Market concentration

Last updated

In economics, market concentration is a function of the number of firms and their respective shares of the total production (alternatively, total capacity or total reserves) in a market. [1] Market concentration is the portion of a given market's market share that is held by a small number of businesses. To ascertain whether an industry [2] is competitive or not, it is employed in antitrust law [3] and economic regulation. When market concentration is high, it indicates that a few firms dominate the market and oligopoly [4] or monopolistic competition is likely to exist. In most cases, high market concentration produces undesirable consequences such as reduced competition and higher prices. [5]

Contents

The market concentration ratio measures the concentration of the top firms in the market, this can be through various metrics such as sales, employment numbers, active users or other relevant indicators. [1] In theory and in practice, market concentration is closely associated with market competitiveness, and therefore is important to various antitrust agencies when considering proposed mergers and other regulatory issues. [6] Market concentration is important in determining firm market power in setting prices and quantities.

Market concentration is affected through various forces, including barriers to entry and existing competition. Market concentration ratios also allows users to more accurately determine the type of market structure they are observing, from a perfect competitive, to a monopolistic, monopoly or oligopolistic market structure. [7]

Market concentration is related to industrial concentration, which concerns the distribution of production within an industry, as opposed to a market. In industrial organization, market concentration may be used as a measure of competition, theorized to be positively related to the rate of profit in the industry, for example in the work of Joe S. Bain. [8]

An alternative economic interpretation is that market concentration is a criterion that can be used to rank order various distributions of firms' shares of the total production (alternatively, total capacity or total reserves) in a market.

Factors affecting market concentration

The 2020 Australian Telecommunications firms market share: an example of a highly concentrated market with an estimated HHI of 3034.

  Telstra (37%)
  Optus (30%)
  Vodafone (27%)
  Other (6%)

There are various factors that affect the concentration of specific markets which include; barriers to entry(high start-up costs, high economies of scale, brand loyalty), industry size and age, product differentiation and current advertising levels. There are also firm specific factors affecting market concentration, including: research and development levels, and the human capital requirements. [9]

Although fewer competitors doesn't always indicate high market concentration, it can be a strong indicator of the market structure and power allocation.

Metrics

After determining the relevant market and firms, through defining the product and geographical parameters, various metrics can be employed to determine the market concentration. This can be quantified using the SSNIP test.

A simple measure of market concentration is to calculate 1/N where N is the number of firms in the market. A result of 1 would indicate a pure monopoly, and will decrease with the number of active firms in the market, and nonincreasing in the degree of symmetry between them. [ clarification needed ] This measure of concentration ignores the dispersion among the firms' shares. This measure is practically useful only if a sample of firms' market shares is believed to be random, rather than determined by the firms' inherent characteristics.

Any criterion that can be used to compare or rank distributions (e.g. probability distribution, frequency distribution or size distribution) can be used as a market concentration criterion. Examples are stochastic dominance and Gini coefficient.

Herfindahl–Hirschman Index

The Herfindahl–Hirschman Index (HHI) (the most commonly used market concentration) is added portion of market attentiveness. It is derived by adding the squares of all the market participants [10] market shares. A higher HHI indicates a higher level of market concentration. A market concentration level of less than 1000 is typically seen as low, whilst one of more than 1500 is regarded as excessive.

Where is the market share of firm i, conventionally expressed as a percentage, [11] and N is the number of firms in the relevant market.

If market shares are expressed as decimals, an HHI of 0 represents a perfectly competitive industry while an HHI index of 1 represents a monopolised industry. Regardless whether the decimal or percentage HHI is used, a higher HHI indicates higher concentration within a market. [12]

Section 1 of the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission's Horizontal Merger Guidelines is entitled "Market Definition, Measurement and Concentration" and states that the Herfindahl index is the measure of concentration that these Guidelines will use. [13]

Herfindahl-Hirschman Index Thumbnail IMG 8662.png
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index

https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=jMJCLwBJYnQ

Concentration ratio

The concentration ratio (CR) is a measure of how concentrated a market is. [14] By dividing the overall market share by the sum of the market shares of the largest enterprises, it is calculated. It can be used to assess the market's strength over both the short and long haul. Generally speaking, a CR of less than 40% and a CR of more than 60% are regarded as modest and high levels of market concentration, respectively. This ratio measures the concentration of the largest firms in the form

where N is usually between 3 and 5.

