Marginal revenue

Last updated
Linear marginal revenue (MR) and average revenue (AR) curves for a firm that is not in perfect competition Average and marginal revenue.svg
Linear marginal revenue (MR) and average revenue (AR) curves for a firm that is not in perfect competition

Marginal revenue (or marginal benefit) is a central concept in microeconomics that describes the additional total revenue generated by increasing product sales by 1 unit. [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] Marginal revenue is the increase in revenue from the sale of one additional unit of product, i.e., the revenue from the sale of the last unit of product. It can be positive or negative. Marginal revenue is an important concept in vendor analysis. [6] [7] To derive the value of marginal revenue, it is required to examine the difference between the aggregate benefits a firm received from the quantity of a good and service produced last period and the current period with one extra unit increase in the rate of production. [8] Marginal revenue is a fundamental tool for economic decision making within a firm's setting, together with marginal cost to be considered. [9]

Contents

In a perfectly competitive market, the incremental revenue generated by selling an additional unit of a good is equal to the price the firm is able to charge the buyer of the good. [3] [10] This is because a firm in a competitive market will always get the same price for every unit it sells regardless of the number of units the firm sells since the firm's sales can never impact the industry's price. [1] [3] Therefore, in a perfectly competitive market, firms set the price level equal to their marginal revenue . [8]

In imperfect competition, a monopoly firm is a large producer in the market and changes in its output levels impact market prices, determining the whole industry's sales. Therefore, a monopoly firm lowers its price on all units sold in order to increase output (quantity) by 1 unit. [1] [3] [8] Since a reduction in price leads to a decline in revenue on each good sold by the firm, the marginal revenue generated is always lower than the price level charged . [1] [3] [8] The marginal revenue (the increase in total revenue) is the price the firm gets on the additional unit sold, less the revenue lost by reducing the price on all other units that were sold prior to the decrease in price. Marginal revenue is the concept of a firm sacrificing the opportunity to sell the current output at a certain price, in order to sell a higher quantity at a reduced price. [8]

Profit maximization occurs at the point where marginal revenue (MR) equals marginal cost (MC). If then a profit-maximizing firm will increase output to generate more profit, while if then the firm will decrease output to gain additional profit. Thus the firm will choose the profit-maximizing level of output for which . [11]

Definition

Marginal revenue is equal to the ratio of the change in revenue for some change in quantity sold to that change in quantity sold. This can be formulated as: [12]

This can also be represented as a derivative when the change in quantity sold becomes arbitrarily small. Define the revenue function to be [13]

where Q is output and P(Q) is the inverse demand function of customers. By the product rule, marginal revenue is then given by

where the prime sign indicates a derivative. For a firm facing perfect competition, price does not change with quantity sold (), so marginal revenue is equal to price. For a monopoly, the price decreases with quantity sold (), so marginal revenue is less than price for positive (see Example 1). [8]

Example 1: If a firm sells 20 units of books (quantity) for $50 each (price), this earns total revenue: P*Q = $50*20 = $1000

Then if the firm increases quantity sold to 21 units of books at $49 each, this earns total revenue: P*Q = $49*21 = $1029

Therefore, using the marginal revenue formula (MR) [12] =

Example 2: If a firm's total revenue function is written as [14]

Then, by first order derivation, marginal revenue would be expressed as

Therefore, if Q = 40,

MR = 200 − 2(40) = $120

Marginal revenue curve

Marginal revenue under perfect competition Costcurve - Marginal Cost 2.svg
Marginal revenue under perfect competition
Marginal revenue under monopoly MarginalRevenue.jpg
Marginal revenue under monopoly

The marginal revenue curve is affected by the same factors as the demand curve – changes in income, changes in the prices of complements and substitutes, changes in populations, etc. [15] These factors can cause the MR curve to shift and rotate. [16] Marginal revenue curve differs under perfect competition and imperfect competition (monopoly). [17]

Under perfect competition, there are multiple firms present in the market. Changes in the supply level of a single firm does not have an impact on the total price in the market. [18] Firms follow the price determined by market equilibrium of supply and demand and are price takers. [19] The marginal revenue curve is a horizontal line at the market price, implying perfectly elastic demand and is equal to the demand curve. [20]

