This article has multiple issues. Please help improve it or discuss these issues on the talk page . (Learn how and when to remove these messages)
|
E. C. Pasour, Jr. | |
---|---|
Born | 12 September 1932 |
Nationality | American |
Academic career | |
Institution | North Carolina State University |
School or tradition | Austrian School |
Alma mater | Michigan State University |
Awards | Leavey Award – Freedoms Foundation at Valley Forge |
E. C. Pasour, Jr. (born 1932) is an American economist [1] and Professor Emeritus of Agricultural and Resource Economics at North Carolina State University. He received a PhD in agricultural economics from Michigan State University and spent a sabbatical at the University of Chicago on a NSF Fellowship.
He is the author of books oriented towards the Austrian school of economics.
He received a Freedoms Foundation at Valley Forge Leavey Award for Excellence in Private Enterprise Education.
His work also has been published in The American Journal of Agricultural Economics , Constitutional Political Economy , The Freeman , the Journal of Libertarian Studies , Minerva , National Tax Journal , Public Choice , Reason , the Review of Austrian Economics , the Southern Economic Journal , The Wall Street Journal and others.
Pasour was born and raised on a farm in Gaston County, North Carolina. [2] He graduated with a degree in agricultural education from North Carolina State College in 1954, and served in the United States Army for two years. He obtained a master's degree specializing in agricultural economics from N.C. State University. There, he was influenced by the Chicago school of economics, which confirmed his criticisms of government intervention in agriculture. He then enrolled in a PhD program at Michigan State University, where the influence of the Chicago school of economics was much less pronounced. He obtained his PhD in agricultural economics in 1963. [2]
After teaching as an assistant and associate professor of economics and business at North Carolina State University, Pasour took a sabbatical at the University of Chicago. [2] His view of economics soon began to change, first being influenced by public choice economists, emphasizing the incentives of government decision-makers versus private entrepreneurs, and then by Austrian economists, emphasizing the role of the entrepreneur in the market process. [2] After reading further Austrian works, such as James Buchanan's Cost and Choice and various articles by Friedrich Hayek, Pasour began to apply Austrian and public choice concepts to his work in agricultural economics. He formed the view that Government regulators cannot do what they profess to do–even when they have the best intentions–because they cannot obtain the relevant information to do so. [2] This view was very different from the mainstream at the time.
Pasour would go on to publish articles in various market-oriented publications, including The Freeman , The Intercollegiate Review , and Reason magazine . [2] He was invited to give a talk at the "Freedom in Third Century in America" seminar in 1982, where he was formally identified with the discipline of Austrian economics. In 1983 he became a member of the board of advisers for the Journal of Austrian Economics. [2]
In 1986 he participated in a summer seminar at the Foundation for Economic Education (FEE), where he shared a manuscript on U.S. agricultural policy. [2] FEE edited and published the manuscript for use in a national high school debate program soon after. Pasour was awarded a Freedoms Foundation at Valley Forge Leavey Award for Excellence in Private Enterprise Education in 1989, which was in large part due to the manuscript. The manuscript was later expanded and published as Agriculture & the State: Market Processes & Bureaucracy in 1990. [2]
The Austrian school was a heterodox school of economic thought, dominant since the end of the 20th century, that advocates strict adherence to methodological individualism, the concept that social phenomena result primarily from the motivations and actions of individuals along with their self interest. Austrian-school theorists hold that economic theory should be exclusively derived from basic principles of human action.
David Director Friedman is an American economist, physicist, legal scholar, and anarcho-capitalist theorist. Although his academic training was in chemistry and physics and not law or economics, he is known for his textbook writings on microeconomics and the libertarian theory of anarcho-capitalism, which is the subject of his most popular book, The Machinery of Freedom. Described by Walter Block as a "free-market anarchist" theorist, Friedman has also authored several other books and articles, including Price Theory: An Intermediate Text (1986), Law's Order: What Economics Has to Do with Law and Why It Matters (2000), Hidden Order: The Economics of Everyday Life (1996), and Future Imperfect (2008).
Murray Newton Rothbard was an American economist of the Austrian School, economic historian, political theorist, and activist. Rothbard was a central figure in the 20th-century American libertarian movement, particularly its right-wing strands, and was a founder and leading theoretician of anarcho-capitalism. He wrote over twenty books on political theory, history, economics, and other subjects.
