Gianmarco Ottaviano

Last updated

Gianmarco Ireo Paolo Ottaviano (born in Milan on September 29, 1967) is an Italian economist and Professor of Economics at Bocconi University. [1]

Contents

Biography

A native of Milan, Gianmarco Ottaviano earned a bachelor's degree in Economic and Social Sciences from Bocconi University in 1991, followed by a M.Sc. in economics from the London School of Economics in 1993, a diploma in international economics from the Graduate Institute of International Studies in Geneva in 1994, a doctorate from Bari in 1995 and a Ph.D. in economics under Jacques-François Thisse at the Université Catholique de Louvain in 1998. He then took up a position as assistant professor of economics at the University of Bologna, followed by an associate professorship at Bocconi in 2000, and a full professorship at Bologna in 2002. In 2008, Ottaviano returned to Bocconi before moving to the London School of Economics in 2013, where he directed the Trade Programme of the Centre for Economic Performance, and back to Bocconi in 2019.

He is affiliated with the Centre for Economic Policy Research, Center for Financial Studies, Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Centre for Research and Analysis of Migration, and the Leverhulme Centre for Research on Globalisation and Economic Policy. Moreover, he is a member of the scientific advisory boards of the Central Bank Research Association and the Centre d'Etudes Prospectives et d'Informations Internationales (CEPII), among others. In terms of professional service, he performs editorial duties at Economica , the Italian Economic Journal , Spatial Economic Analysis , Regional Science and Urban Economics , Politica Economica , and the Revue Région et Développement , and has been on editorial boards of Economic Policy , International Economics , Journal of the European Economic Association , Journal of Economic Geography , Journal of Regional Science , and the Journal of Urban Economics in the past. [2]

Research

Gianmarco Ottaviano's research areas include capital movements and multinational firms, development and growth, economic integration, international trade, international migration, and regional cohesion. [1]

Research on the economics of agglomeration

Reviewing the literature on economic geography, Ottaviano and Diego Puga reconcile the conclusions of Spence (1976) and Dixit and Stiglitz (1977): stronger competition in local product and factor markets causes spatial dispersion, though firms tend to locate close to large markets in order to take advantage of increasing returns to scale and keep trade costs low, which in turn creates pecuniary externalities fostering economic agglomeration. By affecting trade costs, economic integration then shapes the spatial location of economic activities and explains a range of patterns such as offshoring, local immigration and infra-regional development. [3] In that context, Ottaviano and Rikard Forslid developed an extension of Krugman's classical core-periphery model through the introduction of heterogeneity in workers' skills and mobility. [4] Moreover, Ottaviano, Takatoshi Tabuchi and Jacques-François Thisse have shown that the insights from new economic geography models à la Dixit and Stiglitz (1976) do not depend on the choice of modelling framework by developing a distinct modelling framework that yielded the same results. [5] Ottaviano and Thisse's perspective on the relationship between agglomeration and economic geography is elaborated in a chapter of the Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics. [6]

In another study on the link between agglomeration and growth with Philippe Martin, Ottaviano showed how both processes can be mutually self-reinforcing, as agglomeration reduces the cost of innovation and thereby raises growth, while growth further fosters agglomeration as new firms cluster close to the sector from which innovation originates. [7] They similarly showed how growth, FDI, and industrial concentration are mediated through transaction costs and R&D spillovers, with important implications for economic development. [8] In further work with Richard Baldwin, Ottaviano and Martin showed how the industrialization and growth take-off of rich northern countries, massive global income divergences and then convergence through trade integration can be explained through changes in trade costs. [9]

Research on the economics of international trade

Together with Marc Melitz, Ottaviano developed a trade model in which productivity and price mark-ups respond to size and integration of a market through international trade, with higher integration enabling tougher competition and thus also changing the composition of producers and exporters in that market. [10] Expanding this framework in further work with Thierry Mayer to firms' product mixes and range of exported products, Ottaviano and Melitz confirmed the claim that tougher competition in an export market induces firms to skew their export sales towards their best performing products, a finding that is confirmed for French exporters and bears important implications for firms' productivity. [11] In earlier work on the internationalisation of European firms, Ottaviano and Mayer observed that a few high-performing firms drive their countries' international performance, suggesting that economic integration policies should focus on raising the number of international firms rather than "deepening" the international involvement of already internationalized firms. [12]

