The Penrose method (or square-root method) is a method devised in 1946 by Professor Lionel Penrose [1] for allocating the voting weights of delegations (possibly a single representative) in decision-making bodies proportional to the square root of the population represented by this delegation. This is justified by the fact that, due to the square root law of Penrose, the a priori voting power (as defined by the Penrose–Banzhaf index) of a member of a voting body is inversely proportional to the square root of its size. Under certain conditions, this allocation achieves equal voting powers for all people represented, independent of the size of their constituency. Proportional allocation would result in excessive voting powers for the electorates of larger constituencies.
A precondition for the appropriateness of the method is en bloc voting of the delegations in the decision-making body: a delegation cannot split its votes; rather, each delegation has just a single vote to which weights are applied proportional to the square root of the population they represent. Another precondition is that the opinions of the people represented are statistically independent. The representativity of each delegation results from statistical fluctuations within the country, and then, according to Penrose, "small electorates are likely to obtain more representative governments than large electorates." A mathematical formulation of this idea results in the square root rule.
The Penrose method is not currently being used for any notable decision-making body, but it has been proposed for apportioning representation in a United Nations Parliamentary Assembly, [1] [2] and for voting in the Council of the European Union. [3] [4]
Member state | Population | Nice | Penrose [3] | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Germany | 82.54m | 16.5% | 29 | 8.4% | 9.55% | |
France | 59.64m | 12.9% | 29 | 8.4% | 8.11% | |
UK | 59.33m | 12.4% | 29 | 8.4% | 8.09% | |
Italy | 57.32m | 12.0% | 29 | 8.4% | 7.95% | |
Spain | 41.55m | 9.0% | 27 | 7.8% | 6.78% | |
Poland | 38.22m | 7.6% | 27 | 7.8% | 6.49% | |
Romania | 21.77m | 4.3% | 14 | 4.1% | 4.91% | |
Netherlands | 16.19m | 3.3% | 13 | 3.8% | 4.22% | |
Greece | 11.01m | 2.2% | 12 | 3.5% | 3.49% | |
Portugal | 10.41m | 2.1% | 12 | 3.5% | 3.39% | |
Belgium | 10.36m | 2.1% | 12 | 3.5% | 3.38% | |
Czech Rep. | 10.20m | 2.1% | 12 | 3.5% | 3.35% | |
Hungary | 10.14m | 2.0% | 12 | 3.5% | 3.34% | |
Sweden | 8.94m | 1.9% | 10 | 2.9% | 3.14% | |
Austria | 8.08m | 1.7% | 10 | 2.9% | 2.98% | |
Bulgaria | 7.85m | 1.5% | 10 | 2.9% | 2.94% | |
Denmark | 5.38m | 1.1% | 7 | 2.0% | 2.44% | |
Slovakia | 5.38m | 1.1% | 7 | 2.0% | 2.44% | |
Finland | 5.21m | 1.1% | 7 | 2.0% | 2.39% | |
Ireland | 3.96m | 0.9% | 7 | 2.0% | 2.09% | |
Lithuania | 3.46m | 0.7% | 7 | 2.0% | 1.95% | |
Latvia | 2.33m | 0.5% | 4 | 1.2% | 1.61% | |
Slovenia | 2.00m | 0.4% | 4 | 1.2% | 1.48% | |
Estonia | 1.36m | 0.3% | 4 | 1.2% | 1.23% | |
Cyprus | 0.72m | 0.2% | 4 | 1.2% | 0.89% | |
Luxembourg | 0.45m | 0.1% | 4 | 1.2% | 0.70% | |
Malta | 0.40m | 0.1% | 3 | 0.9% | 0.66% | |
EU | 484.20m | 100% | 345 | 100% | 100% |
The Penrose method became revitalised within the European Union when it was proposed by Sweden in 2003 amid negotiations on the Amsterdam Treaty and by Poland June 2007 during summit on the Treaty of Lisbon. In this context, the method was proposed to compute voting weights of member states in the Council of the European Union.
Currently, the voting in the Council of the EU does not follow the Penrose method. Instead, the rules of the Nice Treaty are effective between 2004 and 2014, under certain conditions until 2017. The associated voting weights are compared in the adjacent table along with the population data of the member states.
