Decoupling of wages from productivity

Last updated

The decoupling of wages from productivity, sometimes known as the great decoupling,[ citation needed ] is the gap between the growth rate of median wages and the growth rate of GDP. Economists began to acknowledge this problem toward the end of the twentieth century and the beginning of the twenty-first century. This problem furthermore leads to wage stagnation despite continued economic growth. [1] [2] [3]

Contents

A number of causes have been hypothesized, including advances in technology such as automation, globalization, self-employment and wage inequality. [4] [5] [6] Some commentators argue that some or all of the Great Decoupling can be explained as the product of faulty assumptions about the underlying economics. [7] [8]

Background

Average wages (solid line) vs GDP per hour worked (dotted line) in the G7 from 1990 to 2020 Average wages and GDP per hour worked in G7.svg
Average wages (solid line) vs GDP per hour worked (dotted line) in the G7 from 1990 to 2020

On average across 24 OECD countries, there has been significant decoupling of real median wage growth from productivity growth over the past two decades. There have been large cross-country differences, both in overall decoupling and the extent to which it has gone together with real median wage stagnation. In a number of countries with above-average productivity growth, such as Korea, Poland or the Slovak Republic, real median wages have grown well above the OECD average despite significant wage-productivity decoupling. However, where productivity growth has been around or below the OECD average, such as in Canada, Japan and the United States, decoupling has been associated with near-stagnation of real median wages. [8] In about a third of the covered OECD countries, real median wages have grown at similar or even higher rates than labour productivity. In some countries, such as the Czech Republic or Sweden, this has been associated with above-average real median wage growth, but in some others with below-average productivity growth, including Italy and Spain, real median wages have nonetheless grown at very low rates. [3]

There have also been large differences in the relative contributions of labour shares and wage inequality to overall decoupling, suggesting that country-specific factors matter, including labour and product market policies and the level and distribution of skills in the population. For instance, in the United States around half of the decoupling (0.6 percentage points of 1.3 percentage points) is explained by the decline in the labour share while it explains virtually all decoupling in Japan. [3]

The aggregate decoupling of median wages from productivity partly reflects declines in labour shares at the technological frontier (defined as the top 5% of firms in terms of labour productivity within each country group in each industry and year). In countries where aggregate labour shares have declined, the decoupling of real wages from productivity has been particularly pronounced in firms at the technological frontier. [8] This could indicate the presence of "winner-takes-most" dynamics, as frontier firms take advantage of technology or globalisation-related increases in economies of scale and scope to reduce the share of fixed labour costs in value-added (e.g. related to research and development, product design or marketing) and/or again a dominant position that allows them to raise their mark-ups. [9] By contrast, there has been no such decoupling of real wages from productivity in frontier firms in countries where labour shares have increased.

Causes

Technological change

Expansion of global value chains

Recent OECD analysis further suggests that global value chain expansion has compressed labour shares. [10] Indeed, an increase in global value chain participation of 10 percentage points of value added reduces the labour share by 1 percentage point. Given that the average increase in global value chain participation observed in the OECD over 1995–2013 was around 6 percentage points of value added, this suggests that on average across countries the expansion of global value chains reduced the labour share by 0.6 percentage points. With the caveat that global value chain expansion is unlikely to be independent of technological change, [15] quantitatively its effect appears to be only around a third of that from declines in relative investment prices. Trade integration also appears to play a role in increased wage inequality. At the aggregate level, the ratio of median to average wages is negatively associated with value added imports, especially from China. [13] This could reflect the fact that increased trade integration with China has reduced labour demand more among low-skilled workers than among high-skilled workers. [16]

Evidence from micro-aggregated data further suggests that betweenfirm wage dispersion increased in sectors that became more open to trade. [14] Overall, the empirical evidence based on a variety of data sources and methodologies consistently suggests that technological change and increased trade integration have contributed to the decoupling of median wages from productivity, both by lowering labour shares and raising wage inequality. This does not imply that technological change and increased trade integration harm workers, since a large body of evidence suggests that these developments raise aggregate productivity, including through efficiency-enhancing reallocation, reduce prices and expand the range of available products. [17] However, it raises the question of how public policies can contribute to the broader sharing of the productivity gains from technological change and increased trade integration.

