Shelly Lundberg

Last updated

Shelly J. Lundberg is an economist and currently holds the positions of Leonard Broom Professor of Demography at the University of California, Santa Barbara, where she serves as Associate Director of the Broom Center for Demography. [1] Lundberg is one of the world's leading population economists. [2]

Contents

Biography

Shelly Lundberg earned a B.A. from the University of British Columbia in 1975 and a Ph.D. from Northwestern University in 1981, writing her thesis on the relationship between unemployment and household labour supply. After her graduation, Lundberg became an assistant professor of economics at the University of Pennsylvania (1980–84) before moving on to the University of Washington. There, she was promoted first to associate professor of economics (1989–94), then to full professor (1994-2004) and finally was made Castor Professor of Economics in 2004. [3] While at the University of Washington, Lundberg directed the Center for Research on Families (2001–11) as well as the Center for Studies in Demography and Ecology. Since 2011, she has been the Leonard Broom Professor of Demography at the University of California, Santa Barbara (UCSB), [4] where she serves as Associate Director of the Broom Center for Demography. In parallel, Lundberg has held visiting appointments at the Russell Sage Foundation and Princeton University. She has been a professor (II) of economics at the University of Bergen, [5]

Besides her academic positions, Lundberg is also affiliated with the IZA Institute of Labor Economics, [6] of which she is a research fellow, and the American Economic Association, wherein she chairs the Committee on the Status of Women in the Economics Profession. Her research has been honoured through the award of a national fellowship at the Hoover Institution (1982–83), a Fellowship in the Society of Labor Economists, whose President she was in 2012-13, and a Downing Fellowship. Moreover, Lundberg has served in the past as Chair of the Social Sciences and Population Studies of the National Institutes of Health, as vice-president of the Association of Population Centers, and as member of the Scientific Advisory Board of the German Institute for Economic Research (DIW). Finally, she also performs editorial duties for the Journal of Demographic Economics , IZA World of Labor , and the Review of Economics of the Household , and has done so in the past for the American Economic Review , Journal of Population Economics , Demography , Labour Economics , and the Journal of Human Resources . [7]

Shelly Lundberg is married to economist Richard Startz, with whom she has two children. [8]

Research

Shelly Lundberg's research focuses on labour economics, inequality, and the economics of the family. [9] In her research, she has particularly frequently collaborated with Robert A. Pollak. According to IDEAS/RePEc, Lundberg belongs to the top 2% of economists in terms of her research.

Research on the labour economics of households

One area of Lundberg's research concerns the labour economics of households. In her seminal 1985 paper, Lundberg developed the concept of the added worker effect, which explains countercyclical increases in the labour supply of married women as responses to their husbands' cyclical unemployment.* [10] In further work, Lundberg finds that the labour supply of married couples remains separately determined as long as the couples don't have children of preschool age; thereafter, the working hours of families become highly correlated and display negative cross-earnings effects. [11] Together with Elaina Rose, Lundberg finds that the effects of parenthood on the earnings and hours worked of married men and women strongly vary on the continuity of the mother's attachment to the labour force and on the child's gender: if the wife's employment is interrupted, the fall in the hours worked and wages of the wife is partly offset by an increase in the labour supply and earnings of the husband, whereas in the opposite case fathers' hours worked decrease strongly; moreover, all else equal, fathers tend to increase their labour supply and wages substantially more in case of a son than if they have a daughter, [12] [13] a finding in line with further work by Lundberg on child gender bias. [14]