Under monopoly, one firm is a sole seller in the market with a differentiated product. [17] The supply level (output) and price is determined by the monopolist in order to maximise profits, making a monopolist a price maker. [21] The marginal revenue for a monopolist is the private gain of selling an additional unit of output. The marginal revenue curve is downward sloping and below the demand curve and the additional gain from increasing the quantity sold is lower than the chosen market price. [22] [23] Under monopoly, the price of all units lowers each time a firm increases its output sold, this causes the firm to face a diminishing marginal revenue. [24]

Marginal revenue curve and marginal cost curve

A company will stop producing a product/service when marginal revenue (money the company earns from each additional sale) equals marginal cost (the cost the company costs to produce an additional unit). Therefore, a company is making money when MR is greater than marginal cost (MC). And when MC = MR, it is called profit maximization. After this point; the company can no longer make a profit. Therefore, it is in their interest to stop production. [25]

Relationship between marginal revenue and elasticity

The relationship between marginal revenue and the elasticity of demand by the firm's customers can be derived as follows: [26] [27] [28]

Taking the first order derivative of total revenue:

where R is total revenue, P(Q) is the inverse of the demand function, and e < 0 is the price elasticity of demand written as . [27]

Monopolist firm, as a price maker in the market, has the incentives to lower prices to boost quantities sold. [17] The price effects occur when a firm raises its products' prices and increased revenue on each unit sold. The quantity effect, on the other hand, describes the stage when prices increased and consumers quantity demanded reduce. Firms' pricing decision, therefore, is based on the tradeoff between the two outcomes by considering elasticity. [29]

When a monopolist firm is facing an Inelastic demand curve (e<1), it implies that a percentage change in quantity is less than the percentage change in price. By increasing quantity sold, the firm is forced to accept a reduction of price for all the current and previous production units, [23] resulting in a negative marginal revenue (MR). As such, as consumers are less sensitive and responsive to lower prices movement and so the expected product sales boost is highly unlikely and firms lose more profits due to reduction in marginal revenue. A rational firm will have to maintain its current price levels instead or increase the price for profit expansion. [27] [30] [31]

Increases in consumer's responsiveness to small changes in prices leads represents an elastic demand curve (e>1), resulting in a positive marginal revenue (MR) under monopoly competition. This signifies that a percentage change in quantity outweighs the percentage change in price. Firms in the imperfect competition market that lower prices by a small portion benefit from a large percentage increase in quantity sold and this generates greater marginal revenue. With that, a rational firm will recognize the value of price effects under an elastic demand function for its products and would avoid increasing prices as the quantity (demand) lost would be amplified due to the elastic demand curve. [27] [30] [31]

If the firm is a perfect competitor, where quantity produced and sold has no effect on the market price, then the price elasticity of demand is negative infinity and marginal revenue simply equals the (market-determined) price . [27] [31]

Therefore, it is essential to be aware of the elasticity of demand. A monopolist prefers to be on the more elastic end of the demand curve in order to gain a positive marginal revenue. This shows that a monopolist reduces output produced up to the point where marginal revenue is positive. [27] [28]  

Marginal revenue and Marginal benefit

Example 1: Suppose consumers want to buy an additional lipstick. If the consumer is willing to pay $50 for this extra lipstick, the marginal income of the purchase is $50. However, the more lipsticks consumers have, the less they pay for the next lipstick. This is because as consumers accumulate more and more lipsticks, the benefits of having an additional lipstick will be reduced.

Example 2: Suppose customers are considering buying 10 computers. If the marginal income of the 11th computer is $2, and the computer company is willing to sell the 11th component to maximize its consumer interest, the company's marginal income is $2 and consumers' marginal income is $2.

law of diminishing marginal returns

In microeconomics, for every unit of input added to a firm, the return received decreases. When a variable factor of production is put into a firm at a constant level of technology, the initial increase in this factor of production will increase output, but when it exceeds a certain limit, the increased output will diminish and will eventually reduce output in absolute terms. [32]

law of increasing marginal returns

In contrast to the law of diminishing marginal returns, in a knowledge-dependent economy, as knowledge and technological inputs increase, the output increases and the producer's returns tend to increase. This is an example of increasing marginal revenue; suppose a company produces toy airplanes. After some production, the company spends $10 in materials and labor to build the 1st toy airplane. The 1st toy airplane sells for $15, which means the profit on that toy is $5. Now, suppose that the 2nd toy airplane also costs $10, but this time it can be sold for $17. The profit on the 2nd toy airplane is $12 greater than the profit on the 1st toy airplane.