Relationship between Market Structure and Market Concentration Metrics
Type of MarketCR RangeHHI Range
Monopoly16000 - 10 000 (Depending on Region)
Oligopoly0.5 - 12000 - 6000 (Depending on Region)
Competitive0 - 0.50 - 2000 (Depending on Region)

Regulatory usage

Historical usage

Since the introduction of the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890, in response to growing monopolies and anti-competitive firms in the 1880s, antitrust agencies regularly use market concentration as an important metric to evaluate potential violations of competition laws. [15] Since the passing of the act, these metrics have also been used to evaluate potential mergers' effect on overall market competition and overall consumer welfare. The first major example of the Sherman Act being imposed on a company to prevent potential consumer abuse through excessive market concentration was in the 1911 court case of Standard Oil Co. of New Jersey v. United States where after determining Standard Oil was monopolising the petroleum industry, the court-ordered remedy was the breakup into 34 smaller companies. [16]

Modern usage

Modern regulatory bodies state that an increase in market concentration can inhibit innovation, and have detrimental effects on overall consumer welfare.

The United States Department of Justice determined that any merger that increases the HHI by more than 200 proposes a legitimate concern to antitrust laws and consumer welfare . [17] Therefore, when considering potential mergers, especially in horizontal integration applications, antitrust agencies will consider the whether the increase in efficiency is worth the potential decrease in consumer welfare, through increased costs or reduction in quantity produced. [18]

Whereas the European Commission is unlikely to contest any horizontal integration, which post merger HHI is under 2000 (except in special circumstances). [19]

Modern examples of market concentration being utilised to protect consumer welfare include:

Motivation for firms

The relationship between market concentration and profitability can be divided into two arguments: greater market concentration increases the likelihood of collusion between firms which, resulting in higher pricing. In contrast, market concentration occurs as a result of the efficiency obtained in the course of being a large firm, which is more profitable in comparison to smaller firms and their lack of efficiency. [23]

Collusion

There are game theoretic models of market interaction (e.g. among oligopolists) that predict that an increase in market concentration will result in higher prices and lower consumer welfare even when collusion in the sense of cartelization (i.e. explicit collusion) is absent. Examples are Cournot oligopoly , and Bertrand oligopoly for differentiated products . Bain's (1956) original concern with market concentration was based on an intuitive relationship between high concentration and collusion which led to Bain's finding that firms in concentrated markets should be earning supra-competitive profits. [8] [24] Collins and Preston (1969) shared a similar view to Bain with focus on the reduced competitive impact of smaller firms upon larger firms. [25] Demsetz held an alternative view where he found a positive relationship between the margins of specifically the largest firms within a concentrated industry and collusion as to pricing. [26]

Although theoretical models predict a strong correlation between market concentration and collusion, there is little empirical evidence linking market concentration to the level of collusion in an industry. [27] In the scenario of a merger, some studies have also shown that the asymmetric market structure produced by a merger will negatively affect collusion despite the increased concentration of the market that occurs post-merger. [28]

Efficiency

As an economic tool market concentration is useful because it reflects the degree of competition in the market. Understanding the market concentration is important for firms when deciding their marketing strategy. As well, empirical evidence shows that there exists an inverse relationship between market concentration and efficiency, such that firms display an increase in efficiency when their relevant market concentration decreases. [29] The above positions of Bain (1956) as well as Collins and Preston (1969) are not only supportive of collusion but also of the efficiency-profitability hypothesis: profits are higher for bigger firms within a greater concentrated market as this concentration signifies greater efficiency through mass production. [30] In particular, economies of scale was the greatest kind of efficiency that large firms could achieve in influencing their costs, granting them greater market share. Notably however, Rosenbaum (1994) observed that most studies assumed the relationship between actual market share and observed profitability by following the implication that large firms hold greater market share due to their efficiency, demonstrating that the relationship between these efficiency and market share is not clearly defined. [23]

Industry effects

Implications of market concentration

A high level of market concentration can lead to a decrease in competition [31] and increased market power for the dominant firms. This might lead to greater costs, less quality, fewer options, and less innovation. Thus, consumers and society may be negatively impacted by large levels of market concentration.

