James Harvey Rogers

Last updated
James Harvey Rogers
James Harvey Rogers.jpg
Rogers in 1934
Born(1886-09-25)25 September 1886
Died13 August 1939(1939-08-13) (aged 52)
Known forAdvisor to Franklin D. Roosevelt

James Harvey Rogers was Yale University Sterling Professor of Economics from 1931 until his death in 1939. He was an adviser to President Franklin D. Roosevelt on monetary economics from 1933 to 1934. He was a student of Irving Fisher and Vilfredo Pareto and is considered Fisher's closest disciple [1] and a proto-Keynesian. [2]

Contents

Early life and education

Family background

In 1743, Nicholas Rogers established a 350-acre plantation in the wilderness of Welsh Neck, east across the Great Pee Dee River from Society Hill, in the adjoining Marlboro County. Nicholas's grandson was Colonel Benjamin Rogers Jr., who fought in the American Revolution and was the father of 18 children and one step-child. [3] James Harvey's father, John Terrell Rogers, was a fourth generation descendant of Nicholas Rogers. John was a captain in the Confederate Army by the age of 19 and, after the war, started his own plantation in Society Hill that he named Belle Vue. Rogers's first wife died in 1874 and he married Florence Coker, the youngest daughter of a prosperous store owner, in 1879. [4]

Education

Rogers attended primary school at St. David's Academy where he was a mediocre, if diligent, student. [5] In 1904, he enrolled at the College of South Carolina in Columbia. By starting as an advanced sophomore and taking large course loads, he was able to complete bachelor's degrees in both arts and sciences and a Master of Arts in mathematics and astronomy by 1907. [6] At this point in his life, Rogers had not advanced beyond the sentimental, ethnocentric nationalism of the Southern landowning class. [7] After graduating, he taught at St. David's Academy and was acting principal for one year before entering Yale University for a second bachelor's degree in 1909. He spent two years at the University of Chicago studying mathematics and astronomy. Studying under Alvin Johnson convinced Rogers to combine his interest in mathematics with economics. [8] Nevertheless, he left unsatisfied and without earning a degree and returned to Yale. The death of his father in 1912 temporarily interrupted his education, but he received an M.A. in 1913. Owing to a sense of civic duty and an interest in social reform, he switched to political economy in the doctoral program. [9] It was during his time at Yale that he began his study with Fisher.

For the 1914-1915 school year, Rogers was awarded Yale's Cyler Fellowship to study economics abroad. [8] On Fisher's advice that Pareto was one of the foremost mathematical economists, Rogers went to the Geneva for his fellowship year. In 1893, Pareto had succeeded Léon Walras to the Chair of Political Economy at the University of Lausanne where he continued his work on general equilibrium theory. By 1914, Pareto was largely retired from teaching, but had finished his Trattato di sociologia generale (published in Italian in 1916; published in English as The Mind and Society in 1935) and was eager to lecture on his work. Pareto was living at his Villa Angora in the village of Céligny. For six months Rogers would "go out [to Céligny from Geneva] each Tuesday afternoon at five, listen to [Pareto] lecture for an hour, then discuss the matter for half an hour more, then eat a big French dinner and sit and talk until ten o'clock." [10]

While in Europe, Rogers developed a method that he would employ throughout his career. Weak in theory and lacking the focus on detail necessary to produce the kind of data that was scarce in the pre-war era, [11] Rogers traveled widely, established relationships, spoke to people with first-hand knowledge and cultivated his skills as an observer. [12]

He completed his doctoral dissertation on Some Theories on the Incidence of Taxation in 1916. [13]

First World War

Rogers was in Europe on his fellowship at the start of the First World War. Reading French, German and Italian newspapers imbued Rogers with a certain neutrality. [14] The sinking of the Lusitania changed that. On 12 May 1915, he wrote to his mother that, prior to the Lusitania, "... hearing the Germans so unjustly run down in French Switzerland, I got in the habit of putting in a word for them now and then". After the Lusitania, he wrote, "I think I have spoken my last word in their favor." [15] He also had his first taste of the mob. Witnessing demonstrations in Rome "knocked the last spark of Socialism out of my soul and with it most of my respect for the labor unions". [16]