Besides the voting weight, the voting power (i.e., the Penrose–Banzhaf index) of a member state also depends on the threshold percentage needed to make a decision. Smaller percentages work in favor of larger states. For example, if one state has 30% of the total voting weights while the threshold for decision making is at 29%, this state will have 100% voting power (i.e., an index of 1). For the EU-27, an optimal threshold, at which the voting powers of all citizens in any member state are almost equal, has been computed at about 61.6%. [3] After the university of the authors of this paper, this system is referred to as the "Jagiellonian Compromise". Optimal threshold decreases with the number of the member states as . [6]
According to INFUSA, "The square-root method is more than a pragmatic compromise between the extreme methods of world representation unrelated to population size and allocation of national quotas in direct proportion to population size; Penrose showed that in terms of statistical theory the square-root method gives to each voter in the world an equal influence on decision-making in a world assembly". [2]
Under the Penrose method, the relative voting weights of the most populous countries are lower than their proportion of the world population. In the table below, the countries' voting weights are computed as the square root of their year-2005 population in millions. This procedure was originally published by Penrose in 1946 based on pre-World War II population figures. [1]
Population as of 2005 | Percent of world population | Voting weight | Percent of total weight | ||
World | 6,434,577,575 | 100.00% | 721.32 | 100.00% | |
Rank | Country | ||||
1 | People's Republic of China | 1,306,313,812 | 20.30% | 36.14 | 5.01% |
2 | India | 1,080,264,388 | 16.79% | 32.87 | 4.56% |
3 | United States of America | 297,200,000 | 4.62% | 17.24 | 2.39% |
4 | Indonesia | 241,973,879 | 3.76% | 15.56 | 2.16% |
5 | Brazil | 186,112,794 | 2.89% | 13.64 | 1.89% |
6 | Pakistan | 162,419,946 | 2.52% | 12.74 | 1.77% |
7 | Bangladesh | 144,319,628 | 2.24% | 12.01 | 1.67% |
8 | Russia | 143,420,309 | 2.23% | 11.98 | 1.66% |
9 | Nigeria | 128,771,988 | 2.00% | 11.35 | 1.57% |
10 | Japan | 127,417,244 | 1.98% | 11.29 | 1.56% |
11 | Mexico | 106,202,903 | 1.65% | 10.31 | 1.43% |
12 | Philippines | 87,857,473 | 1.37% | 9.37 | 1.30% |
13 | Vietnam | 83,535,576 | 1.30% | 9.14 | 1.27% |
14 | Germany | 82,468,000 | 1.28% | 9.08 | 1.26% |
15 | Egypt | 77,505,756 | 1.20% | 8.80 | 1.22% |
16 | Ethiopia | 73,053,286 | 1.14% | 8.55 | 1.18% |
17 | Turkey | 69,660,559 | 1.08% | 8.35 | 1.16% |
18 | Iran | 68,017,860 | 1.06% | 8.25 | 1.14% |
19 | Thailand | 65,444,371 | 1.02% | 8.09 | 1.12% |
20 | France | 60,656,178 | 0.94% | 7.79 | 1.08% |
21 | United Kingdom | 60,441,457 | 0.94% | 7.77 | 1.08% |
22 | Democratic Republic of the Congo | 60,085,804 | 0.93% | 7.75 | 1.07% |
23 | Italy | 58,103,033 | 0.90% | 7.62 | 1.06% |
24 | South Korea | 48,422,644 | 0.75% | 6.96 | 0.96% |
25 | Ukraine | 47,425,336 | 0.74% | 6.89 | 0.95% |
26 | South Africa | 44,344,136 | 0.69% | 6.66 | 0.92% |
27 | Spain | 43,209,511 | 0.67% | 6.57 | 0.91% |