Research on migration and diversity

In joint work with Giovanni Peri, Ottaviano investigated the relationship between linguistic diversity across U.S. cities and local productivity over 1970–90; together, they find that wages and employment density of U.S.-born workers were systematically higher, all else equal, in cities with higher linguistic diversity, especially for highly educated and for white workers, and that the relationship was strengthened the better non-native speakers were assimilated in terms of language skills and duration of residence. [13] Further research by Ottaviano and Peri on the value of cultural diversity - as proxied by the diversity of countries of birth of U.S. residents - suggested that US-born citizens living in metropolitan areas with increasing shares of foreign-born residents experienced significant growth in wages and housing values. [14] Their thinking about the effects of immigration on natives' wages turns around the notion that natives and foreigners are inherently imperfectly substitutable even within the same skill group. Using this framework, they showed that immigration to the U.S. in 1990-2006 had small negative short-run effects on native high school dropouts (-0.7%) and average wages (-0.4%), while raising the wages of native high school dropouts and average native wages in the long run by 0.3% and 0.6%, respectively, but depressing the long-run wages of previous immigrants by 6.7%. [15] [16] [17] Another study by Ottaviano with Peri and Greg Wright observed that manufacturing industries with a larger increase in exposure to globalization (through offshoring or immigration) saw improvements in terms of native employment growth relative to less exposed industries. They explain this finding through a model wherein natives, immigrants and offshore workers differ systematically in their ability to apply complex skills and wherein jobs vary in the degree to which their performance requires complex skills. In this framework, the productivity effect related to more efficient task assignment - producers hiring natives, immigrants and offshore workers for different tasks according to their respective comparative advantage - may offset the displacement effect of immigration and offshoring on natives' employment. [18] Finally, with regard to the labour market effects of immigration to Western Germany during the 1990s, Ottaviano - together with Peri and Francesco d'Amuri - found that immigration had a sizeable adverse effect on previous immigrants' employment and a small adverse effect on their wages, while having very little adverse effects on native wages and employments; the authors explain this divergence through the higher substitutability between different groups of immigrants relative to that between immigrants and natives. [19]

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economic geography</span> Subfield of human geography and economics

Economic geography is the subfield of human geography that studies economic activity and factors affecting it. It can also be considered a subfield or method in economics. There are four branches of economic geography.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economies of agglomeration</span> Urban development in locations generating cost savings

One of the major subfields of urban economics, economies of agglomeration, explains, in broad terms, how urban agglomeration occurs in locations where cost savings can naturally arise. This term is most often discussed in terms of economic firm productivity. However, agglomeration effects also explain some social phenomena, such as large proportions of the population being clustered in cities and major urban centers. Similar to economies of scale, the costs and benefits of agglomerating increase the larger the agglomerated urban cluster becomes. Several prominent examples of where agglomeration has brought together firms of a specific industry are: Silicon Valley and Los Angeles being hubs of technology and entertainment, respectively, in California, United States; and London, United Kingdom, being a hub of finance.

A jobless recovery or jobless growth is an economic phenomenon in which a macroeconomy experiences growth while maintaining or decreasing its level of employment. The term was coined by the economist Nick Perna in the early 1990s.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Masahisa Fujita</span> Japanese economist (born 1943)

Masahisa Fujita is a Japanese economist who has studied regional science, urban economics, international trade, and spatial economy. He is a professor at Konan University and an adjunct professor at Institute of Economic Research, Kyoto University.

New trade theory (NTT) is a collection of economic models in international trade theory which focuses on the role of increasing returns to scale and network effects, which were originally developed in the late 1970s and early 1980s. The main motivation for the development of NTT was that, contrary to what traditional trade models would suggest, the majority of the world trade takes place between countries that are similar in terms of development, structure, and factor endowments.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Immigration</span> Movement of people into another country or region to which they are not native

Immigration is the international movement of people to a destination country of which they are not usual residents or where they do not possess nationality in order to settle as permanent residents. Commuters, tourists, and other short-term stays in a destination country do not fall under the definition of immigration or migration; seasonal labour immigration is sometimes included, however.