Innovation

Schumpeter (1950) first recognised the relationship between market concentration and innovation in that a higher concentrated market would facilitate innovation. He reasoned that firms with the greatest market share have the greatest opportunity to benefit from their innovations, particularly through investment into R&D. [32] This can be contrasted with the position taken by Arrow (1962) that a greater market concentration will decrease incentive to innovate because a firm within a monopoly or monopolistic market would have already reached profit levels that greatly exceed costs. [33]

In practice, there are complications in observing the direct correlation between market concentration and its effect on. In collecting empirical evidence, issues have also arisen as to how innovation, a firm's control and gaps between R&D and firm size are measured. There has also been a lack of consensus. For example, a negative correlation was established by Connelly and Hirschey (1984) who explained that the correlation evidenced a decreased expenditure on R&D by oligopolistic firms to benefit from greater monopolised profits. However, Blundell et al. observed a positive correlation by tallying the patents lodged by firms. This general observation was also shared by Aghion et al. in 2005. [32]

Schumpeter also failed to distinguish between the different technologies that contribute to innovation and did not properly define “creative destruction”. Petit and Teece (2021) argued that technological opportunities, a variable which Schumpeter and Arrow did not include during their time, would be included in this definition as it enables new entrants to make a “breakthrough” into the industry. [33]

Research presented by Aghion et al. (2005) suggested an inverted U-shape model that represents the relationship between market concentration and innovation. Delbono and Lambertini modelled empirical evidence onto a graph and found that the pattern demonstrated by the data supported the existence of a U-shaped relationship between these two variables. [34]

Regulation of market concentration

The existence of economic regulations like the Competition Act and antitrust laws like the Sherman Act is due to the necessity of maintaining market competition in order to avoid the formation of monopolies. These laws typically require firms to report their market share and limit the degree of market concentration that is allowed. In some cases, antitrust laws may require the breakup of firms or the establishment of “firewalls” that prevent the potential abuse of power.

Market concentration reveals a market's degree of concentration. It is employed to ascertain the level of industrial competition. A high degree of market concentration is typically undesirable since it might result in less competition and more power for the leading enterprises on the market. Antitrust laws and other economic regulations safeguard market competition and the avoidance of monopolies.

Alternative metrics

Although not as common as the Herfindahl–Hirschman Index or Concentration Ratio metrics, various alternative measures of market concentration can also be used.

(a) The U Index (Davies, 1980):

where is an accepted measure of inequality (in practice the coefficient of variation is suggested), is a constant or a parameter (to be estimated empirically) and N is the number of firms. Davies (1979) suggests that a concentration index should in general depend on both N and the inequality of firms' shares.
The "number of effective competitors" is the inverse of the Herfindahl index.
Terrence Kavyu Muthoka defines distribution just as functionals in the Swartz space which is the space of functions with compact support and with all derivatives existing. The Media:Dirac_Distribution or the Dirac function is a good example.

(b) The Linda index (1976)

where Qi is the ratio between the average share of the first firms and the average share of the remaining firms and is the concentration coefficient for the first firms. Although it doesn't capture the peripheral firms like the HHI formula, it works to capture the "core" of the market, and masure the degree of inequality between the size variable accounted for by various sib-samples of firms. This index, does assume pre-calculation on the users' behalf to determine the relevant value of [35] However, there is little empirical evidence of regulatory usage of the Linda Index.

(c) Comprehensive concentration index (Horwath 1970):

Where s1 is the share of the largest firm. The index is similar to except that greater weight is assigned to the share of the largest firm. When compared to the HHI index, it does present some advantages, such as giving more weight to the quantity of small firms, however the arbitrary choice to only include the absolute value of one firm has led to criticism over its accuracy and usefulness. [36]

(d) The Rosenbluth (1961) index (also Hall and Tideman, 1967):

where symbol i indicates the firm's rank position.
The Rosenbluth index assigns more weight to smaller competitors when there are more firms present in the marketplace, and is sensitive to the amount of competitors in the market, even if there is a small amount of large firms dominating. Its coefficients and ranking are similar to results produced through the use of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index. [36]

(e) The Gini coefficient (1912)