Upon returning to the United States and completing his dissertation, Rogers sought to continue in his family's martial tradition. He sought to enlist as a quartermaster in the Officers' Reserve Corps, but was rejected. He served with the Yale battalion along the Texas-Mexico border. He helped to enroll students in the American Ambulance Service thinking he would ship out to France with them but was again rejected. In fall 1917, he accepted a position as a statistician with the Priorities Committee of the Council of National Defense. [17] He was shocked and dismayed to learn the state of U.S. unpreparedness, administrative disorganization, the paucity of information on the economy and the unwillingness of business to co-operate. [18] He opposed direct government control of the economy and sought instead the creation of a system of priorities. [19] With the routinization of management, he left the Council and was commissioned a first lieutenant in the Ordnance Reserve Corps in January 1918 and sent to Europe.

After the Armistice in November, the War Department sent him to work with the War Industries Board. Wesley C. Mitchell, was the foremost U.S. expert on business cycles. Mitchell needed a statistician to help with the publication, History of Prices During the War, a compilation into a uniform format of the price data gathered by the government during the war. Rogers authored Bulletin Number 23 in the project, "Prices of Cotton and Cotton Products", in 1919. [20]

Eager to return to Europe, in April 1919 Rogers joined the Red Cross. He spent two and a half months working in Paris. In late July, he went to Czechoslovakia and returned to the U.S. in the fall. [21]

He had absorbed a good deal of Pareto's pessimism and was an admirer of such works as The Adding Machine and the essays of H. L. Mencken, as well as having witnessed first-hand the destruction in Europe, but Rogers did not share the disillusion of fellow intellectuals of the Lost Generation. Rather, he remained optimistic about the possibilities of U.S. business culture, democracy, altruism and scientific rationalism. [22]

Academic economist

Rogers was an instructor in economics in 1916 and then an associate professor in 1919 at the University of Missouri. He then was an assistant professor in economics at Cornell University from 1920 to 1923 before returning to the University of Missouri, where he was a full professor from 1923 to 1930. He was appointed a professor of political economy in 1930 and, in 1931, the Sterling Professor of Political Economy at Yale University, retaining that professorial chair until his sudden death in 1939. He was an Invited Speaker of the ICM in 1924 at Toronto. [23]

Government economist

While continuously employed as a university professor, Rogers also gave advice and service to the Roosevelt administration. He advised the administration on fiscal policy from 1933 to 1934, was a special representative of the U. S. Treasury Department in the Far East in 1934, and was the American member of the Economic Committee of the League of Nations from 1933 to 1937.

Left to right: Henry Morgenthau Jr., Eugene R. Black, George F. Warren, Samuel Rosman and James Harvey Rogers attend as President Roosevelt signs the Gold Reserve Act into law, 30 January 1934 Franklin Delano Roosevelt signs Gold Bill 1934.jpg
Left to right: Henry Morgenthau Jr., Eugene R. Black, George F. Warren, Samuel Rosman and James Harvey Rogers attend as President Roosevelt signs the Gold Reserve Act into law, 30 January 1934

Death

On 13 August 1939, while on a mission to investigate the status of the Brazilian economy in the Hemispheric Defense Zone, his airplane crashed in the vicinity of Rio de Janeiro. At Roger's pre-arrangement, he is buried in the Welsh Neck Baptist Church Cemetery in Society Hill. [24]

Legacy

The University of Missouri-Columbia has a James Harvey Rogers Chair of Money, Credit and Banking. The James Harvey Rogers papers are available at the Manuscripts and Archives Division of the Sterling Memorial Library at Yale University.