James McGill Buchanan Jr. was an American economist known for his work on public choice theory originally outlined in his most famous work, The Calculus of Consent, co-authored with Gordon Tullock in 1962. He continued to develop the theory, eventually receiving the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1986. Buchanan's work initiated research on how politicians' and bureaucrats' self-interest, utility maximization, and other non-wealth-maximizing considerations affect their decision-making. He was a member of the Board of Advisors of The Independent Institute as well as of the Institute of Economic Affairs, a member of the Mont Pelerin Society (MPS) and MPS president from 1984 to 1986, a Distinguished Senior Fellow of the Cato Institute, and professor at George Mason University.
The Ludwig von Mises Institute for Austrian Economics, or Mises Institute, is a nonprofit think tank headquartered in Auburn, Alabama, that is a center for Austrian economics, right-wing libertarian thought and the paleolibertarian and anarcho-capitalist movements in the United States. It is named after the economist Ludwig von Mises (1881–1973) and promotes the Misesian version of heterodox Austrian economics.
Libertarian theories of law build upon classical liberal and individualist doctrines.
The Chicago school of economics is a neoclassical school of economic thought associated with the work of the faculty at the University of Chicago, some of whom have constructed and popularized its principles. Milton Friedman and George Stigler are considered the leading scholars of the Chicago school.
Gordon Tullock was an American economist and professor of law and economics at the George Mason University School of Law. He is best known for his work on public choice theory, the application of economic thinking to political issues. He was one of the founding figures in his field.
Richard M. Ebeling is an American libertarian author who was the president of the Foundation for Economic Education (FEE) from 2003 to 2008. Ebeling is currently the BB&T Distinguished Professor of Ethics and Free Enterprise Leadership at The Citadel in Charleston, South Carolina.
Donald Joseph Boudreaux is a libertarian American economist, author, professor, and co-director of the Program on the American Economy and Globalization at the Mercatus Center at George Mason University in Fairfax, Virginia.
Ralph Raico was an American libertarian historian of European liberalism and a professor of history at Buffalo State College.
Ludwig Heinrich Edler von Mises was an Austrian–American economist, logician, sociologist, and philosopher of economics of the Austrian school. Mises wrote and lectured extensively on the societal contributions of classical liberalism and the power of consumers. He is best known for his work in praxeology, particularly for studies comparing communism and capitalism, as well as for being a defender of classical liberalism in the face of rising illiberalism and authoritarianism throughout much of Europe during the 20th century.
The following outline is provided as an overview of and topical guide to libertarianism:
Edward Peter Stringham is an Austrian School American economist, former President of the American Institute for Economic Research in Great Barrington, Massachusetts, and the Davis Professor of Economic Innovation at Trinity College (Connecticut).
Percy L. Greaves Jr. was an American free-market economist, historian, and presidential candidate.
Floyd Arthur "Baldy" Harper was an American academic, economist and writer who was best known for founding the Institute for Humane Studies in 1961.
David Gordon is an American libertarian philosopher and intellectual historian influenced by Murray Rothbard's views of economics. He is a senior fellow of the Ludwig von Mises Institute, a libertarian think tank, and is the editor of The Mises Review.
Ronald Hamowy was a Canadian academic, known primarily for his contributions to political and social academic fields. At the time of his death, he was professor emeritus of intellectual history at the University of Alberta in Edmonton, Canada. Hamowy was closely associated with the political ideology of libertarianism and his writings and scholarship place particular emphasis on individual liberty and the limits of state action in a free society. He is associated with a number of prominent American libertarian organizations.
William Herbert Peterson was an American economist who wrote on the insights of Ludwig von Mises through teaching, writing, and speaking on the relationship between free enterprise and human liberty.
George Stanford Tolley was an agricultural economist at the University of Chicago. Along with the faculty at the University of Chicago, he has worked on the faculty of North Carolina State University. In 1965–1966, he was Director of the Economic Development Division of the Economic Research Service at the US Department of Agriculture, and in 1974–1975 he was Deputy Assistant Secretary and Director of the Office of Tax Analysis at the US Department of Treasury.