The Gini coefficient measures the difference between firms' sizes without including the number of firms operating in a market. This is known as a relative concentration measure and differs from absolute concentration measures (like the Rosenbluth index) which includes the number of firms and firms' distribution sizes. It is used in conjunction with the Lorenz curve. Originally, the Lorenz curve measured the inequality of income distributed with a population and ranked individuals from highest to lowest earnings. [37] Therefore, in this context the Gini coefficient is located between the 45° line representing an equal distribution of income and the Lorenz curve representing the actual distribution of income within the population. [38] In a market concentration context, the Lorenz curve can be plotted ranking firms' market shares from smallest to largest to simulate a concentration curve. The firms’ cumulative percentage shares would remain on the y axis and the cumulative percentage of sellers would remain on the x axis. would the sum of weighted market share located in the area above the concentration curve. The Gini coefficient is 0 when the concentration curve aligns with the 45° line representing a single firm's market share, meaning the market is a monopoly. [37]

(f) Utilizing the power-law exponent (α) of the fitting curve on the out-degree distribution of the network (Pliatsidis, 2024) [39]

For a given set of nodes, each with degree k, the power-law exponent (α) serves as a pivotal metric for analyzing concentration within a network. This exponent characterizes the distribution of out-degrees among nodes, offering insights into the concentration of certain attributes or interactions within the system.
When α>0, a skewed distribution emerges where a small percentage of firms dominate the market.
As α approaches 0, the distribution flattens, indicating a more equitable distribution of contract awards.
Conversely, as α decreases below 0, the concentration among a select few firms diminishes further, suggesting a diversified market landscape.

See also

Related Research Articles

A monopoly, as described by Irving Fisher, is a market with the "absence of competition", creating a situation where a specific person or enterprise is the only supplier of a particular thing. This contrasts with a monopsony which relates to a single entity's control of a market to purchase a good or service, and with oligopoly and duopoly which consists of a few sellers dominating a market. Monopolies are thus characterised by a lack of economic competition to produce the good or service, a lack of viable substitute goods, and the possibility of a high monopoly price well above the seller's marginal cost that leads to a high monopoly profit. The verb monopolise or monopolize refers to the process by which a company gains the ability to raise prices or exclude competitors. In economics, a monopoly is a single seller. In law, a monopoly is a business entity that has significant market power, that is, the power to charge overly high prices, which is associated with a decrease in social surplus. Although monopolies may be big businesses, size is not a characteristic of a monopoly. A small business may still have the power to raise prices in a small industry.

An oligopoly is a market in which control over an industry lies in the hands of a few large sellers who own a dominant share of the market. Oligopolistic markets have homogenous products, few market participants, and inelastic demand for the products in those industries. As a result of their significant market power, firms in oligopolistic markets can influence prices through manipulating the supply function. Firms in an oligopoly are also mutually interdependent, as any action by one firm is expected to affect other firms in the market and evoke a reaction or consequential action. As a result, firms in oligopolistic markets often resort to collusion as means of maximising profits.

In economics, imperfect competition refers to a situation where the characteristics of an economic market do not fulfil all the necessary conditions of a perfectly competitive market. Imperfect competition causes market inefficiencies, resulting in market failure. Imperfect competition usually describes behaviour of suppliers in a market, such that the level of competition between sellers is below the level of competition in perfectly competitive market conditions.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Clayton Antitrust Act of 1914</span> US federal law

The Clayton Antitrust Act of 1914, is a part of United States antitrust law with the goal of adding further substance to the U.S. antitrust law regime; the Clayton Act seeks to prevent anticompetitive practices in their incipiency. That regime started with the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890, the first Federal law outlawing practices that were harmful to consumers. The Clayton Act specified particular prohibited conduct, the three-level enforcement scheme, the exemptions, and the remedial measures. Like the Sherman Act, much of the substance of the Clayton Act has been developed and animated by the U.S. courts, particularly the Supreme Court.

This aims to be a complete article list of economics topics:

<span class="mw-page-title-main">United States antitrust law</span> American legal system intended to promote competition among businesses

In the United States, antitrust law is a collection of mostly federal laws that regulate the conduct and organization of businesses in order to promote competition and prevent unjustified monopolies. The three main U.S. antitrust statutes are the Sherman Act of 1890, the Clayton Act of 1914, and the Federal Trade Commission Act of 1914. These acts serve three major functions. First, Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits price fixing and the operation of cartels, and prohibits other collusive practices that unreasonably restrain trade. Second, Section 7 of the Clayton Act restricts the mergers and acquisitions of organizations that may substantially lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly. Third, Section 2 of the Sherman Act prohibits monopolization.

