Dispersed knowledge

Last updated

Dispersed knowledge in economics is the notion that no single agent has information as to all of the factors which influence prices and production throughout the system. [1] The term has been both expanded upon and popularized by American economist Thomas Sowell. [2]

Contents

Overview

Each agent in a market for assets, goods, or services possesses incomplete knowledge as to most of the factors which affect prices in that market. For example, no agent has full information as to other agents' budgets, preferences, resources or technologies, not to mention their plans for the future and numerous other factors which affect prices in those markets. [3]

Market prices are the result of price discovery, in which each agent participating in the market makes use of its current knowledge and plans to decide on the prices and quantities at which it chooses to transact. The resulting prices and quantities of transactions may be said to reflect the current state of knowledge of the agents currently in the market, even though no single agent commands information as to the entire set of such knowledge. [4]

Some economists believe that market transactions provide the basis for a society to benefit from the knowledge that is dispersed among its constituent agents. For example, in his Principles of Political Economy, John Stuart Mill states that one of the justifications for a laissez faire government policy is his belief that self-interested individuals throughout the economy, acting independently, can make better use of dispersed knowledge than could the best possible government agency. [5]

Dispersed knowledge.png

Key characteristics

Friedrich Hayek claimed that "dispersed knowledge is essentially dispersed, and cannot possibly be gathered together and conveyed to an authority charged with the task of deliberately creating order". [6]

Today, the best and most comprehensive book on dispersed knowledge is Knowledge and Decisions by Thomas Sowell, which Hayek called "the best book on general economics in many a year." [7]

Phenomena

Drivers

  1. Large numbers: Large numbers have a great impact on actions in terms of two aspects. On the one hand, there will be an increase in time and other resource requirements. On the other hand, actors with bounded cognitive resources will lose overview.
  2. Asymmetries: Asymmetries have a two-sides effect. Firstly, asymmetries enable more possibilities regarding learning and competence development. Secondly, asymmetries "increase differences between interpretative frameworks and the knowledge and competence profile of the different actors and thus make integration more difficult".
  3. Uncertainty: Uncertainty is defined to be one of the drivers of dispersed knowledge which can give rise to management problems. [9]

Uncertainty

Dispersed knowledge will give rise to uncertainty which will lead to different kinds of results.

Richard LeFauve highlights the advantages of organizational structure in companies:

"Before if we had a tough decision to make, we would have two or three different perspectives with strong support of all three. In a traditional organization the bossman decides after he’s heard all three alternatives. At Saturn we take time to work it out, and what generally happens is that you end up with a fourth answer which none of the portions had in the first place. but one that all three portions of the organization fully support (AutoWeeR, Oct. 8, 1990. p. 20)."

Companies are supposed to think highly of the dispersed knowledge and make adjustments to meet demands. [10]

Tsoukas stated:

"A firm’s knowledge is distributed, not only in a computational sense . . . or in Hayek’s (1945, p. 521) sense that the factual knowledge of the particular circumstances of time and place cannot be surveyed as a whole. But, more radically, a firm’s knowledge is distributed in the sense that it is inherently indeterminate: nobody knows in advance what that knowledge is or need be. Firms are faced with radical uncertainty: they do not, they cannot, know what they need to know." [11]

Strategies

There are several strategies targeting at the problems caused by dispersed knowledge.

First of all, replacing knowledge by getting access to knowledge can be one of the strategies. [12] [13]

What's more, the capability to complete incomplete knowledge can deal with knowledge gaps created by the dispersed knowledge.

In addition, making a design of institutions with reasonable coordination mechanisms can be regarded as the third strategy. [14]

Besides, resolving organization units into smaller ones should be taken into consideration. [15]

Last but not least, providing more data to decision maker will be helpful for making a correct decision.

See also

Related Research Articles

The economic calculation problem is a criticism of using economic planning as a substitute for market-based allocation of the factors of production. It was first proposed by Ludwig von Mises in his 1920 article "Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth" and later expanded upon by Friedrich Hayek.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Friedrich Hayek</span> Austrian–British economist, philosopher, and Nobel Laureate (1899–1992)

Friedrich August von Hayek, often referred to by his initials F. A. Hayek, was an Austrian-British economist and political philosopher who made contributions to economics, political philosophy, psychology, intellectual history, and other fields. Hayek shared the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences with Gunnar Myrdal for work on money and economic fluctuations, and the interdependence of economic, social and institutional phenomena. His account of how prices communicate information is widely regarded as an important contribution to economics that led to him receiving the prize.

