James Malcomson is a British-Irish economist. He is an emeritus Professor of Economics at the University of Oxford [1] and emeritus Fellow of All Souls College. [2] He is a specialist in the fields of labour economics and contract theory.
Following graduation with a BA in economics at Gonville and Caius College, Cambridge, in 1967, Malcomson studied for a doctorate in economics at Harvard University, which he completed in 1973 [3] with a thesis supervised by the Nobel laureate Wassily Leontief.
Malcomson was a lecturer, then senior lecturer, at the University of York (1972–85), Professor of Economics at the University of Southampton (1985–1999) and then statutory Professor of Economics at the University of Oxford and Fellow of All Souls College (1999–2013). He was elected Fellow of the British Academy in 2000 and Fellow of the Econometric Society in 2005. [4] He chaired [5] the Office of Health Economics Commission on Competition in the NHS, 2011–2012 [6] and served as a member of the Review Body on Doctors' and Dentists' Remuneration, 2015–2021. [7]
Malcomson's early research analysed vintage effects in investment, especially the implications for obsolescence, replacement and utilisation of capital equipment and the effects of tax policy on these. He derived rigorous theoretical models of optimal investment and replacement that do not rely on stationarity (1), [8] showed how optimal policies relate to simple rules, and derived analytic results for the effects of changes in tax policy on investment and replacement (3). [9] He also devised ways to estimate such models empirically without imposing stationarity, an essential step in predicting the short-run effects of tax policy changes (2). [10] [11] He additionally explored dynamic inconsistency in government policies (6), [12] the Laffer Curve (7), [13] and the impact of trade unions (9). [14]
Malcomson's empirical research on production convinced him of the need for economists to understand better the labour side of the production process and much of his more recent research has been directed towards that. [15] One of his main concerns has been with different ways of motivating employees when important aspects of performance are not easily specified in an employment contract and their implications: high pay coupled with the threat of dismissal for unsatisfactory performance (efficiency wages) (4), [16] [17] competition for promotion (5), [18] [19] [20] [21] tournaments (8) [22] and repeated interaction over time (10), [23] which "showed that the optimal long-term contract can be replicated by a sequence of optimal static contracts when the agent's saving decision can be controlled by the principal." [24] With W. Bentley MacLeod, he characterized the full set of outcomes that can be sustained in such repeated principal-agent contexts (12), described as "the "classic" relational contract model" [25] and "(t)he most complete analysis of relational contracts under symmetric information". [26] Together they also showed in (11) that tournaments and competition for promotion can provide effective methods of motivation provided agent-employees are sufficiently heterogeneous in their abilities, a system that "mimics a remarkable number of the features of actual job ladders in internal labor markets". [27] Performance-related bonuses are effective even when agent-employees are homogeneous but may result in less efficient outcomes than efficiency wages when prospective employees are plentiful relative to jobs (18). [28] But when employees differ in abilities, competition for promotion may be open to influence activities and so distort allocation of employees to more senior jobs (21) [29] [30] [31] and efficient outcomes in the future prevent full separation of abilities when differences are sufficiently fine (26) in which "Malcomson provides a general analysis of relational contracts with persistent private information. He shows that full revelation of information is inconsistent with continuation payoffs being on the Pareto frontier, and therefore it generalizes the observation that asymmetric information leads to conflict in relational contracts." [32] This approach has been taken up in the subsequent literature. [33] These results have implications for dual economies (18) and cyclical behavior (14), in which the "interplay between competition and relational contracts also has implications for output over the business cycle". [34] The implications for labour markets are surveyed in (15) and, more completely, in (19) [35] and those for economic organizations in (25).
Other research with W. Bentley MacLeod has shown that the types of contracts used in many practical situations have properties that theory suggests are appropriate for protecting investments in general and specific assets (13). [36] [37] Research with other co-authors has shown how time-serving apprenticeships can mitigate incentive issues in training (22) [38] and the role for not-for-profit providers in provision of public sector services (27). [39] Malcomson also analysed forms of contract appropriate for the provision of health services (23), (24) [40] [41] and, most notably, the quality of care (16) and (17), developments surveyed in (20). [42]
(1) Malcomson, James M. (February 1975). "Replacement and the rental value of capital equipment subject to obsolescence". Journal of Economic Theory. 10 (1): 24–41. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(75)90059-9.
(2) Malcomson, James M.; Prior, Michael J. (October 1979). "The estimation of a vintage model of production for U.K. manufacturing". Review of Economic Studies. 46 (4): 719–736. doi:10.2307/2297038. JSTOR 2297038.
