the Ethiopian military junta known as the Derg and Ethiopian-Eritrean anti-government rebels from 12 September 1974 to 28 May 1991.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Agriculture in Ethiopia</span> Overview of agriculture in Ethiopia

Agriculture in Ethiopia is the foundation of the country's economy, accounting for half of gross domestic product (GDP), 83.9% of exports, and 80% of total employment.

Resettlement and villagization in Ethiopia has been an issue from the late nineteenth century up to the present, due to the overcrowded population of the Ethiopian highlands. As the population of Ethiopia has increased in the twentieth century, the need to move inhabitants has only increased as available cropland per family declined to its current level of less than one hectare per farmer.

The problem of land reform in Ethiopia has hampered that country's economic development throughout the late 19th and 20th centuries. Attempts to modernize land ownership by giving title either to the peasants who till the soil, or to large-scale farming programs, have been tried under imperial rulers like Emperor Haile Selassie, and under Marxist regimes like the Derg, with mixed results. The present Constitution of Ethiopia, which was put into force January 1995, vests land ownership exclusively "in the State and in the peoples of Ethiopia." The relevant section continues, "Land is a common property of the Nations, Nationalities and Peoples of Ethiopia and shall not be subject to sale or to other means of exchange." Despite these different approaches to land reform, Ethiopia still faces issues of sustainable food self-sufficiency.

Dessalegn Rahmato is an Ethiopian sociologist. He was born in 1940 in Adama and he studied in the United States. He is specialized in agricultural development, famine and resettlement.

The Great Turn or Great Break was the radical change in the economic policy of the USSR from 1928 to 1929, primarily consisting of the process by which the New Economic Policy (NEP) of 1921 was abandoned in favor of the acceleration of collectivization and industrialization and also a cultural revolution. The term came from the title of Joseph Stalin's article "Year of the Great Turn" published on November 7, 1929, the 12th anniversary of the October Revolution. David R. Marples argues that the era of the Great Break lasted until 1934.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Collective farming</span> Type of agricultural organization

Collective farming and communal farming are various types of, "agricultural production in which multiple farmers run their holdings as a joint enterprise". There are two broad types of communal farms: agricultural cooperatives, in which member-owners jointly engage in farming activities as a collective, and state farms, which are owned and directly run by a centralized government. The process by which farmland is aggregated is called collectivization. In some countries, there have been both state-run and cooperative-run variants. For example, the Soviet Union had both kolkhozy and sovkhozy.

Agrarian socialism is a political ideology that promotes “the equal distribution of landed resources among collectivized peasant villages”. This socialist system places agriculture at the center of the economy instead of the industrialization efforts found in urban settings. Seen as more progressive in terms of social orientation, many agrarian socialist movements have tended to be rural, locally focused and traditional. The emphasis of agrarian socialists is therefore on social control, ownership and utilization of the means of production in a rural society. Additionally, principles like community, sharing and local ownership are emphasized under agrarian socialism. For instance, in rural communities in post-Soviet Russia “social organization of labor in the peasant household is based upon highly dense networks of mutual trust and interdependences” that diminished the need for manager-employee styles of labor. Nationalist ideology can also be seen coupled with agrarian socialist ideology, sometimes serving as the foundation for peasant-led revolutions. For instance, nationalist propaganda from the fledging Chinese communist party during the Sino-Japanese war era, “furthered the mobilization of the masses and helped determine the form this mobilization took”.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Fall of the Derg</span> 1991 downfall of the Ethiopian ruling junta

The fall of the Derg, also known as Downfall of the Derg, was a military campaign that resulted the defeat of the ruling military junta Derg by the rebel coalition Ethiopian People's Revolutionary Democratic Front (EPRDF) on 28 May 1991 in Addis Ababa, ending the Ethiopian Civil War. The Derg took power after deposing Emperor Haile Selassie and the Solomonic dynasty, an imperial dynasty of Ethiopia that began in 1270. The Derg suffered insurgency with different factions, and separatist rebels groups since early their rule, beginning with the Ethiopian Civil War. The 1983–1985 famine, the Red Terror, and resettlement and villagization infamed the Derg with majority of Ethiopians tended to support insurgent groups like the Tigray People's Liberation Front (TPLF) and Eritrean People's Liberation Front (EPLF).

This list details about chronological aspect of the Derg, the military junta that ruled Ethiopia from 1974 to 1987 by decade.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Casualties and impact of the Ethiopian Civil War</span>

The Ethiopian Civil War (1974–1991) has costed civilian, infrastructure and agricultural impacts. It left at least 1.4 million people dead, with 1 million related to famine and the remainder from violence and conflicts, which is one third of population.

There is not much in-depth information available about the revolution in Ethiopia, but the book Peasant Revolution in Ethiopia by John Young provides detailed information about the revolution, why it started, how the Derg affected the nation, and the role of the peasant population in Tigray and Eritrea.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">1974 Ethiopian coup d'état</span> Coup détat against Ethiopian Emperor Haile Selassie by the Derg

On 12 September 1974, Emperor Haile Selassie was deposed by the Derg, a Soviet-backed military junta that consequently ruled Ethiopia until 1991.