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Joseph Schumpeter</span> Austrian political economist (1883–1950)

Joseph Alois Schumpeter was an Austrian political economist. He served briefly as Finance Minister of Austria in 1919. In 1932, he emigrated to the United States to become a professor at Harvard University, where he remained until the end of his career, and in 1939 obtained American citizenship.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">James Tobin</span> American economist (1918–2002)

James Tobin was an American economist who served on the Council of Economic Advisers and consulted with the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, and taught at Harvard and Yale Universities. He contributed to the development of key ideas in the Keynesian economics of his generation and advocated government intervention in particular to stabilize output and avoid recessions. His academic work included pioneering contributions to the study of investment, monetary and fiscal policy and financial markets. He also proposed an econometric model for censored dependent variables, the well-known tobit model.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Keynesian economics</span> Group of macroeconomic theories

Keynesian economics are the various macroeconomic theories and models of how aggregate demand strongly influences economic output and inflation. In the Keynesian view, aggregate demand does not necessarily equal the productive capacity of the economy. Instead, it is influenced by a host of factors – sometimes behaving erratically – affecting production, employment, and inflation.

Neoclassical economics is an approach to economics in which the production, consumption, and valuation (pricing) of goods and services are observed as driven by the supply and demand model. According to this line of thought, the value of a good or service is determined through a hypothetical maximization of utility by income-constrained individuals and of profits by firms facing production costs and employing available information and factors of production. This approach has often been justified by appealing to rational choice theory, a theory that has come under considerable question in recent years.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Vilfredo Pareto</span> Italian polymath (1848–1923)

Vilfredo Federico Damaso Pareto was an Italian polymath. He made several important contributions to economics, particularly in the study of income distribution and in the analysis of individuals' choices. He was also responsible for popularising the use of the term "elite" in social analysis.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Monetarism</span> School of thought in monetary economics

Monetarism is a school of thought in monetary economics that emphasizes the role of governments in controlling the amount of money in circulation. Monetarist theory asserts that variations in the money supply have major influences on national output in the short run and on price levels over longer periods. Monetarists assert that the objectives of monetary policy are best met by targeting the growth rate of the money supply rather than by engaging in discretionary monetary policy. Monetarism is commonly associated with neoliberalism.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Franco Modigliani</span> Italian-American economist (1918–2003)

Franco Modigliani was an Italian-American economist and the recipient of the 1985 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics. He was a professor at University of Illinois at Urbana–Champaign, Carnegie Mellon University, and MIT Sloan School of Management.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Irving Fisher</span> American economist (1867–1947)

Irving Fisher was an American economist, statistician, inventor, eugenicist and progressive social campaigner. He was one of the earliest American neoclassical economists, though his later work on debt deflation has been embraced by the post-Keynesian school. Joseph Schumpeter described him as "the greatest economist the United States has ever produced", an assessment later repeated by James Tobin and Milton Friedman.

The Chicago school of economics is a neoclassical school of economic thought associated with the work of the faculty at the University of Chicago, some of whom have constructed and popularized its principles. Milton Friedman and George Stigler are considered the leading scholars of the Chicago school.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Lauchlin Currie</span> American economist

Lauchlin Bernard Currie was an economist who worked as White House economic adviser to President Franklin Roosevelt during World War II (1939–45). From 1949 to 1953, he directed a major World Bank mission to Colombia and related studies.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">John B. Taylor</span> American economist (born 1946)

John Brian Taylor is the Mary and Robert Raymond Professor of Economics at Stanford University, and the George P. Shultz Senior Fellow in Economics at Stanford University's Hoover Institution.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Edmund Phelps</span> American economist

Edmund Strother Phelps is an American economist and the recipient of the 2006 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Heterodox economics</span> Economic theories that contrast with orthodox schools of economic thought

Heterodox economics is any economic thought or theory that contrasts with orthodox schools of economic thought, or that may be beyond neoclassical economics. These include institutional, evolutionary, feminist, social, post-Keynesian, ecological, Austrian, complexity, Marxian, socialist, and anarchist economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Alvin Hansen</span> American economist

Alvin Harvey Hansen was an American economist who taught at the University of Minnesota and was later a chair professor of economics at Harvard University. Often referred to as "the American Keynes", he was a widely read popular author on economic issues, and an influential advisor to the government on economic policy. Hansen helped create the Council of Economic Advisors and the Social Security system. He is best remembered today for introducing Keynesian economics in the United States in the 1930s and 40s.

