Winner-take-all market

Last updated

In economics, a winner-take-all market is a market in which a product or service that is favored over the competitors, even if only slightly, receives a disproportionately large share of the revenues for that class of products or services. [1] It occurs when the top producer of a product earns a lot more than their competitors. [1] [2] [3] Examples of winner-take-all markets include the sports and entertainment markets. [4] [5]

Contents

The distribution of rewards for different amounts of work determines the degree to which a market is considered winner-take-all. For example, most lottery games are 100% winner-take-all systems because one person takes the entire reward and the rest receive nothing. On the other hand, most manual work, such as picking apples, is the opposite of a winner-take-all system. In this apple-picking example, the reward is proportional to the amount picked — a person who picks only one box of apples still gets rewarded proportionally. There are also intermediate cases. For example, in Olympic competition, only the top three individuals or teams are rewarded with medals, but other finishers receive lesser rewards such as bragging rights and publicity.

Although some markets (such as lottery games) are designed to be winner-take-all, there are some markets that evolve to become winner-take-all. For example, the piano market was not winner-take-all before rail transportation, whose growing availability and popularity resulted in leading piano makers became progressively larger and capturing more of the piano market, while smaller competitors disappeared over time. (See the Matthew effect, in which "the rich get richer and the poor get poorer".)

The term "winner-take-all" as applied to economic markets was popularized by the 1996 book The Winner-Take-All Society: Why the Few at the Top Get So Much More Than the Rest of Us by Robert H. Frank and Philip J. Cook. [5]

Winner-take-all effect

The winner-take-all phenomenon, categorized by Frank and Cook, which describes the tendency in certain markets for rewards to skew heavily to “superstar” players despite small differences between their performance and that of alternatives. [6] [7]

Earnings distributions or payoff-structures in winner-take-all models differ from a standard human capital model, where earnings directly correlate to the capital produced per unit of worker time. In a winner-take-all market “small differences in human capital translate to large differences in economic reward”. [8]

Characteristics

Frank and Cook’s model describes a Winner-take-all market as one which is characterised by excessive entry and investment. [7]

In winner take-all markets the magnitude of entrants has been found to be in excess of typical Nash equilibrium predictions. [9] When compared with expected payoff-equivalent market games the winner-take all market induces more entry despite having the same expected payoff and greater variance. This effect contradicts predictions of expected utility models with risk aversion. [10]

Cumulative prospect theory has been found to provide a more comprehensive explanation for the winner-take-all market than classical expected utility theory. [10]

Models

Frank and Cook model winner-take-all (WTA) markets under a variety of conditions. [7]

They use an example of a two sector economy where one sector presents WTA characteristics. In this model the revenue reward function modelling number of players in the economy and number of players which are allocated to the winner take all market. In this case is used to predict the revenue available to WTA contestants as a function of expected reward .

Unobservable Differences

In the simplest instance a WTA market where the differences between players are unobservable and therefore the probability of each player winning is perceived as equal. Finding for the simple two sector economy; output , similar to rent seeking models and dual labour market models for developing countries. [7]

Private equilibrium versus social optimum in a winner-take all market Two sector private equilibrium vs social optimimum allocation for a Winner-take-all market.png
Private equilibrium versus social optimum in a winner-take all market

This model is used to demonstrate the inefficiencies of entry into the WTA market by contrasting these values with the socially optimal allocation showing the private equilibrium allocation in a WTA market outstrips the socially optimum allocation where output is maximised.

Observable Differences

To provide a more realistic model of the winner-take-all market – when differences in talent of the players are observable – meaning the perceived probability of each player winning varies. This model takes the factor Q which combines the selective factors talent and representing unobserved factors which influence quality such that for each player where and are variables determined from some distribution and drawn randomly for the players.

While in the model of unobservable differences the market reward increases with every additional WTA player , in this model the value of reward increases only where the quality of the new WTA player is higher than the lowest quality of the existing player pool. The probability of this event then determines the marginal reward gain for new entrants

where is the expected value gain if the new entrant wins. The model takes where is the expected revenue gain and is a positive number as the expected gain in WTA market value is only a part of the revenue which will be received by the entrant upon winning.

This model finds that which shows that the anticipated reward (left) to new entrants exceeds the opportunity wage by . This model finds that observable talent narrows the gap between social optimum and equilibrium allocation of entrants though does not eliminate the inefficiency entirely.

Related Research Articles

Pareto efficiency or Pareto optimality is a situation where no action or allocation is available that makes one individual better off without making another worse off. The concept is named after Vilfredo Pareto (1848–1923), Italian civil engineer and economist, who used the concept in his studies of economic efficiency and income distribution. The following three concepts are closely related:

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Capital asset pricing model</span> Model used in finance

In finance, the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) is a model used to determine a theoretically appropriate required rate of return of an asset, to make decisions about adding assets to a well-diversified portfolio.