Collusion is a deceitful agreement or secret cooperation between two or more parties to limit open competition by deceiving, misleading or defrauding others of their legal right. Collusion is not always considered illegal. It can be used to attain objectives forbidden by law; for example, by defrauding or gaining an unfair market advantage. It is an agreement among firms or individuals to divide a market, set prices, limit production or limit opportunities. It can involve "unions, wage fixing, kickbacks, or misrepresenting the independence of the relationship between the colluding parties". In legal terms, all acts effected by collusion are considered void.

In economics, concentration ratios are used to quantify market concentration and are based on companies' market shares in a given industry.

The Herfindahl index is a measure of the size of firms in relation to the industry they are in and is an indicator of the amount of competition among them. Named after economists Orris C. Herfindahl and Albert O. Hirschman, it is an economic concept widely applied in competition law, antitrust regulation, and technology management. HHI has continued to be used by antitrust authorities, primarily to evaluate and understand how mergers will affect their associated markets. HHI is calculated by squaring the market share of each competing firm in the industry and then summing the resulting numbers. The result is proportional to the average market share, weighted by market share. As such, it can range from 0 to 1.0, moving from a huge number of very small firms to a single monopolistic producer. Increases in the HHI generally indicate a decrease in competition and an increase of market power, whereas decreases indicate the opposite. Alternatively, the index can be expressed per 10,000 "points". For example, an index of .25 is the same as 2,500 points.

Anti-competitive practices are business or government practices that prevent or reduce competition in a market. Antitrust laws ensure businesses do not engage in competitive practices that harm other, usually smaller, businesses or consumers. These laws are formed to promote healthy competition within a free market by limiting the abuse of monopoly power. Competition allows companies to compete in order for products and services to improve; promote innovation; and provide more choices for consumers. In order to obtain greater profits, some large enterprises take advantage of market power to hinder survival of new entrants. Anti-competitive behavior can undermine the efficiency and fairness of the market, leaving consumers with little choice to obtain a reasonable quality of service.

In theories of competition in economics, a barrier to entry, or an economic barrier to entry, is a fixed cost that must be incurred by a new entrant, regardless of production or sales activities, into a market that incumbents do not have or have not had to incur. Because barriers to entry protect incumbent firms and restrict competition in a market, they can contribute to distortionary prices and are therefore most important when discussing antitrust policy. Barriers to entry often cause or aid the existence of monopolies and oligopolies, or give companies market power. Barriers of entry also have an importance in industries. First of all it is important to identify that some exist naturally, such as brand loyalty. Governments can also create barriers to entry to meet consumer protection laws, protecting the public. In other cases it can also be due to inherent scarcity of public resources needed to enter a market.

Competition law is the field of law that promotes or seeks to maintain market competition by regulating anti-competitive conduct by companies. Competition law is implemented through public and private enforcement. It is also known as antitrust law, anti-monopoly law, and trade practices law; the act of pushing for antitrust measures or attacking monopolistic companies is commonly known as trust busting.

In economics, market power refers to the ability of a firm to influence the price at which it sells a product or service by manipulating either the supply or demand of the product or service to increase economic profit. In other words, market power occurs if a firm does not face a perfectly elastic demand curve and can set its price (P) above marginal cost (MC) without losing revenue. This indicates that the magnitude of market power is associated with the gap between P and MC at a firm's profit maximising level of output. The size of the gap, which encapsulates the firm's level of market dominance, is determined by the residual demand curve's form. A steeper reverse demand indicates higher earnings and more dominance in the market. Such propensities contradict perfectly competitive markets, where market participants have no market power, P = MC and firms earn zero economic profit. Market participants in perfectly competitive markets are consequently referred to as 'price takers', whereas market participants that exhibit market power are referred to as 'price makers' or 'price setters'.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Market structure</span> Differentiation of firms by goods and operations

Market structure, in economics, depicts how firms are differentiated and categorised based on the types of goods they sell (homogeneous/heterogeneous) and how their operations are affected by external factors and elements. Market structure makes it easier to understand the characteristics of diverse markets.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Competition Act 1998</span> United Kingdom legislation

The Competition Act 1998 is the current major source of competition law in the United Kingdom, along with the Enterprise Act 2002. The act provides an updated framework for identifying and dealing with restrictive business practices and abuse of a dominant market position.