Marginal revenue and markup pricing

Profit maximization requires that a firm produces where marginal revenue equals marginal costs. Firm managers are unlikely to have complete information concerning their marginal revenue function or their marginal costs. However, the profit maximization conditions can be expressed in a “more easily applicable form”:

MR = MC,
MR = P(1 + 1/e),
MC = P(1 + 1/e),
MC = P + P/e,
(P − MC)/ P = −1/e. [33]

Markup is the difference between price and marginal cost. The formula states that markup as a percentage of price equals the negative (and hence the absolute value) of the inverse of the elasticity of demand. [33] A lower elasticity of demand implies a higher markup at the profit maximising equilibrium. [31]

(P − MC)/ P = −1/e is called the Lerner index after economist Abba Lerner. [34] The Lerner index is a measure of market power — the ability of a firm to charge a price that exceeds marginal cost. The index varies from zero (when demand is infinitely elastic (a perfectly competitive market) to 1 (when demand has an elasticity of −1). The closer the index value is to 1, the greater is the difference between price and marginal cost. The Lerner index increases as demand becomes less elastic. [34]

Alternatively, the relationship can be expressed as:

P = MC/(1 + 1/e).

Thus, for example, if e is −2 and MC is $5.00 then price is $10.00.

Example If a company can sell 10 units at $20 each or 11 units at $19 each, then the marginal revenue from the eleventh unit is (11 × 19) − (10 × 20) = $9.

See also

Notes

  1. 1 2 3 4 Bradley R. chiller, "Essentials of Economics", New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc., 1991.
  2. Edwin Mansfield, "Micro-Economics Theory and Applications, 3rd Edition", New York and London:W.W. Norton and Company, 1979.
  3. 1 2 3 4 5 Roger LeRoy Miller, "Intermediate Microeconomics Theory Issues Applications, Third Edition", New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc, 1982.
  4. Tirole, Jean, "The Theory of Industrial Organization", Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press, 1988.
  5. John Black, "Oxford Dictionary of Economics", New York: Oxford University Press, 2003.
  6. Primont, D. F., & Primont, D. (1995). Further Evidence of Positively Sloping Marginal Revenue. Southern Economic Journal, 62(2), 481–485. https://doi.org/10.2307/1060699
  7. Wilson, T. (1979). The Price of Oil: A Case of Negative Marginal Revenue. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 27(4), 301–315. https://doi.org/10.2307/2097955
  8. 1 2 3 4 5 6 Schiller, Bradley R.; Gebhardt, Karen (2017). Essentials of economics (10th ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin. ISBN   978-1-259-23570-2. OCLC   955345952.
  9. Mankiw, N. Gregory (2009). Principles of microeconomics (5th ed.). Mason, OH: South-Western Cengage Learning. ISBN   978-0-324-58998-6. OCLC   226358094.
  10. O'Sullivan & Sheffrin (2003), p. 112.
  11. Fisher, Timothy C. G.; Prentice, David; Waschik, Robert G. (2010). Managerial economics : a strategic approach. Routledge. p. 33. ISBN   9780415495172. OCLC   432989728.
  12. 1 2 Pindyck, Robert S. (3 December 2014). Microeconomics. Rubinfeld, Daniel L. (Global edition, Eighth ed.). Boston [Massachusetts]. ISBN   978-1-292-08197-7. OCLC   908406121.
  13. "3.2: Monopoly Profit-Maximizing Solution". Social Sci LibreTexts. 2020-02-27. Retrieved 2020-10-26.
  14. Goldstein, Larry Joel; Lay, David C.; Schneider, David I. (2004). Brief calculus & its applications (10th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education. ISBN   0-13-046618-2. OCLC   50235091.
  15. Landsburg, Steven E. (2013). Price theory and applications (Ninth ed.). Stamford, CT. ISBN   978-1-285-42352-4. OCLC   891601555.
  16. Landsburg, S Price 2002. p. 137.
  17. 1 2 3 Kumar, Manoj (2015-05-08). "Revenue Curves under Different Markets (With Diagram)". Economics Discussion. Retrieved 2020-10-26.
  18. "The Supply Curve of a Competitive Firm". saylordotorg.github.io. Retrieved 2020-10-26.
  19. "Demand in a Perfectly Competitive Market". www.cliffsnotes.com. Retrieved 2020-10-26.
  20. Russell W. Cooper; Alun Andrew John (2011). Microeconomics : theory through applications. Arlington, Virginia. ISBN   978-1-4533-1328-2. OCLC   953968136.
  21. McLean, William J. (William Joseph) (2013). Economics and contemporary issues. Applegate, Michael. (9e ed.). Mason, Ohio: South-Western Cengage Learning. ISBN   978-1-111-82339-9. OCLC   775406167.
  22. Tuovila, Alicia. "Marginal Revenue (MR) Definition". Investopedia. Retrieved 2020-10-26.
  23. 1 2 "Marginal revenue for a monopolist". www.economics.utoronto.ca. Retrieved 2020-10-26.
  24. "The Monopoly Model". saylordotorg.github.io. Retrieved 2020-10-26.
  25. Boyce, Paul (February 6, 2021). "Marginal Revenue Definition". Boycewire.
  26. Perloff (2008) p. 364.
  27. 1 2 3 4 5 6 "3.3: Marginal Revenue and the Elasticity of Demand". Social Sci LibreTexts. 2020-02-27. Retrieved 2020-10-27.
  28. 1 2 Rekhi, Samia (2016-05-16). "Marginal Revenue and Price Elasticity of Demand". Economics Discussion. Retrieved 2020-10-27.
  29. Paul Krugman; Robin Wells; Iris Au; Jack Parkinson (2013). Microeconomics (3rd ed.). New York: Worth Publishers. ISBN   978-1-4292-4005-5. OCLC   796082268.
  30. 1 2 Pemberton, Malcolm; Rau, Nicholas (2011). Mathematics for economists : an introductory textbook (3rd ed.). Manchester: Manchester University Press. ISBN   978-0-7190-8705-9. OCLC   756276243.
  31. 1 2 3 4 "Leibniz: The elasticity of demand". www.core-econ.org. Retrieved 2020-10-27.
  32. Bondarenko, Peter. "microeconomics". Encyclopedia Britannica, Mar 25, 2023, https://www.britannica.com/topic/microeconomics. Accessed 21 April 2023.
  33. 1 2 Pindyck, R & Rubinfeld, D (2001) p. 334.
  34. 1 2 Perloff (2008) p. 371.