Role of public policies and institutions

Public policies play a key role in ensuring that productivity gains from technological change and global value chain expansion are broadly shared with workers. Based on several recent OECD studies, a number of key findings emerge. In particular, enhancing and preserving workers’ skills is crucial not only for raising productivity growth but also for promoting a broader sharing of productivity gains, both by supporting wages at the bottom of the wage distribution and raising labour shares. By contrast, a number of other policies that tend to raise productivity growth can have conflicting effects on labour shares and wage inequality, with the relative size of these effects likely to depend on initial policy settings. [8]

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Labour economics</span> Study of the markets for wage labour

Labour economics, or labor economics, seeks to understand the functioning and dynamics of the markets for wage labour. Labour is a commodity that is supplied by labourers, usually in exchange for a wage paid by demanding firms. Because these labourers exist as parts of a social, institutional, or political system, labour economics must also account for social, cultural and political variables.

A minimum wage is the lowest remuneration that employers can legally pay their employees—the price floor below which employees may not sell their labor. Most countries had introduced minimum wage legislation by the end of the 20th century. Because minimum wages increase the cost of labor, companies often try to avoid minimum wage laws by using gig workers, by moving labor to locations with lower or nonexistent minimum wages, or by automating job functions. Minimum wage policies can vary significantly between countries or even within a country, with different regions, sectors, or age groups having their own minimum wage rates. These variations are often influenced by factors such as the cost of living, regional economic conditions, and industry-specific factors.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economic growth</span> Measure of increase in market value of goods

Economic growth can be defined as the increase or improvement in the inflation-adjusted market value of the goods and services produced by an economy in a financial year. Statisticians conventionally measure such growth as the percent rate of increase in the real and nominal gross domestic product (GDP).

Productivity is the efficiency of production of goods or services expressed by some measure. Measurements of productivity are often expressed as a ratio of an aggregate output to a single input or an aggregate input used in a production process, i.e. output per unit of input, typically over a specific period of time. The most common example is the (aggregate) labour productivity measure, one example of which is GDP per worker. There are many different definitions of productivity and the choice among them depends on the purpose of the productivity measurement and data availability. The key source of difference between various productivity measures is also usually related to how the outputs and the inputs are aggregated to obtain such a ratio-type measure of productivity.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Living wage</span> Minimum income to meet a workers basic needs

A living wage is defined as the minimum income necessary for a worker to meet their basic needs. This is not the same as a subsistence wage, which refers to a biological minimum, or a solidarity wage, which refers to a minimum wage tracking labor productivity. Needs are defined to include food, housing, and other essential needs such as clothing. The goal of a living wage is to allow a worker to afford a basic but decent standard of living through employment without government subsidies. Due to the flexible nature of the term "needs", there is not one universally accepted measure of what a living wage is and as such it varies by location and household type. A related concept is that of a family wage – one sufficient to not only support oneself, but also to raise a family.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Real wages</span> Wages adjusted for inflation or in terms of the amount of goods and services that can be bought

Real wages are wages adjusted for inflation, or, equivalently, wages in terms of the amount of goods and services that can be bought. This term is used in contrast to nominal wages or unadjusted wages.

International economics is concerned with the effects upon economic activity from international differences in productive resources and consumer preferences and the international institutions that affect them. It seeks to explain the patterns and consequences of transactions and interactions between the inhabitants of different countries, including trade, investment and transaction.

In economics, total-factor productivity (TFP), also called multi-factor productivity, is usually measured as the ratio of aggregate output to aggregate inputs. Under some simplifying assumptions about the production technology, growth in TFP becomes the portion of growth in output not explained by growth in traditionally measured inputs of labour and capital used in production. TFP is calculated by dividing output by the weighted geometric average of labour and capital input, with the standard weighting of 0.7 for labour and 0.3 for capital. Total factor productivity is a measure of productive efficiency in that it measures how much output can be produced from a certain amount of inputs. It accounts for part of the differences in cross-country per-capita income. For relatively small percentage changes, the rate of TFP growth can be estimated by subtracting growth rates of labor and capital inputs from the growth rate of output.