Market dominance is the control of a economic market by a firm. A dominant firm possesses the power to affect competition and influence market price. A firms' dominance is a measure of the power of a brand, product, service, or firm, relative to competitive offerings, whereby a dominant firm can behave independent of their competitors or consumers, and without concern for resource allocation. Dominant positioning is both a legal concept and an economic concept and the distinction between the two is important when determining whether a firm's market position is dominant.

Merger guidelines in the United States are a set of internal rules promulgated by the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice (DOJ) in conjunction with the Federal Trade Commission (FTC). These rules have been revised over the past four decades. They govern the process by which these two regulatory bodies scrutinize and/or challenge a potential merger. Grounds for challenges include increased market concentration and threat to competition within a relevant market.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Tacit collusion</span> Collusion between competitors

Tacit collusion is a collusion between competitors who do not explicitly exchange information but achieve an agreement about coordination of conduct. There are two types of tacit collusion: concerted action and conscious parallelism. In a concerted action also known as concerted activity, competitors exchange some information without reaching any explicit agreement, while conscious parallelism implies no communication. In both types of tacit collusion, competitors agree to play a certain strategy without explicitly saying so. It is also called oligopolistic price coordination or tacit parallelism.

European Union merger law is a part of the law of the European Union. It is charged with regulating mergers between two or more entities in a corporate structure. This institution has jurisdiction over concentrations that might or might not impede competition. Although mergers must comply with policies and regulations set by the commission; certain mergers are exempt if they promote consumer welfare. Mergers that fail to comply with the common market may be blocked. It is part of competition law and is designed to ensure that firms do not acquire such a degree of market power on the free market so as to harm the interests of consumers, the economy and society as a whole. Specifically, the level of control may lead to higher prices, less innovation and production.

Competition law theory covers the strands of thought relating to competition law or antitrust policy.