Related Research Articles

A monopoly, as described by Irving Fisher, is a market with the "absence of competition", creating a situation where a specific person or enterprise is the only supplier of a particular thing. This contrasts with a monopsony which relates to a single entity's control of a market to purchase a good or service, and with oligopoly and duopoly which consists of a few sellers dominating a market. Monopolies are thus characterised by a lack of economic competition to produce the good or service, a lack of viable substitute goods, and the possibility of a high monopoly price well above the seller's marginal cost that leads to a high monopoly profit. The verb monopolise or monopolize refers to the process by which a company gains the ability to raise prices or exclude competitors. In economics, a monopoly is a single seller. In law, a monopoly is a business entity that has significant market power, that is, the power to charge overly high prices, which is associated with a decrease in social surplus. Although monopolies may be big businesses, size is not a characteristic of a monopoly. A small business may still have the power to raise prices in a small industry.

An oligopoly is a market in which control over an industry lies in the hands of a few large sellers who own a dominant share of the market. Oligopolistic markets have homogenous products, few market participants, and inelastic demand for the products in those industries. As a result of their significant market power, firms in oligopolistic markets can influence prices through manipulating the supply function. Firms in an oligopoly are also mutually interdependent, as any action by one firm is expected to affect other firms in the market and evoke a reaction or consequential action. As a result, firms in oligopolistic markets often resort to collusion as means of maximising profits.

In economics, specifically general equilibrium theory, a perfect market, also known as an atomistic market, is defined by several idealizing conditions, collectively called perfect competition, or atomistic competition. In theoretical models where conditions of perfect competition hold, it has been demonstrated that a market will reach an equilibrium in which the quantity supplied for every product or service, including labor, equals the quantity demanded at the current price. This equilibrium would be a Pareto optimum.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Profit maximization</span> Process to determine the highest profits for a firm

In economics, profit maximization is the short run or long run process by which a firm may determine the price, input and output levels that will lead to the highest possible total profit. In neoclassical economics, which is currently the mainstream approach to microeconomics, the firm is assumed to be a "rational agent" which wants to maximize its total profit, which is the difference between its total revenue and its total cost.

In economics, elasticity measures the responsiveness of one economic variable to a change in another. If the price elasticity of the demand of something is -2, a 10% increase in price causes the quantity demanded to fall by 20%. Elasticity in economics provides an understanding of changes in the behavior of the buyers and sellers with price changes. There are two types of elasticity for demand and supply, one is inelastic demand and supply and other one is elastic demand and supply.