In economics, the Baumol effect, also known as Baumol's cost disease, is the rise of wages in jobs that have experienced little or no increase in labor productivity in response to rising wages in other jobs that have experienced higher productivity growth. The phenomenon was described by William J. Baumol and William G. Bowen in the 1960s and is an example of cross elasticity of demand.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Demand-led growth</span>

Demand-led growth is the foundation of an economic theory claiming that an increase in aggregate demand will ultimately cause an increase in total output in the long run. This is based on a hypothetical sequence of events where an increase in demand will, in effect, stimulate an increase in supply. This stands in opposition to the common neo-classical theory that demand follows supply, and consequently, that supply determines growth in the long run.

Economics of participation is an umbrella term spanning the economic analysis of worker cooperatives, labor-managed firms, profit sharing, gain sharing, employee ownership, employee stock ownership plans, works councils, codetermination, and other mechanisms which employees use to participate in their firm's decision making and financial results.

Alan Manning is a British economist and professor of economics at the London School of Economics.

In Marxist theory and Marxian economics, the immiseration thesis, also referred to as emiseration thesis, is derived from Karl Marx's analysis of economic development in capitalism, implying that the nature of capitalist production stabilizes real wages, reducing wage growth relative to total value creation in the economy. Even if real wages rise, therefore, the overall labor share of income decreases, leading to the increasing power of capital in society.

Wage compression refers to the empirical regularity that wages for low-skilled workers and wages for high-skilled workers tend toward one another. As a result, the prevailing wage for a low-skilled worker exceeds the market-clearing wage, resulting in unemployment for low-skilled workers. Meanwhile, the prevailing wage for high-skilled workers is below the market-clearing wage, creating a short supply of high-skilled workers.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Causes of income inequality in the United States</span> Overview of the various possible causes of income inequality in the United States of America

Causes of income inequality in the United States describes the reasons for the unequal distribution of income in the US and the factors that cause it to change over time. This topic is subject to extensive ongoing research, media attention, and political interest.

Giovanni Peri is an Italian-born American economist who is Professor and Chair of the Department of Economics at the University of California, Davis, where he directs the Global Migration Center. He is also a research associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research and the co-editor of the peer-reviewed Journal of the European Economic Association. He is known for his research on the economic impact of immigration to the United States. He has also researched the economic determinants of international migrations and the Economic impact of immigration in several European Countries. He has challenged and broadened the work of George Borjas, which has argued that immigration has negative economic effects on low educated US workers.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Stephen Machin</span>

Stephen Jonathan Machin is a British economist and professor of economics at the London School of Economics (LSE). Moreover, he is currently director of the Centre for Economic Performance (CEP) and is a fellow of the British Academy, the Society of Labor Economists and the European Economic Association. His current research interests include labour market inequality, the economics of education, and the economics of crime.

Engels' pause is a term coined by economic historian Robert C. Allen to describe the period from 1790 to 1840, when British working-class wages stagnated and per-capita gross domestic product expanded rapidly during a technological upheaval. Allen named the period after German philosopher Friedrich Engels, who describes it in The Condition of the Working Class in England. Economists have analyzed its causes and effects since the nineteenth century, with some questioning its existence. Twenty-first-century technological upheaval and wage stagnation have led economists and academics to draw parallels between the two periods.

Holger Görg is a German economist who currently works as Professor of International Economics at the University of Kiel. Görg also leads the Kiel Center for Globalization and heads the Research Area "Global Division of Labour" at the Kiel Institute for the World Economy. In 2009, he was awarded the Gossen Prize for his contributions to the study of firms' decisions to invest, export and outsource parts of their value chains abroad.

Wage growth is a rise of wage adjusted for inflations, often expressed in percentage. In macroeconomics, wage growth is one of the main indications to measure economic growth for a long-term since it reflects the consumer's purchasing power in the economy as well as the level of living standards. An increase in wage growth implies price inflation in the economy while a low wage growth indicates deflation that needs artificial interferences such as through fiscal policies by federal/state government. Minimum wage law is often introduced to increase wage growth by stimulating price inflations from corresponding purchasing powers in the economy. Wage growth can also be maximised through the development of industry factors by investing skilled workers in which decision made by businesses. More financial compensation for skilled workers not only lifts wage growth but stimulates higher market prices in the economy.