Satisficing is a decision-making strategy or cognitive heuristic that entails searching through the available alternatives until an acceptability threshold is met. The term satisficing, a portmanteau of satisfy and suffice, was introduced by Herbert A. Simon in 1956, although the concept was first posited in his 1947 book Administrative Behavior. Simon used satisficing to explain the behavior of decision makers under circumstances in which an optimal solution cannot be determined. He maintained that many natural problems are characterized by computational intractability or a lack of information, both of which preclude the use of mathematical optimization procedures. He observed in his Nobel Prize in Economics speech that "decision makers can satisfice either by finding optimum solutions for a simplified world, or by finding satisfactory solutions for a more realistic world. Neither approach, in general, dominates the other, and both have continued to co-exist in the world of management science".

In economics and related disciplines, a transaction cost is a cost in making any economic trade when participating in a market. The idea that transactions form the basis of economic thinking was introduced by the institutional economist John R. Commons in 1931, and Oliver E. Williamson's Transaction Cost Economics article, published in 2008, popularized the concept of transaction costs. Douglass C. North argues that institutions, understood as the set of rules in a society, are key in the determination of transaction costs. In this sense, institutions that facilitate low transaction costs, boost economic growth.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Vertical integration</span> When a company owns its supply chain

In microeconomics, management and international political economy, vertical integration is an arrangement in which the supply chain of a company is integrated and owned by that company. Usually each member of the supply chain produces a different product or (market-specific) service, and the products combine to satisfy a common need. It contrasts with horizontal integration, wherein a company produces several items that are related to one another. Vertical integration has also described management styles that bring large portions of the supply chain not only under a common ownership but also into one corporation.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">X-inefficiency</span>

X-inefficiency - is a concept used in economics to describe instances where firms go through internal inefficiency resulting in higher production costs than required for a given output. This inefficiency is a result of various factors such as outdated technology, Inefficient production processes, poor management and lack of competition resulting in lower profits and higher prices for consumers. The concept of X-inefficiency was introduced by Harvey Leibenstein.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Information asymmetry</span> Concept in contract theory and economics

In contract theory and economics, information asymmetry deals with the study of decisions in transactions where one party has more or better information than the other.

Managerial economics is a branch of economics involving the application of economic methods in the organizational decision-making process. Economics is the study of the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. Managerial economics involves the use of economic theories and principles to make decisions regarding the allocation of scarce resources. It guides managers in making decisions relating to the company's customers, competitors, suppliers, and internal operations.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Paul Milgrom</span> Economist and winner of the 2020 Nobel Prize in Economics

Paul Robert Milgrom is an American economist. He is the Shirley and Leonard Ely Professor of Humanities and Sciences at the Stanford University School of Humanities and Sciences, a position he has held since 1987. He is a professor in the Stanford School of Engineering as well and a Senior Fellow at the Stanford Institute for Economic Research. Milgrom is an expert in game theory, specifically auction theory and pricing strategies. He is the winner of the 2020 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences, together with Robert B. Wilson, "for improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats".

The theory of the firm consists of a number of economic theories that explain and predict the nature of the firm, company, or corporation, including its existence, behaviour, structure, and relationship to the market. Firms are key drivers in economics, providing goods and services in return for monetary payments and rewards. Organisational structure, incentives, employee productivity, and information all influence the successful operation of a firm in the economy and within itself. As such major economic theories such as Transaction cost theory, Managerial economics and Behavioural theory of the firm will allow for an in-depth analysis on various firm and management types.

Information economics or the economics of information is the branch of microeconomics that studies how information and information systems affect an economy and economic decisions.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Armen Alchian</span> American economist (1914–2013)

Armen Albert Alchian was an American economist. He spent almost his entire career at the University of California, Los Angeles (UCLA). A major microeconomic theorist, he is known as one of the founders of new institutional economics and widely acknowledged for his work on property rights.

An agency cost is an economic concept that refers to the costs associated with the relationship between a "principal", and an "agent". The agent is given powers to make decisions on behalf of the principal. However, the two parties may have different incentives and the agent generally has more information. The principal cannot directly ensure that its agent is always acting in its best interests. This potential divergence in interests is what gives rise to agency costs.

In contract theory, signalling is the idea that one party credibly conveys some information about itself to another party.

A price signal is information conveyed to consumers and producers, via the prices offered or requested for, and the amount requested or offered of a product or service, which provides a signal to increase or decrease quantity supplied or quantity demanded. It also provides potential business opportunities. When a certain kind of product is in shortage supply and the price rises, people will pay more attention to and produce this kind of product. The information carried by prices is an essential function in the fundamental coordination of an economic system, coordinating things such as what has to be produced, how to produce it and what resources to use in its production.