References

  1. 1 2 "What is Market Concentration? Definition of Market Concentration, Market Concentration Meaning". The Economic Times. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  2. "Industry", Wikipedia, 2023-01-23, retrieved 2023-04-24
  3. "Competition law", Wikipedia, 2023-04-12, retrieved 2023-04-24
  4. "Oligopoly", Wikipedia, 2023-04-24, retrieved 2023-04-24
  5. Turner, Scott F.; Mitchell, Will; Bettis, Richard A. (2010). "Responding to Rivals and Complements: How Market Concentration Shapes Generational Product Innovation Strategy". Organization Science. 21 (4): 856. doi:10.1287/orsc.1090.0486. hdl: 10161/4440 .
  6. "What We Can Learn from Merger Deals That Never Happened". Harvard Business Review. 2016-06-21. ISSN   0017-8012 . Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  7. "Market structure", Wikipedia, 2023-04-23, retrieved 2023-04-24
  8. 1 2 Bain, Joe, S (1951). "Relation of Profit Rate to Industry Concentration: American Manufacturing, 1936-1940". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 65 (3): 293–324. doi:10.2307/1882217. JSTOR   1882217 via JSTOR.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  9. Janashvili '02, David (2002-04-26). "Market Concentration: The Effects of Technology". Honors Projects.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)
  10. "Market participant", Wikipedia, 2021-03-29, retrieved 2023-04-24
  11. "Herfindahl-Hirschman Index - United States Department of Justice". US Department of Justice. 25 June 2015. Retrieved 2022-11-09.
  12. Evans, Anthony J. (2014). Markets for Managers: A Managerial Economics Primer. John Wiley & Sons Ltd. p. 69.
  13. "Herfindahl-Hirschman Index". www.justice.gov. 2015-06-25. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  14. J. Gregory Sidak, Evaluating Market Power Using Competitive Benchmark Prices Instead of the Hirschman-Herfindahl Index, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 387, 387-388 (2007).
  15. Brock, James W.; Obst, Norman P. (2009-03-01). "Market Concentration, Economic Welfare, and Antitrust Policy". Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade. 9 (1): 65–75. doi:10.1007/s10842-007-0026-6. ISSN   1573-7012. S2CID   154631137.
  16. "Standard Oil | History, Monopoly, & Breakup". Encyclopædia Britannica. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  17. "HERFINDAHL-HIRSCHMAN INDEX". The United States Department of Justice. 25 June 2015.
  18. Brock, James W.; Obst, Norman P. (2007-10-03). "Market Concentration, Economic Welfare, and Antitrust Policy". Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade. 9 (1): 65–75. doi:10.1007/s10842-007-0026-6. ISSN   1566-1679. S2CID   154631137.
  19. "EUR-Lex - 52004XC0205(02) - EN". Official Journal C 031, 05/02/2004, p. 0005-0018. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  20. Fernholz, Tim (13 February 2014). "Why the Time Warner-Comcast merger isn't going to happen—at least the way it looks today". Quartz. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  21. "Halliburton and Baker Hughes Abandon Anticompetitive Merger". www.justice.gov. 2017-03-15. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  22. Baker, Mark (9 April 2008). "U.S./EU: Analysis -- What Killed The GE-Honeywell Merger?". Radio Free Europe/Radio Liberty. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  23. 1 2 Rosenbaum, David I. (1994). "Efficiency v. Collusion: Evidence Cast in Cement". Review of Industrial Organization. 9 (4): 379–392. doi:10.1007/BF01029512. JSTOR   41798521. S2CID   153620070.
  24. Schmalensee, Richard (1987). "Inter-Industry Studies of Structure and Performance". Handbook of Industrial Organization. (Working Paper No. 1874-87).
  25. Collins, Norman R.; Preston, Lee E. (1969). "Price-Cost Margins and Industry Structure". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 51 (3): 271–286. doi:10.2307/1926562. JSTOR   1926562.
  26. Demsetz, Harold (1973). "Industry Structure, Market Rivalry, and Public Policy". Journal of Law and Economics. 16 (1): 1–9. doi:10.1086/466752. JSTOR   724822. S2CID   154506488.
  27. Salinger, Michael (1990). "The Concentration-Margins Relationship Reconsidered" (PDF). Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Microeconomics. 1990: 287–335. doi:10.2307/2534784. JSTOR   2534784.
  28. Fonseca, Miguel A.; Normann, Hans-Theo (2008). "Mergers, Asymmetries and Collusion: Experimental Evidence". The Economic Journal. 118 (527): 387–400. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02126.x. JSTOR   20108803. S2CID   154378955.
  29. "Highly concentrated markets are bad for consumers and bad for investors". MoneyWeek. 21 May 2019. Retrieved 2021-04-28.
  30. Martin, Stephen (1988). "Market Power and/or Efficiency?". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 70 (2): 331–335. doi:10.2307/1928318. JSTOR   1928318.
  31. "Competition", Wikipedia, 2023-03-15, retrieved 2023-04-24
  32. 1 2 Sonenshine, Ralph M. (2010). "The Stock Market's Valuation of R&D and Market Concentration in Horizontal Mergers". Review of Industrial Organization. 37 (2): 119–140. doi:10.1007/s11151-010-9262-8. JSTOR   41799483. S2CID   155085616.
  33. 1 2 Petit, Nicolas; Teece, David J. (2021). "Original Article Innovating Big Tech firms and competition policy: favoring dynamic over static competition". Industrial and Corporate Change. 30 (1168–1198). doi: 10.1093/icc/dtab049 . hdl: 1814/74432 .
  34. Delbono, Flavio; Lambertini, Luca (2022). "Innovation and product market concentration: Schumpeter, arrow, and the inverted U-shape curve". Oxford Economic Papers. 74 (1): 297–311. doi:10.1093/oep/gpaa044. hdl: 11585/831079 .
  35. Bukvić, Rajko; Pavlović, Radica; Gajić, Аlеksаndаr M. (2014). "Possibilities of Application of the Index Concentration of Linda in Small Economy: Example of Serbian Food Industries". mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de. Retrieved 2021-04-27.
  36. 1 2 Romualdas, Stasys, Ginevičius, Čirba (2009). "Additive measurement of Market Concentration". Journal of Business Economics and Management. 10 (3): 191–198. doi: 10.3846/1611-1699.2009.10.191-198 .{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  37. 1 2 du Pisanie, Johann (2013). "Concentration Measures as an element in testing the structure-conduct-performance paradigm" (PDF). Economic Research Southern Africa. (Working Papers No. 345).
  38. Palan, Nicole (2010). "Measurement of Specialization # The Choice of Indices" (PDF). Research Centre International Economics, Vienna. (FIW Working Paper No. 62).
  39. Pliatsidis, Andreas Christos (2024-02-12). "Analyzing concentration in the Greek public procurement market: a network theory approach". Journal of Industrial and Business Economics. doi:10.1007/s40812-023-00291-z. ISSN   1972-4977.