(3) "Corporate tax policy and the service life of capital equipment", Review of Economic Studies, 48(2), April 1981, 311–316. Print ISSN 0034-6527 Online ISSN 1467-937X https://doi.org/10.2307/2296887
(4) "Unemployment and the efficiency wage hypothesis", Economic Journal, 91(364), December 1981, 848–866. Print ISSN 0013-0133 Online ISSN 1468-029 https://doi.org/10.2307/2232496
(5) "Work incentives, hierarchy, and internal labor markets", Journal of Political Economy, 92(3), June 1984, 486–507. Print ISSN 0022-3808 E-ISSN 1537-534X JSTOR 1837229. Reprinted in George A. Akerlof and Janet L. Yellen (eds.), Efficiency Wage Models of the Labor Market (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1986), 157–178. ISBN 978-0-521-32156-3 E ISBN 978-0-511-55959-4 doi : 10.1017/CBO9780511559594.011
(6) "Dynamic inconsistency, rational expectations, and optimal government policy" (with Brian Hillier), Econometrica, 52(6), November 1984, 1437–1451. Print ISSN 0012-9682 Online ISSN 1468-0262 doi : 10.2307/1913514
(7) "Some analytics of the Laffer curve", Journal of Public Economics, 29(3), April 1986, 263–279. Print ISSN 0047-2727 Online ISSN 1879-2316 doi : 10.1016/0047-2727(86)90029-0
(8) "Rank-order contracts for a principal with many agents", Review of Economic Studies, 53(5), October 1986, 807–817. Print ISSN 0034-6527 Online ISSN 1467-937X doi : 10.2307/2297720
(9) "Tax push inflation in a unionized labour market" (with Nicola Sartor), European Economic Review, 31(8), December 1987, 1581–1596. Print ISSN 0014-2921 Online ISSN 1873-572X doi : 10.1016/S0014-2921(87)80027-2
(10) "The multiperiod principal-agent problem" (with Frans Spinnewyn), Review of Economic Studies, 55(3), July 1988, 391–407. Print ISSN 0034-6527 Online ISSN 1467-937X doi : 10.2307/2297391
(11) "Reputation and hierarchy in dynamic models of employment" (with W. Bentley MacLeod), Journal of Political Economy, 96(4), August 1988, 832–854. Print ISSN 0022-3808 E-ISSN 1537-534X JSTOR 1830476
(12) "Implicit contracts, incentive compatibility, and involuntary unemployment" (with W. Bentley MacLeod), Econometrica, 57(2), March 1989, 447–480. Print ISSN 0012-9682 Online ISSN 1468-0262 https://doi.org/10.2307/1912562. Reprinted in Patrick Bolton (ed.), The Economics of Contracts, vol. 2, chapter 12 (Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, 2008) ISBN 978-1-84064-416-6 https://www.e-elgar.com/shop/gbp/the-economics-of-contracts-9781840644166.html and in David Martimort (ed.), The Economic Theory of Incentives, vol. II, chapter 11 (Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, 2017) ISBN 978-1-78536-443-3 https://www.e-elgar.com/shop/gbp/the-economic-theory-of-incentives-9781785364433.html
(13) "Investments, holdup, and the form of market contracts" (with W. Bentley MacLeod), American Economic Review, 83(4), September 1993, 811–837. Print ISSN 0002-8282 Online ISSN 1944-7981 JSTOR 2117580
(14) "Labor turnover and the natural rate of unemployment: efficiency wage versus frictional unemployment" (with W. Bentley MacLeod and Paul Gomme), Journal of Labor Economics, 12(2), April 1994, 276–315. Print ISSN 0734-306X E-ISSN 1537-5307 JSTOR 2535277
(15) "Contracts, hold-up, and labor markets", Journal of Economic Literature, 35(4), December 1997, 1916–1957. Print ISSN 0022-0515 Online ISSN 2328-8175 JSTOR 2729883
(16) "Contracting for health services when patient demand does not reflect quality" (with Martin Chalkley), Journal of Health Economics, 17(1), January 1998, 1–19. Print ISSN 0167-6296 Online ISSN 1879-1646 doi : 10.1016/S0167-6296(97)00019-2
(17) "Contracting for health services with unmonitored quality" (with Martin Chalkley), Economic Journal, 108(449), July 1998, 1093–1110. Print ISSN 0013-0133 Online ISSN 1468-0297 doi : 10.1111/1468-0297.00331
(18) "Motivation and markets" (with W. Bentley MacLeod), American Economic Review, 88(3), June 1998, 388–411. Print ISSN 0002-8282 Online ISSN 1944-7981 JSTOR 116841
(19) "Individual employment contracts" in Orley Ashenfelter and David Card (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, vol. 3B (Elsevier Science, Amsterdam, 1999), chapter 35, 2291–2372. ISBN 978-0-444-50188-2 doi : 10.1016/S1573-4463(99)30021-3
(20) "Government purchasing of health services" (with Martin Chalkley) in Anthony J. Culyer and Joseph P. Newhouse (eds.), Handbook of Health Economics, vol. 1A, chapter 15 (Elsevier Science, Amsterdam, 2000), 847–890. ISBN 978-0-444-50470-8 doi : 10.1016/S1574-0064(00)80174-2
(21) "Performance, promotion, and the Peter Principle" (with James A. Fairburn), Review of Economic Studies, 68(1), January 2001, 45–66. Print ISSN 0034-6527 EISSN 1467-937X doi : 10.1111/1467-937X.00159