28 | Colombia | 42,954,279 | 0.67% | 6.55 | 0.91% |
29 | Myanmar | 42,909,464 | 0.67% | 6.55 | 0.91% |
30 | Sudan | 40,187,486 | 0.62% | 6.34 | 0.88% |
31 | Argentina | 39,537,943 | 0.61% | 6.29 | 0.87% |
32 | Poland | 38,635,144 | 0.60% | 6.22 | 0.86% |
33 | Tanzania | 36,766,356 | 0.57% | 6.06 | 0.84% |
34 | Kenya | 33,829,590 | 0.53% | 5.82 | 0.81% |
35 | Canada | 32,400,000 | 0.50% | 5.69 | 0.79% |
36 | Morocco | 32,725,847 | 0.51% | 5.72 | 0.79% |
37 | Algeria | 32,531,853 | 0.51% | 5.70 | 0.79% |
38 | Afghanistan | 29,928,987 | 0.47% | 5.47 | 0.76% |
39 | Peru | 27,925,628 | 0.43% | 5.28 | 0.73% |
40 | Nepal | 27,676,547 | 0.43% | 5.26 | 0.73% |
41 | Uganda | 27,269,482 | 0.42% | 5.22 | 0.72% |
42 | Uzbekistan | 26,851,195 | 0.42% | 5.18 | 0.72% |
43 | Saudi Arabia | 26,417,599 | 0.41% | 5.14 | 0.71% |
44 | Malaysia | 26,207,102 | 0.41% | 5.12 | 0.71% |
45 | Iraq | 26,074,906 | 0.41% | 5.11 | 0.71% |
46 | Venezuela | 25,375,281 | 0.39% | 5.04 | 0.70% |
47 | North Korea | 22,912,177 | 0.36% | 4.79 | 0.66% |
48 | Republic of China | 22,894,384 | 0.36% | 4.78 | 0.66% |
49 | Romania | 22,329,977 | 0.35% | 4.73 | 0.66% |
50 | Ghana | 21,029,853 | 0.33% | 4.59 | 0.64% |
51 | Yemen | 20,727,063 | 0.32% | 4.55 | 0.63% |
52 | Australia | 20,229,800 | 0.31% | 4.50 | 0.62% |
53 | Sri Lanka | 20,064,776 | 0.31% | 4.48 | 0.62% |
54 | Mozambique | 19,406,703 | 0.30% | 4.41 | 0.61% |
55 | Syria | 18,448,752 | 0.29% | 4.30 | 0.60% |
56 | Madagascar | 18,040,341 | 0.28% | 4.25 | 0.59% |
57 | Côte d'Ivoire | 17,298,040 | 0.27% | 4.16 | 0.58% |
58 | Netherlands | 16,407,491 | 0.25% | 4.05 | 0.56% |
59 | Cameroon | 16,380,005 | 0.25% | 4.05 | 0.56% |
60 | Chile | 16,267,278 | 0.25% | 4.03 | 0.56% |
61 | Kazakhstan | 15,185,844 | 0.24% | 3.90 | 0.54% |
62 | Guatemala | 14,655,189 | 0.23% | 3.83 | 0.53% |
63 | Burkina Faso | 13,925,313 | 0.22% | 3.73 | 0.52% |
64 | Cambodia | 13,607,069 | 0.21% | 3.69 | 0.51% |
65 | Ecuador | 13,363,593 | 0.21% | 3.66 | 0.51% |
66 | Zimbabwe | 12,746,990 | 0.20% | 3.57 | 0.49% |
67 | Mali | 12,291,529 | 0.19% | 3.51 | 0.49% |
68 | Malawi | 12,158,924 | 0.19% | 3.49 | 0.48% |
69 | Niger | 11,665,937 | 0.18% | 3.42 | 0.47% |
70 | Cuba | 11,346,670 | 0.18% | 3.37 | 0.47% |
71 | Zambia | 11,261,795 | 0.18% | 3.36 | 0.47% |
72 | Angola | 11,190,786 | 0.17% | 3.35 | 0.46% |
73 | Senegal | 11,126,832 | 0.17% | 3.34 | 0.46% |
74 | Serbia and Montenegro | 10,829,175 | 0.17% | 3.29 | 0.46% |
75 | Greece | 10,668,354 | 0.17% | 3.27 | 0.45% |
76 | Portugal | 10,566,212 | 0.16% | 3.25 | 0.45% |
77 | Belgium | 10,364,388 | 0.16% | 3.22 | 0.45% |
78 | Belarus | 10,300,483 | 0.16% | 3.21 | 0.44% |
79 | Czech Republic | 10,241,138 | 0.16% | 3.20 | 0.44% |
80 | Hungary | 10,081,000 | 0.16% | 3.18 | 0.44% |
81 | Tunisia | 10,074,951 | 0.16% | 3.17 | 0.44% |
82 | Chad | 9,826,419 | 0.15% | 3.13 | 0.43% |
83 | Guinea | 9,467,866 | 0.15% | 3.08 | 0.43% |
84 | Sweden | 9,001,774 | 0.14% | 3.00 | 0.42% |
85 | Dominican Republic | 8,950,034 | 0.14% | 2.99 | 0.41% |
86 | Bolivia | 8,857,870 | 0.14% | 2.98 | 0.41% |
87 | Somalia | 8,591,629 | 0.13% | 2.93 | 0.41% |
88 | Rwanda | 8,440,820 | 0.13% | 2.91 | 0.40% |
