Supermodular function

Last updated

In mathematics, a supermodular function is a function on a lattice that, informally, has the property of being characterized by "increasing differences." Seen from the point of set functions, this can also be viewed as a relationship of "increasing returns", where adding more elements to a subset increases its valuation. In economics, supermodular functions are often used as a formal expression of complementarity in preferences among goods. Supermodular functions are studied and have applications in game theory, economics, lattice theory, combinatorial optimization, and machine learning.

Contents

Definition

Let be a lattice. A real-valued function is called supermodular if

for all [1] .

If the inequality is strict, then is strictly supermodular on . If is (strictly) supermodular then f is called (strictly) submodular. A function that is both submodular and supermodular is called modular. This corresponds to the inequality being changed to an equality.

We can also define supermodular functions where the underlying lattice is the vector space . Then the function is supermodular if

for all , , where denotes the componentwise maximum and the componentwise minimum of and .

If f is twice continuously differentiable, then supermodularity is equivalent to the condition [2]

Supermodularity in economics and game theory

The concept of supermodularity is used in the social sciences to analyze how one agent's decision affects the incentives of others.

Consider a symmetric game with a smooth payoff function defined over actions of two or more players . Suppose the action space is continuous; for simplicity, suppose each action is chosen from an interval: . In this context, supermodularity of implies that an increase in player 's choice increases the marginal payoff of action for all other players . That is, if any player chooses a higher , all other players have an incentive to raise their choices too. Following the terminology of Bulow, Geanakoplos, and Klemperer (1985), economists call this situation strategic complementarity, because players' strategies are complements to each other. [3] This is the basic property underlying examples of multiple equilibria in coordination games. [4]

The opposite case of supermodularity of , called submodularity, corresponds to the situation of strategic substitutability. An increase in lowers the marginal payoff to all other player's choices , so strategies are substitutes. That is, if chooses a higher , other players have an incentive to pick a lower.

For example, Bulow et al. consider the interactions of many imperfectly competitive firms. When an increase in output by one firm raises the marginal revenues of the other firms, production decisions are strategic complements. When an increase in output by one firm lowers the marginal revenues of the other firms, production decisions are strategic substitutes.

A supermodular utility function is often related to complementary goods. However, this view is disputed. [5]

Supermodular set functions

Supermodularity can also be defined for set functions, which are functions defined over subsets of a larger set. Many properties of submodular set functions can be rephrased to apply to supermodular set functions.

Intuitively, a supermodular function over a set of subsets demonstrates "increasing returns". This means that if each subset is assigned a real number that corresponds to its value, the value of a subset will always be less than the value of a larger subset which contains it. Alternatively, this means that as we add elements to a set, we increase its value.

Definition

Let be a finite set. A set function is supermodular if it satifies the following (equivalent) conditions [6] :

  1. for all .
  2. for all , where .

A set function is submodular if is supermodular, and modular if it is both supermodular and submodular.

Additional Facts

Optimization Techniques

There are specialized techniques for optimizing submodular functions. Theory and enumeration algorithms for finding local and global maxima (minima) of submodular (supermodular) functions can be found in "Maximization of submodular functions: Theory and enumeration algorithms", B. Goldengorin. [7]

See also

Notes and references

  1. Topkis, Donald M., ed. (1998). Supermodularity and complementarity. Frontiers of economic research. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press. ISBN   978-0-691-03244-3.
  2. The equivalence between the definition of supermodularity and its calculus formulation is sometimes called Topkis' characterization theorem. See Milgrom, Paul; Roberts, John (1990). "Rationalizability, Learning, and Equilibrium in Games with Strategic Complementarities". Econometrica . 58 (6): 1255–1277 [p. 1261]. doi:10.2307/2938316. JSTOR   2938316.
  3. Bulow, Jeremy I.; Geanakoplos, John D.; Klemperer, Paul D. (1985). "Multimarket Oligopoly: Strategic Substitutes and Complements". Journal of Political Economy . 93 (3): 488–511. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.541.2368 . doi:10.1086/261312. S2CID   154872708.
  4. Cooper, Russell; John, Andrew (1988). "Coordinating coordination failures in Keynesian models" (PDF). Quarterly Journal of Economics . 103 (3): 441–463. doi:10.2307/1885539. JSTOR   1885539.
  5. Chambers, Christopher P.; Echenique, Federico (2009). "Supermodularity and preferences". Journal of Economic Theory . 144 (3): 1004. CiteSeerX   10.1.1.122.6861 . doi:10.1016/j.jet.2008.06.004.
  6. McCormick, S. Thomas (2005), Submodular Function Minimization, Handbooks in Operations Research and Management Science, vol. 12, Elsevier, pp. 321–391, doi:10.1016/s0927-0507(05)12007-6, ISBN   978-0-444-51507-0 , retrieved 2024-12-12
  7. Goldengorin, Boris (2009-10-01). "Maximization of submodular functions: Theory and enumeration algorithms". European Journal of Operational Research. 198 (1): 102–112. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2008.08.022. ISSN   0377-2217.

Related Research Articles

In mathematics, a directed set is a nonempty set together with a reflexive and transitive binary relation , with the additional property that every pair of elements has an upper bound. In other words, for any and in there must exist in with and A directed set's preorder is called a direction.

In the mathematical areas of order and lattice theory, the Knaster–Tarski theorem, named after Bronisław Knaster and Alfred Tarski, states the following:

In functional analysis and related areas of mathematics, Fréchet spaces, named after Maurice Fréchet, are special topological vector spaces. They are generalizations of Banach spaces. All Banach and Hilbert spaces are Fréchet spaces. Spaces of infinitely differentiable functions are typical examples of Fréchet spaces, many of which are typically not Banach spaces.