Spatial inequality refers to the unequal distribution of income and resources across geographical regions. Attributable to local differences in infrastructure, geographical features and economies of agglomeration, such inequality remains central to public policy discussions regarding economic inequality more broadly.

Economics of participation is an umbrella term spanning the economic analysis of worker cooperatives, labor-managed firms, profit sharing, gain sharing, employee ownership, employee stock ownership plans, works councils, codetermination, and other mechanisms which employees use to participate in their firm's decision making and financial results.

Cluster theory is a theory of strategy.

The economic impact of illegal immigrants in the United States is challenging to measure and politically contentious. Research shows that illegal immigrants increase the size of the U.S. economy/contribute to economic growth, enhance the welfare of natives, contribute more in tax revenue than they collect, reduce American firms' incentives to offshore jobs and import foreign-produced goods, and benefit consumers by reducing the prices of goods and services.

International trade theory is a sub-field of economics which analyzes the patterns of international trade, its origins, and its welfare implications. International trade policy has been highly controversial since the 18th century. International trade theory and economics itself have developed as means to evaluate the effects of trade policies.

Alan Manning is a British economist and professor of economics at the London School of Economics.

The economics of digitization is the field of economics that studies how digitization, digitalisation and digital transformation affects markets and how digital data can be used to study economics. Digitization is the process by which technology lowers the costs of storing, sharing, and analyzing data. This has changed how consumers behave, how industrial activity is organized, and how governments operate. The economics of digitization exists as a distinct field of economics for two reasons. First, new economic models are needed because many traditional assumptions about information no longer hold in a digitized world. Second, the new types of data generated by digitization require new methods for their analysis.

Giovanni Peri is an Italian-born American economist who is Professor and Chair of the Department of Economics at the University of California, Davis, where he directs the Global Migration Center. He is also a research associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research and the co-editor of the peer-reviewed Journal of the European Economic Association. He is known for his research on the economic impact of immigration to the United States. He has also researched the economic determinants of international migrations and the Economic impact of immigration in several European Countries. He has challenged and broadened the work of George Borjas, which has argued that immigration has negative economic effects on low educated US workers.

Thierry Mayer is a French economist and Professor of Economics at Sciences Po. He belongs to the most frequently-cited economists in the field of international trade. In 2006, Mayer and Etienne Wasmer were awarded the Best Young Economist of France Award by Cercle des économistes and Le Monde.

Frédéric Docquier is a Belgian economist and Professor of Economics at the Catholic University of Louvain (UCLouvain). He ranks as one of the leading economists in the field of international migration, with a focus on brain drain and skilled migration.

The decoupling of wages from productivity, sometimes known as the great decoupling, is the gap between the growth rate of median wages and the growth rate of GDP. Economists began to acknowledge this problem toward the end of the twentieth century and the beginning of the twenty-first century. This problem furthermore leads to wage stagnation despite continued economic growth.

Immigration to the United States has many effects on the culture and politics of the United States.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Bibliography of Germany</span>

This is a list of books in the English language which deal with Germany and its geography, history, inhabitants, culture, biota, etc.

James R. Markusen is an American economist, academic, and author. He is Distinguished Professor (emeritus) at the University of Colorado, Boulder.