89 | Austria | 8,184,691 | 0.13% | 2.86 | 0.40% |
90 | Haiti | 8,121,622 | 0.13% | 2.85 | 0.40% |
91 | Azerbaijan | 7,911,974 | 0.12% | 2.81 | 0.39% |
92 | Switzerland | 7,489,370 | 0.12% | 2.74 | 0.38% |
93 | Benin | 7,460,025 | 0.12% | 2.73 | 0.38% |
94 | Bulgaria | 7,450,349 | 0.12% | 2.73 | 0.38% |
95 | Tajikistan | 7,163,506 | 0.11% | 2.68 | 0.37% |
96 | Honduras | 6,975,204 | 0.11% | 2.64 | 0.37% |
97 | Israel | 6,955,000 | 0.11% | 2.64 | 0.37% |
98 | El Salvador | 6,704,932 | 0.10% | 2.59 | 0.36% |
99 | Burundi | 6,370,609 | 0.10% | 2.52 | 0.35% |
100 | Paraguay | 6,347,884 | 0.10% | 2.52 | 0.35% |
101 | Laos | 6,217,141 | 0.10% | 2.49 | 0.35% |
102 | Sierra Leone | 6,017,643 | 0.09% | 2.45 | 0.34% |
103 | Libya | 5,765,563 | 0.09% | 2.40 | 0.33% |
104 | Jordan | 5,759,732 | 0.09% | 2.40 | 0.33% |
105 | Togo | 5,681,519 | 0.09% | 2.38 | 0.33% |
106 | Papua New Guinea | 5,545,268 | 0.09% | 2.35 | 0.33% |
107 | Nicaragua | 5,465,100 | 0.08% | 2.34 | 0.32% |
108 | Denmark | 5,432,335 | 0.08% | 2.33 | 0.32% |
109 | Slovakia | 5,431,363 | 0.08% | 2.33 | 0.32% |
110 | Finland | 5,223,442 | 0.08% | 2.29 | 0.32% |
111 | Kyrgyzstan | 5,146,281 | 0.08% | 2.27 | 0.31% |
112 | Turkmenistan | 4,952,081 | 0.08% | 2.23 | 0.31% |
113 | Georgia | 4,677,401 | 0.07% | 2.16 | 0.30% |
114 | Norway | 4,593,041 | 0.07% | 2.14 | 0.30% |
115 | Eritrea | 4,561,599 | 0.07% | 2.14 | 0.30% |
116 | Croatia | 4,495,904 | 0.07% | 2.12 | 0.29% |
117 | Moldova | 4,455,421 | 0.07% | 2.11 | 0.29% |
118 | Singapore | 4,425,720 | 0.07% | 2.10 | 0.29% |
119 | Ireland | 4,130,700 | 0.06% | 2.03 | 0.28% |
120 | New Zealand | 4,098,200 | 0.06% | 2.02 | 0.28% |
121 | Bosnia and Herzegovina | 4,025,476 | 0.06% | 2.01 | 0.28% |
122 | Costa Rica | 4,016,173 | 0.06% | 2.00 | 0.28% |
123 | Lebanon | 3,826,018 | 0.06% | 1.96 | 0.27% |
124 | Central African Republic | 3,799,897 | 0.06% | 1.95 | 0.27% |
125 | Lithuania | 3,596,617 | 0.06% | 1.90 | 0.26% |
126 | Albania | 3,563,112 | 0.06% | 1.89 | 0.26% |
127 | Liberia | 3,482,211 | 0.05% | 1.87 | 0.26% |
128 | Uruguay | 3,415,920 | 0.05% | 1.85 | 0.26% |
129 | Mauritania | 3,086,859 | 0.05% | 1.76 | 0.24% |
130 | Panama | 3,039,150 | 0.05% | 1.74 | 0.24% |
131 | Republic of the Congo | 3,039,126 | 0.05% | 1.74 | 0.24% |
132 | Oman | 3,001,583 | 0.05% | 1.73 | 0.24% |
133 | Armenia | 2,982,904 | 0.05% | 1.73 | 0.24% |
134 | Mongolia | 2,791,272 | 0.04% | 1.67 | 0.23% |
135 | Jamaica | 2,731,832 | 0.04% | 1.65 | 0.23% |
136 | United Arab Emirates | 2,563,212 | 0.04% | 1.60 | 0.22% |
137 | Kuwait | 2,335,648 | 0.04% | 1.53 | 0.21% |
138 | Latvia | 2,290,237 | 0.04% | 1.51 | 0.21% |
139 | Bhutan | 2,232,291 | 0.03% | 1.49 | 0.21% |
140 | Macedonia | 2,045,262 | 0.03% | 1.43 | 0.20% |
141 | Namibia | 2,030,692 | 0.03% | 1.43 | 0.20% |
142 | Slovenia | 2,011,070 | 0.03% | 1.42 | 0.20% |
143 | Lesotho | 1,867,035 | 0.03% | 1.37 | 0.19% |
144 | Botswana | 1,640,115 | 0.03% | 1.28 | 0.18% |
145 | The Gambia | 1,593,256 | 0.02% | 1.26 | 0.17% |
146 | Guinea-Bissau | 1,416,027 | 0.02% | 1.19 | 0.16% |
147 | Gabon | 1,389,201 | 0.02% | 1.18 | 0.16% |
148 | Estonia | 1,332,893 | 0.02% | 1.15 | 0.16% |