In mathematics, in set theory, the constructible universe, denoted by , is a particular class of sets that can be described entirely in terms of simpler sets. is the union of the constructible hierarchy. It was introduced by Kurt Gödel in his 1938 paper "The Consistency of the Axiom of Choice and of the Generalized Continuum-Hypothesis". In this paper, he proved that the constructible universe is an inner model of ZF set theory, and also that the axiom of choice and the generalized continuum hypothesis are true in the constructible universe. This shows that both propositions are consistent with the basic axioms of set theory, if ZF itself is consistent. Since many other theorems only hold in systems in which one or both of the propositions is true, their consistency is an important result.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Mechanism design</span> Field in game theory

Mechanism design is a field in economics and game theory that takes an objectives-first approach to designing economic mechanisms or incentives, toward desired objectives, in strategic settings, where players act rationally. Because it starts at the end of the game, then goes backwards, it is also called reverse game theory. It has broad applications, from economics and politics in fields such as market design, auction theory and social choice theory to networked-systems.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Vickrey auction</span> Auction priced by second-highest sealed bid

A Vickrey auction or sealed-bid second-price auction (SBSPA) is a type of sealed-bid auction. Bidders submit written bids without knowing the bid of the other people in the auction. The highest bidder wins but the price paid is the second-highest bid. This type of auction is strategically similar to an English auction and gives bidders an incentive to bid their true value. The auction was first described academically by Columbia University professor William Vickrey in 1961 though it had been used by stamp collectors since 1893. In 1797 Johann Wolfgang von Goethe sold a manuscript using a sealed-bid, second-price auction.

In mathematical economics, the Arrow–Debreu model is a theoretical general equilibrium model. It posits that under certain economic assumptions there must be a set of prices such that aggregate supplies will equal aggregate demands for every commodity in the economy.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Markov random field</span> Set of random variables

In the domain of physics and probability, a Markov random field (MRF), Markov network or undirected graphical model is a set of random variables having a Markov property described by an undirected graph. In other words, a random field is said to be a Markov random field if it satisfies Markov properties. The concept originates from the Sherrington–Kirkpatrick model.

Cohen's kappa coefficient is a statistic that is used to measure inter-rater reliability for qualitative (categorical) items. It is generally thought to be a more robust measure than simple percent agreement calculation, as κ takes into account the possibility of the agreement occurring by chance. There is controversy surrounding Cohen's kappa due to the difficulty in interpreting indices of agreement. Some researchers have suggested that it is conceptually simpler to evaluate disagreement between items.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Multi-armed bandit</span> Resource problem in machine learning

In probability theory and machine learning, the multi-armed bandit problem is a problem in which a decision maker iteratively selects one of multiple fixed choices when the properties of each choice are only partially known at the time of allocation, and may become better understood as time passes. A fundamental aspect of bandit problems is that choosing an arm does not affect the properties of the arm or other arms.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Kelly criterion</span> Formula for bet sizing that maximizes the expected logarithmic value

In probability theory, the Kelly criterion is a formula for sizing a bet. The Kelly bet size is found by maximizing the expected value of the logarithm of wealth, which is equivalent to maximizing the expected geometric growth rate. It assumes that the expected returns are known and is optimal for a bettor who values their wealth logarithmically. J. L. Kelly Jr, a researcher at Bell Labs, described the criterion in 1956. Under the stated assumptions, the Kelly criterion leads to higher wealth than any other strategy in the long run.

In natural language processing, latent Dirichlet allocation (LDA) is a Bayesian network for modeling automatically extracted topics in textual corpora. The LDA is an example of a Bayesian topic model. In this, observations are collected into documents, and each word's presence is attributable to one of the document's topics. Each document will contain a small number of topics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Auction theory</span> Branch of applied economics regarding the behavior of bidders in auctions

Auction theory is an applied branch of economics which deals with how bidders act in auction markets and researches how the features of auction markets incentivise predictable outcomes. Auction theory is a tool used to inform the design of real-world auctions. Sellers use auction theory to raise higher revenues while allowing buyers to procure at a lower cost. The conference of the price between the buyer and seller is an economic equilibrium. Auction theorists design rules for auctions to address issues which can lead to market failure. The design of these rulesets encourages optimal bidding strategies among a variety of informational settings. The 2020 Nobel Prize for Economics was awarded to Paul R. Milgrom and Robert B. Wilson “for improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats.”

The softmax function, also known as softargmax or normalized exponential function, converts a vector of K real numbers into a probability distribution of K possible outcomes. It is a generalization of the logistic function to multiple dimensions, and used in multinomial logistic regression. The softmax function is often used as the last activation function of a neural network to normalize the output of a network to a probability distribution over predicted output classes, based on Luce's choice axiom.