A good's Price elasticity of demand is a measure of how sensitive the quantity demanded is to its price. When the price rises, quantity demanded falls for almost any good, but it falls more for some than for others. The price elasticity gives the percentage change in quantity demanded when there is a one percent increase in price, holding everything else constant. If the elasticity is −2, that means a one percent price rise leads to a two percent decline in quantity demanded. Other elasticities measure how the quantity demanded changes with other variables.

In economics, economic equilibrium is a situation in which economic forces such as supply and demand are balanced and in the absence of external influences the values of economic variables will not change. For example, in the standard text perfect competition, equilibrium occurs at the point at which quantity demanded and quantity supplied are equal.

In economics, the marginal cost is the change in the total cost that arises when the quantity produced is incremented, the cost of producing additional quantity. In some contexts, it refers to an increment of one unit of output, and in others it refers to the rate of change of total cost as output is increased by an infinitesimal amount. As Figure 1 shows, the marginal cost is measured in dollars per unit, whereas total cost is in dollars, and the marginal cost is the slope of the total cost, the rate at which it increases with output. Marginal cost is different from average cost, which is the total cost divided by the number of units produced.

The marginal revenue productivity theory of wages is a model of wage levels in which they set to match to the marginal revenue product of labor, , which is the increment to revenues caused by the increment to output produced by the last laborer employed. In a model, this is justified by an assumption that the firm is profit-maximizing and thus would employ labor only up to the point that marginal labor costs equal the marginal revenue generated for the firm. This is a model of the neoclassical economics type.

Cournot competition is an economic model used to describe an industry structure in which companies compete on the amount of output they will produce, which they decide on independently of each other and at the same time. It is named after Antoine Augustin Cournot (1801–1877) who was inspired by observing competition in a spring water duopoly. It has the following features:

The Ramsey problem, or Ramsey pricing, or Ramsey–Boiteux pricing, is a second-best policy problem concerning what prices a public monopoly should charge for the various products it sells in order to maximize social welfare while earning enough revenue to cover its fixed costs.

The Lerner index, formalized in 1934 by British economist of Russian origin Abba Lerner, is a measure of a firm's market power.

In economics, a cost curve is a graph of the costs of production as a function of total quantity produced. In a free market economy, productively efficient firms optimize their production process by minimizing cost consistent with each possible level of production, and the result is a cost curve. Profit-maximizing firms use cost curves to decide output quantities. There are various types of cost curves, all related to each other, including total and average cost curves; marginal cost curves, which are equal to the differential of the total cost curves; and variable cost curves. Some are applicable to the short run, others to the long run.

In economics, demand is the quantity of a good that consumers are willing and able to purchase at various prices during a given time. The relationship between price and quantity demand is also called the demand curve. Demand for a specific item is a function of an item's perceived necessity, price, perceived quality, convenience, available alternatives, purchasers' disposable income and tastes, and many other options.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Supply (economics)</span> Amount of a good that sellers are willing to provide in the market

In economics, supply is the amount of a resource that firms, producers, labourers, providers of financial assets, or other economic agents are willing and able to provide to the marketplace or to an individual. Supply can be in produced goods, labour time, raw materials, or any other scarce or valuable object. Supply is often plotted graphically as a supply curve, with the price per unit on the vertical axis and quantity supplied as a function of price on the horizontal axis. This reversal of the usual position of the dependent variable and the independent variable is an unfortunate but standard convention.

Total revenue is the total receipts a seller can obtain from selling goods or services to buyers. It can be written as P × Q, which is the price of the goods multiplied by the quantity of the sold goods.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Factor market</span> In economics, a market where resources used in the production process are bought and sold

In economics, a factor market is a market where factors of production are bought and sold. Factor markets allocate factors of production, including land, labour and capital, and distribute income to the owners of productive resources, such as wages, rents, etc.

In economics, the marginal product of labor (MPL) is the change in output that results from employing an added unit of labor. It is a feature of the production function, and depends on the amounts of physical capital and labor already in use.

A markup rule is the pricing practice of a producer with market power, where a firm charges a fixed mark-up over its marginal cost.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Monopoly price</span>

A monopoly price is set by a monopoly. A monopoly occurs when a firm lacks any viable competition and is the sole producer of the industry's product. Because a monopoly faces no competition, it has absolute market power and can set a price above the firm's marginal cost.

References