149 | Mauritius | 1,230,602 | 0.02% | 1.11 | 0.15% |
150 | Swaziland | 1,173,900 | 0.02% | 1.08 | 0.15% |
151 | Trinidad and Tobago | 1,088,644 | 0.02% | 1.04 | 0.14% |
152 | East Timor | 1,040,880 | 0.02% | 1.02 | 0.14% |
153 | Fiji | 893,354 | 0.01% | 0.95 | 0.13% |
154 | Qatar | 863,051 | 0.01% | 0.93 | 0.13% |
155 | Cyprus | 780,133 | 0.01% | 0.88 | 0.12% |
156 | Guyana | 765,283 | 0.01% | 0.87 | 0.12% |
157 | Bahrain | 688,345 | 0.01% | 0.83 | 0.12% |
158 | Comoros | 671,247 | 0.01% | 0.82 | 0.11% |
159 | Solomon Islands | 538,032 | 0.01% | 0.73 | 0.10% |
160 | Equatorial Guinea | 535,881 | 0.01% | 0.73 | 0.10% |
161 | Djibouti | 476,703 | 0.01% | 0.69 | 0.10% |
162 | Luxembourg | 468,571 | 0.01% | 0.68 | 0.09% |
163 | Suriname | 438,144 | 0.01% | 0.66 | 0.09% |
164 | Cape Verde | 418,224 | 0.01% | 0.65 | 0.09% |
165 | Malta | 398,534 | 0.01% | 0.63 | 0.09% |
166 | Brunei | 372,361 | 0.01% | 0.61 | 0.08% |
167 | Maldives | 349,106 | 0.01% | 0.59 | 0.08% |
168 | The Bahamas | 301,790 | 0.005% | 0.55 | 0.08% |
169 | Iceland | 296,737 | 0.005% | 0.54 | 0.08% |
170 | Belize | 279,457 | 0.004% | 0.53 | 0.07% |
171 | Barbados | 279,254 | 0.004% | 0.53 | 0.07% |
172 | Vanuatu | 205,754 | 0.003% | 0.45 | 0.06% |
173 | São Tomé and Príncipe | 187,410 | 0.003% | 0.43 | 0.06% |
174 | Samoa | 177,287 | 0.003% | 0.42 | 0.06% |
175 | Saint Lucia | 166,312 | 0.003% | 0.41 | 0.06% |
176 | Saint Vincent and the Grenadines | 117,534 | 0.002% | 0.34 | 0.05% |
177 | Tonga | 112,422 | 0.002% | 0.34 | 0.05% |
178 | Federated States of Micronesia | 108,105 | 0.002% | 0.33 | 0.05% |
179 | Kiribati | 103,092 | 0.002% | 0.32 | 0.04% |
180 | Grenada | 89,502 | 0.001% | 0.30 | 0.04% |
181 | Seychelles | 81,188 | 0.001% | 0.28 | 0.04% |
182 | Andorra | 70,549 | 0.001% | 0.27 | 0.04% |
183 | Dominica | 69,029 | 0.001% | 0.26 | 0.04% |
184 | Antigua and Barbuda | 68,722 | 0.001% | 0.26 | 0.04% |
185 | Marshall Islands | 59,071 | 0.001% | 0.24 | 0.03% |
186 | Saint Kitts and Nevis | 38,958 | 0.001% | 0.20 | 0.03% |
187 | Liechtenstein | 33,717 | 0.001% | 0.18 | 0.03% |
188 | Monaco | 32,409 | 0.001% | 0.18 | 0.02% |
189 | San Marino | 28,880 | 0.0004% | 0.17 | 0.02% |
190 | Palau | 20,303 | 0.0003% | 0.14 | 0.02% |
191 | Nauru | 13,048 | 0.0002% | 0.11 | 0.02% |
192 | Tuvalu | 11,636 | 0.0002% | 0.11 | 0.01% |
193 | Vatican City | 921 | 0.00001% | 0.03 | 0.004% |
It has been claimed that the Penrose square root law is limited to votes for which public opinion is equally divided for and against. [7] [8] [9] A study of various elections has shown that this equally-divided scenario is not typical; these elections suggested that voting weights should be distributed according to the 0.9 power of the number of voters represented (in contrast to the 0.5 power used in the Penrose method). [8]
In practice, the theoretical possibility of the decisiveness of a single vote is questionable. Elections results that come close to a tie are likely to be legally challenged, as was the case in the US presidential election in Florida in 2000, which suggests that no single vote is pivotal. [8]