(22) "General training by firms, apprentice contracts, and public policy" (with James W. Maw and Barry McCormick), European Economic Review, 47(2), April 2003, 197–227. Print ISSN 0014-2921 Online ISSN 1873-572X doi : 10.1016/S0014-2921(02)00207-6. Reprinted in Francis Green (ed.), Recent Developments in the Economics of Training, vol. 1, chapter 6 (Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, 2007). ISBN 978 1 84542 546 3 https://www.e-elgar.com/shop/gbp/recent-developments-in-the-economics-of-training-9781845425463.html
(23) "Health service gatekeepers", RAND Journal of Economics, 35(2), Summer 2004, 401–421. Print ISSN 0741-6261 Online ISSN 1756-2171 JSTOR 1593698
(24) "Supplier discretion over provision: theory and an application to medical care", RAND Journal of Economics, 36(2), Summer 2005, 412–432. Print ISSN 0741-6261 Online ISSN 1756-2171 JSTOR 4135249
(25) "Relational incentive contracts" in Robert Gibbons and John Roberts (eds.), The Handbook of Organizational Economics (Princeton University Press, 2013), chapter 25, 1014–1065. ISBN 978-0-691-13279-2 doi : 10.1515/9781400845354-027
(26) "Relational incentive contracts with persistent private information", Econometrica, 84(1), January 2016, 317–346. Print ISSN 0012-9682 Online ISSN 1468-0262 doi : 10.3982/ECTA10946
(27) "Competition in public service provision: the role of not-for-profit providers" (with Timothy Besley), Journal of Public Economics, 162, June 2018, 158–172. Print ISSN 0047-2727 Online ISSN 1879-2316 doi : 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2018.04.004
Malcomson is married to the social gerontologist Dr Sally Richards. [43] They live in Oxford.
In economics, industrial organization is a field that builds on the theory of the firm by examining the structure of firms and markets. Industrial organization adds real-world complications to the perfectly competitive model, complications such as transaction costs, limited information, and barriers to entry of new firms that may be associated with imperfect competition. It analyzes determinants of firm and market organization and behavior on a continuum between competition and monopoly, including from government actions.
Bertil Gotthard Ohlin was a Swedish economist and politician. He was a professor of economics at the Stockholm School of Economics from 1929 to 1965. He was also leader of the People's Party, a social-liberal party which at the time was the largest party in opposition to the governing Social Democratic Party, from 1944 to 1967. He served briefly as Minister of Commerce and Industry from 1944 to 1945 in the Swedish coalition government during World War II. He was President of the Nordic Council in 1959 and 1964.
Oliver Eaton Williamson was an American economist, a professor at the University of California, Berkeley, and recipient of the 2009 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences, which he shared with Elinor Ostrom.
Industrial relations or employment relations is the multidisciplinary academic field that studies the employment relationship; that is, the complex interrelations between employers and employees, labor/trade unions, employer organizations, and the state.
Law and economics, or economic analysis of law, is the application of microeconomic theory to the analysis of law. The field emerged in the United States during the early 1960s, primarily from the work of scholars from the Chicago school of economics such as Aaron Director, George Stigler, and Ronald Coase. The field uses economics concepts to explain the effects of laws, assess which legal rules are economically efficient, and predict which legal rules will be promulgated. There are two major branches of law and economics; one based on the application of the methods and theories of neoclassical economics to the positive and normative analysis of the law, and a second branch which focuses on an institutional analysis of law and legal institutions, with a broader focus on economic, political, and social outcomes, and overlapping with analyses of the institutions of politics and governance.
Experimental economics is the application of experimental methods to study economic questions. Data collected in experiments are used to estimate effect size, test the validity of economic theories, and illuminate market mechanisms. Economic experiments usually use cash to motivate subjects, in order to mimic real-world incentives. Experiments are used to help understand how and why markets and other exchange systems function as they do. Experimental economics have also expanded to understand institutions and the law.