In abstract algebra, a semiring is an algebraic structure. Semirings are a generalization of rings, dropping the requirement that each element must have an additive inverse. At the same time, semirings are a generalization of bounded distributive lattices.

In game theory, a cooperative game is a game with groups of players who form binding “coalitions” with external enforcement of cooperative behavior. This is different from non-cooperative games in which there is either no possibility to forge alliances or all agreements need to be self-enforcing.

In mathematics, fuzzy measure theory considers generalized measures in which the additive property is replaced by the weaker property of monotonicity. The central concept of fuzzy measure theory is the fuzzy measure, which was introduced by Choquet in 1953 and independently defined by Sugeno in 1974 in the context of fuzzy integrals. There exists a number of different classes of fuzzy measures including plausibility/belief measures, possibility/necessity measures, and probability measures, which are a subset of classical measures.

In mathematics, a polymatroid is a polytope associated with a submodular function. The notion was introduced by Jack Edmonds in 1970. It is also described as the multiset analogue of the matroid.

In mathematical economics, Topkis's theorem is a result that is useful for establishing comparative statics. The theorem allows researchers to understand how the optimal value for a choice variable changes when a feature of the environment changes. The result states that if f is supermodular in (x,θ), and D is a lattice, then is nondecreasing in θ. The result is especially helpful for establishing comparative static results when the objective function is not differentiable. The result is named after Donald M. Topkis.

Stochastic dominance is a partial order between random variables. It is a form of stochastic ordering. The concept arises in decision theory and decision analysis in situations where one gamble can be ranked as superior to another gamble for a broad class of decision-makers. It is based on shared preferences regarding sets of possible outcomes and their associated probabilities. Only limited knowledge of preferences is required for determining dominance. Risk aversion is a factor only in second order stochastic dominance.

In mathematics, a Riesz space, lattice-ordered vector space or vector lattice is a partially ordered vector space where the order structure is a lattice.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Ordered vector space</span> Vector space with a partial order

In mathematics, an ordered vector space or partially ordered vector space is a vector space equipped with a partial order that is compatible with the vector space operations.

In economics and game theory, the decisions of two or more players are called strategic complements if they mutually reinforce one another, and they are called strategic substitutes if they mutually offset one another. These terms were originally coined by Bulow, Geanakoplos, and Klemperer (1985).

In the mathematics of matroids and lattices, a geometric lattice is a finite atomistic semimodular lattice, and a matroid lattice is an atomistic semimodular lattice without the assumption of finiteness. Geometric lattices and matroid lattices, respectively, form the lattices of flats of finite, or finite and infinite, matroids, and every geometric or matroid lattice comes from a matroid in this way.

In mathematics, the Fortuin–Kasteleyn–Ginibre (FKG) inequality is a correlation inequality, a fundamental tool in statistical mechanics and probabilistic combinatorics, due to Cees M. Fortuin, Pieter W. Kasteleyn, and Jean Ginibre. Informally, it says that in many random systems, increasing events are positively correlated, while an increasing and a decreasing event are negatively correlated. It was obtained by studying the random cluster model.

In cryptography, learning with errors (LWE) is a mathematical problem that is widely used to create secure encryption algorithms. It is based on the idea of representing secret information as a set of equations with errors. In other words, LWE is a way to hide the value of a secret by introducing noise to it. In more technical terms, it refers to the computational problem of inferring a linear -ary function over a finite ring from given samples some of which may be erroneous. The LWE problem is conjectured to be hard to solve, and thus to be useful in cryptography.

In decision theory and game theory, Wald's maximin model is a non-probabilistic decision-making model according to which decisions are ranked on the basis of their worst-case outcomes – the optimal decision is one with the least bad worst outcome. It is one of the most important models in robust decision making in general and robust optimization in particular.

In mathematics, a submodular set function is a set function that, informally, describes the relationship between a set of inputs and an output, where adding more of one input has a decreasing additional benefit. The natural diminishing returns property which makes them suitable for many applications, including approximation algorithms, game theory and electrical networks. Recently, submodular functions have also found utility in several real world problems in machine learning and artificial intelligence, including automatic summarization, multi-document summarization, feature selection, active learning, sensor placement, image collection summarization and many other domains.

Monotone comparative statics is a sub-field of comparative statics that focuses on the conditions under which endogenous variables undergo monotone changes when there is a change in the exogenous parameters. Traditionally, comparative results in economics are obtained using the Implicit Function Theorem, an approach that requires the concavity and differentiability of the objective function as well as the interiority and uniqueness of the optimal solution. The methods of monotone comparative statics typically dispense with these assumptions. It focuses on the main property underpinning monotone comparative statics, which is a form of complementarity between the endogenous variable and exogenous parameter. Roughly speaking, a maximization problem displays complementarity if a higher value of the exogenous parameter increases the marginal return of the endogenous variable. This guarantees that the set of solutions to the optimization problem is increasing with respect to the exogenous parameter.

Some branches of economics and game theory deal with indivisible goods, discrete items that can be traded only as a whole. For example, in combinatorial auctions there is a finite set of items, and every agent can buy a subset of the items, but an item cannot be divided among two or more agents.

In discrete mathematics, a discrete fixed-point is a fixed-point for functions defined on finite sets, typically subsets of the integer grid .