In addition, a minor technical issue is that the theoretical argument for allocation of voting weight is based on the possibility that an individual has a deciding vote in each representative's area. This scenario is only possible when each representative has an odd number of voters in their area. [9]
Proportional representation (PR) refers to any type of electoral system under which subgroups of an electorate are reflected proportionately in the elected body. The concept applies mainly to political divisions among voters. The essence of such systems is that all votes cast – or almost all votes cast – contribute to the result and are effectively used to help elect someone. Under other election systems, a bare plurality or a scant majority are all that are used to elect candidates. PR systems provide balanced representation to different factions, reflecting how votes are cast.
The D'Hondt method, also called the Jefferson method or the greatest divisors method, is an apportionment method for allocating seats in parliaments among federal states, or in proportional representation among political parties. It belongs to the class of highest-averages methods. Compared to ideal proportional representation, the D'Hondt method reduces somewhat the political fragmentation for smaller electoral district sizes, where it favors larger political parties over small parties.
The Webster method, also called the Sainte-Laguë method, is a highest averages apportionment method for allocating seats in a parliament among federal states, or among parties in a party-list proportional representation system. The Sainte-Laguë method shows a more equal seats-to-votes ratio for different sized parties among apportionment methods.
The highest averages, divisor, or divide-and-round methods are a family of apportionment algorithms that aim to fairly divide a legislature between several groups, such as political parties or states. More generally, divisor methods can be used to round shares of a total, e.g. percentage points.
Lionel Sharples Penrose, FRS was an English psychiatrist, medical geneticist, paediatrician, mathematician and chess theorist, who carried out pioneering work on the genetics of intellectual disability. Penrose was initially the Galton professor of eugenics (1945–1963) at University College London, before having his title changed to professor of human genetics (1963–1965) at his request. He was later emeritus professor.
The apportionment of seats within the European Parliament to each member state of the European Union is set out by the EU treaties. According to European Union treaties, the distribution of seats is "degressively proportional" to the population of the member states, with negotiations and agreements between member states playing a role. Thus the allocation of seats is not strictly proportional to the size of a state's population, nor does it reflect any other automatically triggered or fixed mathematical formula. The process can be compared to the composition of the electoral college used to elect the President of the United States of America in that, pro rata, the smaller state received more places in the electoral college than the more populous states.