International political economy (IPE) is the study of how politics shapes the global economy and how the global economy shapes politics. A key focus in IPE is on the power of different actors such as nation states, international organizations and multinational corporations to shape the international economic system and the distributive consequences of international economic activity. It has been described as the study of "the political battle between the winners and losers of global economic exchange."
Bruno S. Frey is a Swiss economist and visiting professor for Political Economy at the University of Basel. Frey's research topics include Political economy and Happiness economics, with his published work including concepts derived from Psychology, Sociology, Jurisprudence, History, Arts, and Theology.
Personnel economics has been defined as "the application of economic and mathematical approaches and econometric and statistical methods to traditional questions in human resources management". It is an area of applied micro labor economics, but there are a few key distinctions. One distinction, not always clearcut, is that studies in personnel economics deal with the personnel management within firms, and thus internal labor markets, while those in labor economics deal with labor markets as such, whether external or internal. In addition, personnel economics deals with issues related to both managerial-supervisory and non-supervisory workers.
Claudia Dale Goldin is an American economic historian and labor economist. She is the Henry Lee Professor of Economics at Harvard University. In October 2023, she was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences "for having advanced our understanding of women's labor market outcomes”. The third woman to win the award, she was the first woman to win the award solo.
Zoltan J. Acs is an American economist. He is Professor of Management at The London School of Economics (LSE), and a professor at George Mason University, where he teaches in the Schar School of Policy and Government and is the Director of the Center for Entrepreneurship and Public Policy. He is also a visiting professor at Imperial College Business School in London and affiliated with the University of Pecs in Hungary. He is co-editor and founder of Small Business Economics.
Family economics applies economic concepts such as production, division of labor, distribution, and decision making to the family. It is used to explain outcomes unique to family—such as marriage, the decision to have children, fertility, time devoted to domestic production, and dowry payments using economic analysis.
The neoclassical synthesis (NCS), or neoclassical–Keynesian synthesis is an academic movement and paradigm in economics that worked towards reconciling the macroeconomic thought of John Maynard Keynes in his book The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (1936) with neoclassical economics.
Mathematical economics is the application of mathematical methods to represent theories and analyze problems in economics. Often, these applied methods are beyond simple geometry, and may include differential and integral calculus, difference and differential equations, matrix algebra, mathematical programming, or other computational methods. Proponents of this approach claim that it allows the formulation of theoretical relationships with rigor, generality, and simplicity.
Demographic economics or population economics is the application of economic analysis to demography, the study of human populations, including size, growth, density, distribution, and vital statistics.
Andrew Wen-Chuan Lo is a Hong Kong-born Taiwanese-American economist and academic who is the Charles E. and Susan T. Harris Professor of Finance at the MIT Sloan School of Management. Lo is the author of many academic articles in finance and financial economics. He founded AlphaSimplex Group in 1999 and served as chairman and chief investment strategist until 2018 when he transitioned to his current role as chairman emeritus and senior advisor.
Macroeconomic theory has its origins in the study of business cycles and monetary theory. In general, early theorists believed monetary factors could not affect real factors such as real output. John Maynard Keynes attacked some of these "classical" theories and produced a general theory that described the whole economy in terms of aggregates rather than individual, microeconomic parts. Attempting to explain unemployment and recessions, he noticed the tendency for people and businesses to hoard cash and avoid investment during a recession. He argued that this invalidated the assumptions of classical economists who thought that markets always clear, leaving no surplus of goods and no willing labor left idle.
Statistical discrimination is a theorized behavior in which group inequality arises when economic agents have imperfect information about individuals they interact with. According to this theory, inequality may exist and persist between demographic groups even when economic agents are rational. This is distinguished from taste-based discrimination which emphasizes the role of prejudice to explain disparities in labour market outcomes between demographic groups.
In economics, non-convexity refers to violations of the convexity assumptions of elementary economics. Basic economics textbooks concentrate on consumers with convex preferences and convex budget sets and on producers with convex production sets; for convex models, the predicted economic behavior is well understood. When convexity assumptions are violated, then many of the good properties of competitive markets need not hold: Thus, non-convexity is associated with market failures, where supply and demand differ or where market equilibria can be inefficient. Non-convex economies are studied with nonsmooth analysis, which is a generalization of convex analysis.
William Bentley MacLeod is a Canadian-American economist. He is Lecturer with Rank of Professor and Research Scholar at Princeton University, and the Sami Mnaymneh Professor of Economics and Professor of International and Public Affairs Emeritus at Columbia University. He is a specialist in the fields of labor economics and health economics, and law and economics.