In probability theory and statistics, the Dirichlet-multinomial distribution is a family of discrete multivariate probability distributions on a finite support of non-negative integers. It is also called the Dirichlet compound multinomial distribution (DCM) or multivariate Pólya distribution. It is a compound probability distribution, where a probability vector p is drawn from a Dirichlet distribution with parameter vector , and an observation drawn from a multinomial distribution with probability vector p and number of trials n. The Dirichlet parameter vector captures the prior belief about the situation and can be seen as a pseudocount: observations of each outcome that occur before the actual data is collected. The compounding corresponds to a Pólya urn scheme. It is frequently encountered in Bayesian statistics, machine learning, empirical Bayes methods and classical statistics as an overdispersed multinomial distribution.

Competitive equilibrium is a concept of economic equilibrium, introduced by Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu in 1951, appropriate for the analysis of commodity markets with flexible prices and many traders, and serving as the benchmark of efficiency in economic analysis. It relies crucially on the assumption of a competitive environment where each trader decides upon a quantity that is so small compared to the total quantity traded in the market that their individual transactions have no influence on the prices. Competitive markets are an ideal standard by which other market structures are evaluated.

The Gittins index is a measure of the reward that can be achieved through a given stochastic process with certain properties, namely: the process has an ultimate termination state and evolves with an option, at each intermediate state, of terminating. Upon terminating at a given state, the reward achieved is the sum of the probabilistic expected rewards associated with every state from the actual terminating state to the ultimate terminal state, inclusive. The index is a real scalar.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Revenue equivalence</span>

Revenue equivalence is a concept in auction theory that states that given certain conditions, any mechanism that results in the same outcomes also has the same expected revenue.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Online machine learning</span> Method of machine learning

In computer science, online machine learning is a method of machine learning in which data becomes available in a sequential order and is used to update the best predictor for future data at each step, as opposed to batch learning techniques which generate the best predictor by learning on the entire training data set at once. Online learning is a common technique used in areas of machine learning where it is computationally infeasible to train over the entire dataset, requiring the need of out-of-core algorithms. It is also used in situations where it is necessary for the algorithm to dynamically adapt to new patterns in the data, or when the data itself is generated as a function of time, e.g., stock price prediction. Online learning algorithms may be prone to catastrophic interference, a problem that can be addressed by incremental learning approaches.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Market design</span>

Market design is a practical methodology for creation of markets of certain properties, which is partially based on mechanism design. In some markets, prices may be used to induce the desired outcomes — these markets are the study of auction theory. In other markets, prices may not be used — these markets are the study of matching theory.

In theoretical economics, an abstract economy is a model that generalizes both the standard model of an exchange economy in microeconomics, and the standard model of a game in game theory. An equilibrium in an abstract economy generalizes both a Walrasian equilibrium in microeconomics, and a Nash equilibrium in game-theory.

References

  1. 1 2 Grant, Randy R.; Leadley, John C.; Zygmont, Zenon X. (2014-10-21). The Economics of Intercollegiate Sports. World Scientific Publishing Co Inc. ISBN   9789814583398.
  2. Arnold, Roger A. (2007-01-25). Economics. Cengage Learning. ISBN   978-0324538014.
  3. Rycroft, Robert (2014-12-18). The Economics of Inequality, Discrimination, Poverty, and Mobility. Routledge. ISBN   9781317457312.
  4. Phillips, Ronnie (2012-11-19). Rock and Roll Fantasy?: The Reality of Going from Garage Band to Superstardom. Springer Science & Business Media. ISBN   9781461459002.
  5. 1 2 Elberse, Anita (2013). Blockbusters: Hit-Making, Risk-Taking, and the Big Business of Entertainment. New York: Henry Holt and Company. p. 88. ISBN   9781429945325.
  6. Rosen, Sherwin (1981). "The Economics of Superstars". The American Economic Review. 71 (5): 845–858. ISSN   0002-8282. JSTOR   1803469.
  7. 1 2 3 4 Frank, Robert H.; Cook, Philip J. (December 2013). "Winner-Take-All Markets". Studies in Microeconomics. 1 (2): 131–154. doi:10.1177/2321022213501254. ISSN   2321-0222. S2CID   154188635.
  8. Frank, Robert H.; Cook, Philip J. (2010). The Winner-take-all Society: Why the Few at the Top Get So Much More Than the Rest of Us. Virgin Books. ISBN   978-0-7535-2226-4.
  9. Fischbacher, Urs; Thöni, Christian (2008). "Excess entry in an experimental winner-take-all market". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 67 (1): 150–163. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2006.05.018. hdl: 20.500.11850/146627 .
  10. 1 2 Laferrière, Vincent; Staubli, David; Thöni, Christian (February 2023). "Explaining Excess Entry in Winner-Take-All Markets". Management Science. 69 (2): 1050–1069. doi:10.1287/mnsc.2022.4397. ISSN   0025-1909. S2CID   247970325.