References

  1. 1 2 Profile of Gianmarco Ottaviano at Bocconi University. Retrieved July 3rd, 2019.
  2. CV of Gianmarco Ottaviano from the website of the London School of Economics. Retrieved July 3rd, 2019.
  3. Ottaviano, Gianmarco I. P.; Puga, Diego (1998). "Agglomeration in the Global Economy: A Survey of the 'New Economic Geography'". The World Economy. 21 (6): 707–731. doi:10.1111/1467-9701.00160.
  4. Forslid, Rikard; Ottaviano, Gianmarco I. P. (2003). "An analytically solvable core-periphery model". Journal of Economic Geography. 3 (3): 229–240. doi:10.1093/jeg/3.3.229. JSTOR   26160482.
  5. Ottaviano, Gianmarco; Tabuchi, Takatoshi; Thisse, Jacques-François (2002). "Agglomeration and Trade Revisited". International Economic Review. 43 (2): 409–435. doi:10.1111/1468-2354.t01-1-00021. hdl:10419/155014. JSTOR   826994. S2CID   14829078.
  6. Ottaviano, Gianmarco; Thisse, Jacques-François (2004). "Chapter 58 Agglomeration and economic geography". Cities and Geography. Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics. Vol. 4. pp. 2563–2608. doi:10.1016/S1574-0080(04)80015-4. ISBN   9780444509673. S2CID   153604628.
  7. Martin, Philippe; Ottaviano, Gianmarco I. P. (2001). "Growth and Agglomeration". International Economic Review. 42 (4): 947–968. doi:10.1111/1468-2354.00141.
  8. Martin, Philippe; i.p. Ottaviano, Gianmarco (1999). "Growing locations: Industry location in a model of endogenous growth". European Economic Review. 43 (2): 281–302. doi:10.1016/S0014-2921(98)00031-2. S2CID   54174345.
  9. Baldwin, Richard E.; Martin, Philippe; Ottaviano, Gianmarco I. P. (2001). "Global Income Divergence, Trade, and Industrialization: The Geography of Growth Take-Offs". Journal of Economic Growth. 6 (1): 5–37. doi:10.1023/A:1009876310544. S2CID   195302947.
  10. Melitz, Marc J.; Ottaviano, Giancarlo I. P. (2008). "Market Size, Trade, and Productivity". The Review of Economic Studies. 75 (1): 295–316. doi:10.1111/j.1467-937X.2007.00463.x. JSTOR   4626196. S2CID   6797333.
  11. Mayer, Thierry; Melitz, Marc J.; Ottaviano, Gianmarco I. P. (2014). "Market Size, Competition, and the Product Mix of Exporters". American Economic Review. 104 (2): 495–536. doi:10.1257/aer.104.2.495. S2CID   2696937.
  12. Mayer, Thierry; Ottaviano, Gianmarco I. P. (2008). "The Happy Few: The Internationalisation of European Firms". Intereconomics. 43 (3): 135–148. doi:10.1007/s10272-008-0247-x. S2CID   154403749.
  13. Ottaviano, Gianmarco I.P.; Peri, Giovanni (2005). "Cities and cultures". Journal of Urban Economics. 58 (2): 304–337. doi:10.1016/j.jue.2005.06.004.
  14. Ottaviano, Gianmarco I.P.; Peri, Giovanni (2006). "The economic value of cultural diversity: Evidence from US cities". Journal of Economic Geography. 6: 9–44. doi: 10.1093/jeg/lbi002 .
  15. Ottaviano, Gianmarco I.P.; Peri, Giovanni (2005). "Rethinking the Gains from Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the U.S." Working Paper Series. doi:10.3386/w11672.{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  16. Ottaviano, Gianmarco I.P.; Peri, Giovanni (2008). "Immigration and National Wages: Clarifying the Theory and the Empirics". Working Paper Series. doi:10.3386/w14188.{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  17. Ottaviano, Gianmarco I. P.; Peri, Giovanni (2012). "Rethinking the Effect of Immigration on Wages". Journal of the European Economic Association. 10: 152–197. doi:10.1111/j.1542-4774.2011.01052.x. S2CID   154634966.
  18. Ottaviano, Gianmarco I. P.; Peri, Giovanni; Wright, Greg C. (2013). "Immigration, Offshoring, and American Jobs". The American Economic Review. 103 (5): 1925–1959. doi:10.1257/aer.103.5.1925. JSTOR   42920634.
  19. d'Amuri, Francesco; Ottaviano, Gianmarco I.P.; Peri, Giovanni (2010). "The labor market impact of immigration in Western Germany in the 1990s". European Economic Review. 54 (4): 550–570. doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2009.10.002.

Bibliography (selected)