The Lausanne School of economics, sometimes referred to as the Mathematical School, refers to the neoclassical economics school of thought surrounding Léon Walras and Vilfredo Pareto. It is named after the University of Lausanne, at which both Walras and Pareto held professorships. Polish economist Leon Winiarski is also said to have been a member of the Lausanne School.

Applied economics is the study as regards the application of economic theory and econometrics in specific settings. As one of the two sets of fields of economics, it is typically characterized by the application of the core, i.e. economic theory and econometrics to address practical issues in a range of fields including demographic economics, labour economics, business economics, industrial organization, agricultural economics, development economics, education economics, engineering economics, financial economics, health economics, monetary economics, public economics, and economic history. From the perspective of economic development, the purpose of applied economics is to enhance the quality of business practices and national policy making.

In the history of economic thought, a school of economic thought is a group of economic thinkers who share or shared a common perspective on the way economies work. While economists do not always fit into particular schools, particularly in modern times, classifying economists into schools of thought is common. Economic thought may be roughly divided into three phases: premodern, early modern and modern. Systematic economic theory has been developed mainly since the beginning of what is termed the modern era.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Paul Davidson (economist)</span> American macroeconomist (born 1930)

Paul Davidson is an American macroeconomist who has been one of the leading spokesmen of the American branch of the post-Keynesian school in economics. He is a prolific writer and has actively intervened in important debates on economic policy from a position critical of mainstream economics.

Warren Joseph Samuels was an American economist and historian of economic thought. He received a BBA from University of Miami, Miami, FL and obtained his Ph.D. from University of Wisconsin–Madison. After holding academic posts in the University of Missouri, Georgia State University, Atlanta, and University of Miami, he was appointed Professor of Economics in Michigan State University in 1968, where he stayed until his retirement in 1998.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">History of macroeconomic thought</span>

Macroeconomic theory has its origins in the study of business cycles and monetary theory. In general, early theorists believed monetary factors could not affect real factors such as real output. John Maynard Keynes attacked some of these "classical" theories and produced a general theory that described the whole economy in terms of aggregates rather than individual, microeconomic parts. Attempting to explain unemployment and recessions, he noticed the tendency for people and businesses to hoard cash and avoid investment during a recession. He argued that this invalidated the assumptions of classical economists who thought that markets always clear, leaving no surplus of goods and no willing labor left idle.

References

  1. Jones 1966, p. 20.
  2. Sweezy 1972 , p. 116 writes, "There were no full-fledged Keynesians before the General Theory [1936]. This makes it difficult to say who should be included in a list of Keynesians of the early New Deal period. We find elements of Keynesianism in the work of various people but nowhere the complete product. In discussing those who influenced policy in the early period, I have selected a few outstanding people who contributed in one way or another to the evolution of policy in a Keynesian direction." Among those outstanding people, Sweezy considers Rogers.
  3. Thomas, Rev. John Alexander William (1897). A History of Marlboro County: With Traditions and Sketches of Numerous Families. Atlanta, Georgia: The Foote & Davies Company. p.  32.
  4. Jones 1966, pp. 1–2.
  5. Jones 1966, p. 5.
  6. Jones 1966, p. 6.
  7. Jones 1966, pp. 7–9.
  8. 1 2 Bruchey 2000.
  9. Jones 1966, p. 11.
  10. Jones 1966, pp. 16–17.
  11. Jones 1966, p. 23.
  12. Jones 1966, pp. 29–30.
  13. Jones 1966, p. 326.
  14. Jones 1966, p. 30.
  15. Jones 1966, p. 32.
  16. Jones 1966, p. 33.
  17. Jones 1966, p. 36.
  18. Jones 1966, pp. 37–38.
  19. Jones 1966, pp. 39–40.
  20. Jones 1966, p. 44.
  21. Jones 1966, pp. 46–47.
  22. Jones 1966, pp. 47–49.
  23. Rogers, James Harvey. "Vilfredo Pareto, the mathematician of the social sciences". Proceedings of the International Congress of Mathematicians in Toronto, August 11–16. 1924. Vol. 2. pp. 969–972.
  24. Jones 1966, p. 323.

Bibliography

Works by James Harvey Rogers

Secondary sources