The government of the Derg consisted of Unitary Marxist-Leninist one-party system with communist and later socialist ideology. Opposing feudal system of Ethiopia, the Derg abolished land tenure in March 1975 and began sweeping land reform under Land Reform Proclamation. All means of goods have been therefore nationalized by the regime including housing, land, farms, and industry.

References

  1. Getahun, Haileleul (2001). Assault on Rural Poverty: The Case of Ethiopia. Maryland: University Press of America. pp. 51–69. ISBN   0761819800.
  2. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Harbeson, John W. (1988). The Ethiopian Transformation: The Quest for the Post Imperial State. Boulder: Westview Press. pp. 172–180.
  3. 1 2 Pankhurst, Alula (1992). Resettlement and Famine in Ethiopia. New York: Manchester University Press. pp. 51–105. ISBN   0719035376.
  4. Regassa, Asebe; Hizekiel, Yetebarek; Korf, Benedikt (2018-01-31). "'Civilizing' the pastoral frontier: land grabbing, dispossession and coercive agrarian development in Ethiopia". The Journal of Peasant Studies. 46 (5): 935–955. doi:10.1080/03066150.2017.1420060. ISSN   0306-6150. S2CID   158704956.
  5. Cannon-Lorgen, Christy (January 1999). "The Experience of Villagization" (PDF). Oxfam Great Britain.
  6. 1 2 Giorgis, David Wolde (1989). Red Tears: War, Famine, and Revolution in Ethiopia. New Jersey: Princeton Center for International Studies. ISBN   0932415342.
  7. 1 2 Waal, Alexander De (1991). Evil Days: Thirty Years of War and Famine in Ethiopia. Human Rights Watch. ISBN   9781564320384.
  8. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Getahun, Haileleul (2001). "Post Imperial Development Crises: The Derg Era 1974-1991". Assault on Rural Poverty: The Case of Ethiopia. New York: University Press of America. ISBN   0761819800.
  9. 1 2 3 Wubne, Mulata (1991). "Resettlement and Villagization". In Ofcansky, Thomas (ed.). Ethiopia: A Country Study. Washington: Library of Congress.
  10. 1 2 Rahmato, Dessalegn (1985). "The Ethiopian Experience in Agrarian Reform". In Kiros, Fassil G. (ed.). Challenging Rural Poverty. Trenton, NJ: Africa World Press.
  11. 1 2 3 McCann, James C. (1988). A Great Agrarian Cycle? : a history of agricultural productivity and demographic change in highland Ethiopia, 1900-1987. Boston: African Studies Center, Boston University Press.
  12. Yemane-ab, Abera (2016-06-28). ""Land to the Tiller": Unrealized Agenda of the Revolution". Northeast African Studies. 16 (1): 39–63. doi:10.14321/nortafristud.16.1.0039. ISSN   1535-6574. S2CID   156651118.
  13. 1 2 Dejene, Alemneh (1987). "The Role of Peasant Institutions in Socialist Transformation and Rural Development". Peasants, Agrarian Socialism, and Rural Development in Ethiopia. Boulder: Westview Press. ISBN   081337247X.
  14. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Keller, Edmond J. (1988). Revolutionary Ethiopia: from Empire to People's Republic. Bloomington: Indiana University Press. pp. 227–230.
  15. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Giorgis, Dawit Wolde (1989). "Resettlement and Villagization". Red Tears: War, Famine and Revolution in Ethiopia. Trenton, NJ: The Red Sea Press.
  16. Giorgis, Dawit Wolde (1989). "The Cause of the Famine". Red Tears: War, Famine, and Revolution in Ethiopia. Trenton, NJ: The Red Sea Press. ISBN   0932415342.
  17. Pankhurst, Alula, 1962- (1992). Resettlement and famine in Ethiopia : the villagers' experience. Manchester University Press. pp. 17–18. ISBN   0719035376. OCLC   23769773.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  18. Giorgis. Red Tears. p. 290.
  19. 1 2 3 4 5 Dejene, Alemneh (1987). "Conclusion: Strategies for Growth and for Social Transformation". Peasants, Agrarian Socialism, and Rural Development in Ethiopia. Boulder: Westview Press. ISBN   081337247X.
  20. 1 2 Clapham, Christopher (1988). Transformation and Continuity in Revolutionary Ethiopia . New Rochelle, NY: Cambridge University Press.
  21. 1 2 3 Harbeson. The Ethiopian Transformation. pp. 197–199.
  22. 1 2 3 Giorgis. Red Tears. p. 306.
  23. Patrick Webb and Joachim von Braun, Famine and Food Security in Ethiopia: Lessons for Africa (Chichester: John Wiley and Sons, 1994), pp.42f
  24. Mengisteab, Kidane (1990). Ethiopia: Failure of Land Reform and Agricultural Crisis . New York: Greenwood Press. pp.  162–163.
  25. Wubneh, Mulatu; Abate, Yohannis (1988). Ethiopia: Transition and Development in the Horn of Africa . Boulder: Westview Press. pp.  95.
  26. Giorgis. Red Tears. p. 307.