References

  1. Brynjolfsson, Erik; McAfee, Andrew (2013). "The Great Decoupling". mitsloan.mit.edu. Retrieved 23 November 2020.
  2. Škare, Marinko; Škare, Damian (4 May 2017). "Is the great decoupling real?". Journal of Business Economics and Management. 18 (3): 451–467. doi: 10.3846/16111699.2017.1323793 . ISSN   1611-1699.
  3. 1 2 3 Schwellnus, Cyrille; Kappeler, Andreas; Pionnier, Pierre-Alain (31 January 2017). "Decoupling of wages from productivity: Macro-level facts". OECD Economics Department Working Papers. doi:10.1787/d4764493-en.{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  4. "OECD Economic Outlook, Volume 2018 Issue 2, Chapter 2: Decoupling of wages from productivity: what implications for public policies?" (PDF). OECD. 2018. p. 51. Retrieved 23 November 2020.
  5. "Wage growth and productivity growth: the myth and reality of 'decoupling'". British Politics and Policy at LSE. 13 January 2014. Retrieved 23 November 2020.
  6. Schwellnus, Cyrille (2019). "Decoupling of wages from productivity" (PDF). OECD. Retrieved 23 November 2020.
  7. Pessoa, João Paulo; Van Reenen, John (October 2013). "CEP Discussion Paper No 1246: Decoupling of Wage Growth and Productivity Growth? Myth and Reality" (PDF). cep.lse.ac.uk. Retrieved 23 November 2020.
  8. 1 2 3 4 "Decoupling of wages from productivity: What implications for public policies? – OECD". www.oecd.org. Retrieved 30 April 2021.
  9. Calligaris, Sara; Criscuolo, Chiara; Marcolin, Luca (25 April 2018). "Mark-ups in the digital era". OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers. doi: 10.1787/4efe2d25-en . S2CID   158520096.{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  10. 1 2 Schwellnus, Cyrille; Pak, Mathilde; Pionnier, Pierre-Alain; Crivellaro, Elena (4 September 2018). "Labour share developments over the past two decades: The role of technological progress, globalisation and "winner-takes-most" dynamics". OECD Economics Department Working Papers. doi:10.1787/3eb9f9ed-en. S2CID   54962424.{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  11. Autor, David; Salomons, Anna (30 July 2018). "Is Automation Labor-Displacing? Productivity Growth, Employment, and the Labor Share". doi: 10.3386/w24871 . S2CID   219376868.{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  12. Acemoglu, Daron; Restrepo, Pascual (June 2018). "The Race between Man and Machine: Implications of Technology for Growth, Factor Shares, and Employment". American Economic Review. 108 (6): 1488–1542. doi: 10.1257/aer.20160696 . ISSN   0002-8282.
  13. 1 2 OECD (7 December 2018). OECD Economic Outlook, Volume 2018 Issue 2. OECD Publishing. ISBN   978-92-64-30873-2.
  14. 1 2 Berlingieri, Giuseppe; Blanchenay, Patrick; Criscuolo, Chiara (12 May 2017). "The great divergence(s)". OECD Science, Technology and Industry Policy Papers. doi:10.1787/953f3853-en.{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  15. Baker, Scott R.; Bloom, Nicholas; Davis, Steven J. (11 July 2016). "Measuring Economic Policy Uncertainty*". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 131 (4): 1593–1636. doi: 10.1093/qje/qjw024 . ISSN   1531-4650.
  16. Autor, David H.; Dorn, David; Hanson, Gordon H. (31 October 2016). "The China Shock: Learning from Labor-Market Adjustment to Large Changes in Trade". Annual Review of Economics. 8 (1): 205–240. doi:10.1146/annurev-economics-080315-015041. ISSN   1941-1383. S2CID   1415485.
  17. Melitz, Marc J.; Redding, Stephen J. (May 2014). "Missing Gains from Trade?". American Economic Review. 104 (5): 317–321. doi:10.1257/aer.104.5.317. ISSN   0002-8282. S2CID   15370295.