George Lennox Sharman Shackle was an English economist. He made a practical attempt to challenge classical rational choice theory and has been characterised as a "post-Keynesian", though he is influenced as well by Austrian economics. Much of his work is associated with the Dempster–Shafer theory of evidence.

"The Use of Knowledge in Society" is a scholarly article written by economist Friedrich Hayek, first published in the September 1945 issue of The American Economic Review.

In economics, the local knowledge problem is the argument that the data required for rational economic planning are distributed among individual actors and thus unavoidably exist outside the knowledge of a central authority.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">A Behavioral Theory of the Firm</span> Book by Richard Cyert

The behavioral theory of the firm first appeared in the 1963 book A Behavioral Theory of the Firm by Richard M. Cyert and James G. March. The work on the behavioral theory started in 1952 when March, a political scientist, joined Carnegie Mellon University, where Cyert was an economist.

Margaret E. Slade is Professor Emeritus at the Vancouver School of Economics at the University of British Columbia and was a council member of the Royal Economic Society from 2004–2008. Slade is best known for her work on Industrial Economics, serving as the President of the European Association for Research in Industrial Economics (EARIE) from 2001–2003.

References

  1. Hayek, Friedrich (1 September 1945). "The use of knowledge in society". The American Economic Review. 35 (4): 519–530. ISSN   0002-8282. JSTOR   1809376.
  2. "Book review: Knowledge and Decisions by Thomas Sowell - LessWrong". www.lesswrong.com. Retrieved 2022-02-02.
  3. Hayek, Friedrich (1973). Law, Legislation and Liberty. University of Chicago Press. pp. 11–16, 42, 51. ISBN   978-0-226-32086-1.
  4. Menger, Carl; Louis, Schneider (1963). Problems of Economics and Sociology . University of Illinois Press.
  5. Mill, John Stuart (1909). Ashley, William James (ed.). Principles of Political Economy (7th ed.). London: Longmans, Green and Co.
  6. Hayek, Friedrich (1988). The fatal conceit: The errors of socialism. London: Routledge. ISBN   978-0415008204.
  7. Friedrich August von Hayek (Dec 1, 1981). "The Best Book on General Economics in Many a Year". Reason .
  8. Dew, Nicholas; Velamuri, S. Ramakrishna; Venkataraman, Sankaran (2004). "Dispersed knowledge and an entrepreneurial theory of the firm" (PDF). Journal of Business Venturing. 19 (5): 659–679. doi:10.1016/j.jbusvent.2003.09.004. hdl:10945/41244. ISSN   0883-9026. S2CID   154877523.
  9. Becker, Markus C (16 December 2002). "Managing Dispersed Knowledge: Organizational Problems, Managerial Strategies, and Their Effectiveness". Journal of Management Studies . 38 (7): 1037–1051. doi:10.1111/1467-6486.00271. ISSN   0022-2380.
  10. Minkler, Alanson P (November 1993). "The Problem with Dispersed Knowledge: Firms in Theory and Practice". Kyklos. 46 (4): 569–587. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6435.1993.tb00499.x. ISSN   0023-5962.
  11. Tsoukas, Haridimos (1996). "The firm as a distributed knowledge system: A constructionist approach". Strategic Management Journal. 17: 11–25. doi:10.1002/smj.4250171104. ISSN   0143-2095.
  12. Cohen, Wesley M; Levinthal, Daniel A (1990). "Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on Learning and Innovation". Administrative Science Quarterly. 35 (1): 128–152. doi:10.2307/2393553. ISSN   0001-8392. JSTOR   2393553.
  13. Nahapiet, Janine; Ghoshal, Sumantra (1998). "Social capital, intellectual capital, and the organizational advantage". The Academy of Management Review. 23 (2): 242–266. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.598.8940 . doi:10.5465/amr.1998.533225. ISSN   0363-7425. JSTOR   259373.
  14. Burkley, Peter J; Carter, Martin J (1999). "Managing Cross-Border Complementary Knowledge: Conceptual Developments in the Business Process Approach to Knowledge Management in Multinational Firms". International Studies of Management & Organization. 29 (1): 80–104. doi:10.1080/00208825.1999.11656758. ISSN   0020-8825. JSTOR   40397436.
  15. Luce, R Duncan; Howard, Raiffa (1957). Games and decisions : introduction and critical survey . New York: Dover Publications. ISBN   978-0486659435.