The Gallagher index measures an electoral system's relative disproportionality between votes received and seats in a legislature. As such, it measures the difference between the percentage of votes each party gets and the percentage of seats each party gets in the resulting legislature, and it also measures this disproportionality from all parties collectively in any one given election. That collective disproportionality from the election is given a precise score, which can then be used in comparing various levels of proportionality among various elections from various electoral systems. The Gallagher index is a statistical analysis methodology utilised within political science, notably the branch of psephology.
The Banzhaf power index, named after John Banzhaf, is a power index defined by the probability of changing an outcome of a vote where voting rights are not necessarily equally divided among the voters or shareholders.
Apportionment is the process by which seats in a legislative body are distributed among administrative divisions, such as states or parties, entitled to representation. This page presents the general principles and issues related to apportionment. The page apportionment by country describes the specific practices used around the world. The page Mathematics of apportionment describes mathematical formulations and properties of apportionment rules.
The procedures for voting in the Council of the European Union are described in the treaties of the European Union. The Council of the European Union has had its voting procedure amended by subsequent treaties and currently operates on the system set forth in the Treaty of Lisbon. The system is known as qualified majority voting is a type of consociational democracy.
Spain is a European Parliament constituency for elections in the European Union covering the member state of Spain. It is currently represented by 61 Members of the European Parliament and is the second largest European Parliament constituency in terms of geographic area after France, as well as the third most populated after Germany and France.
Weighted voting refers to voting rules that grant some voters a greater influence than others. Examples include publicly-traded companies, as well as the European council, where the number of votes of each member state is roughly proportional to the square root of the population.
In economics, philosophy, and social choice theory, a person's entitlement refers to the value of goods they are owed or deserve, i.e. the total value of the goods or resources that a player would ideally receive. For example, in party-list proportional representation, a party's seat entitlement is equal to its share of the vote, times the number of seats in the legislature.
The Treaty of Lisbon is an international agreement that amends the two treaties which form the constitutional basis of the European Union (EU). The Treaty of Lisbon, which was signed by all EU member states on 13 December 2007, entered into force on 1 December 2009. It amends the Maastricht Treaty (1992), known in updated form as the Treaty on European Union (2007) or TEU, as well as the Treaty of Rome (1957), known in updated form as the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (2007) or TFEU. It also amends the attached treaty protocols as well as the Treaty establishing the European Atomic Energy Community (EURATOM).
Degressive or progressive proportionality is an approach to the allocation of seats in a legislature or other decision-making body. Degressive proportionality means that while the subdivisions do not each elect an equal number of members, smaller subdivisions are allocated more seats than would be allocated strictly in proportion to their population. The seats-to-votes ratio decreases for larger subdivisions.
Direct representation or proxy representation is a form of representative democracy where voters can vote for any candidate in the land, and each representative's vote is weighted in proportion to the number of citizens who have chosen that candidate to represent them.
In the mathematical theory of games, the Penrose square root law, originally formulated by Lionel Penrose, concerns the distribution of the voting power in a voting body consisting of N members. It states that the a priori voting power of any voter, measured by the Penrose–Banzhaf index scales like .
The Jagiellonian compromise is an electoral system for two-tier voting bodies originally proposed in 2004 for the Council of the European Union as a way of achieving "one person, one vote" within the union. The compromise was analysed by various authors and received attention in the popular press. The system is based on the square root law of Penrose, which implies that a priori voting power defined by the Penrose–Banzhaf index of a member of a voting body is inversely proportional to the square root of its size. Hence the number of votes obtained by a representative of a state with population is proportional to . Jagiellonian Compromise is based on a single criterion only. Decision of the Council of the union of member states is taken if the sum of the weights of states voting in favour of a given proposal exceeds the qualified majority quota equal to
This is the results breakdown of the European Parliament election held in Spain on 26 May 2019. The following tables show detailed results in each of the country's 17 autonomous communities and in the autonomous cities of Ceuta and Melilla.
Optimal apportionment is an approach to apportionment that is based on mathematical optimization.