Research on intrahousehold bargaining

A second area of Shelly Lundberg's research addresses bargaining within married couples. In a seminal paper with Robert A. Pollak, Lundberg developed the "separate spheres" bargaining model, wherein spouses don't threaten each other with divorce but rather with the adoption of a non-cooperative separate spheres approach to the marriage, with important implications for marriage market and the distributional consequences of transfer policies. [15] [16] Relatedly, Lundberg and Pollak are critical of "common preferences" (unitary) models of households compared to household models that involve intra-household bargaining and emphasize spouses' relative control over resources. [17] In line with this view, Lundberg, Pollak and Terence Wales observe that the reallocation of child benefits to wives in the UK was associated with substantial increases in households' expenditures on women's and children's clothing. [18] Lundberg and Pollak have also challenged the notion that bargaining in marriages generally results in efficiency, arguing that inefficient outcomes may occur if current decisions can be expected to affect future bargaining power. [19] Together with Startz and Steven Stillman, Lundberg has also studied the sudden drop in consumption associated with the retirement of male household heads, which she explains through the shift in control over household income due to retirement and wives' preference to save more because of their relatively higher life expectancies. [20]

Research on the economics of teenage pregnancies

A third area of Lundberg's research deals with the economics of premarital adolescent fertility. In research with Robert Plotnick, Lundberg observes important differences between the responsiveness of Caucasian and Afro-American adolescents' premarital pregnancies, pregnancy outcomes and prenatal marriages to welfare benefits, abortion laws and family planning policies, with Afro-Americans' behaviour being essentially unaffected by these policy variables. [21] The importance of racial differences in the effects of teenage pregnancies is also reflected by Lundberg and Plotnick's finding (together with Daniel Klepinger) that having a child before age 18 significantly reduces educational attainment only among Afro-Americans, though significant negative effects can also be observed for Caucasians and Hispanics with regard to childbearing before the age of 20. [22] By reducing young women's educational attainment, teenage childbearing also is found by Lundberg, Klepinger and Plotnick to significantly depress young women's wages, offering a further rationale for public policies aimed at reducing teenage pregnancies. [23]

Other research in labour economics, population economics and family economics

In early work with Startz, Lundberg developed an influential model of statistical discrimination in competitive labour markets wherein social welfare could be maximized by policies prohibiting group-specific discrimination. [24] Together with Rose, Lundberg finds that sons tend to accelerate the transition of women into marriage if the husband is also the son's biological father, though child gender doesn't affect mothers' remarriage probabilities when the children are born within a previous marriage. [25]

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Labour economics</span> Study of the markets for wage labour

Labour economics, or labor economics, seeks to understand the functioning and dynamics of the markets for wage labour. Labour is a commodity that is supplied by labourers, usually in exchange for a wage paid by demanding firms. Because these labourers exist as parts of a social, institutional, or political system, labour economics must also account for social, cultural and political variables.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Gary Becker</span> American economist (1930–2014)

Gary Stanley Becker was an American economist who received the 1992 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. He was a professor of economics and sociology at the University of Chicago, and was a leader of the third generation of the Chicago school of economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Feminist economics</span> Gender-aware branch of economics

Feminist economics is the critical study of economics and economies, with a focus on gender-aware and inclusive economic inquiry and policy analysis. Feminist economic researchers include academics, activists, policy theorists, and practitioners. Much feminist economic research focuses on topics that have been neglected in the field, such as care work, intimate partner violence, or on economic theories which could be improved through better incorporation of gendered effects and interactions, such as between paid and unpaid sectors of economies. Other feminist scholars have engaged in new forms of data collection and measurement such as the Gender Empowerment Measure (GEM), and more gender-aware theories such as the capabilities approach. Feminist economics is oriented towards the goal of "enhancing the well-being of children, women, and men in local, national, and transnational communities."

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Labour supply</span>

In mainstream economic theories, the labour supply is the total hours that workers wish to work at a given real wage rate. It is frequently represented graphically by a labour supply curve, which shows hypothetical wage rates plotted vertically and the amount of labour that an individual or group of individuals is willing to supply at that wage rate plotted horizontally. There are three distinct aspects to labor supply or expected hours of work: the fraction of the population who are employed, the average number of hours worked by those that are employed, and the average number of hours worked in the population as a whole.

In economics, distribution is the way total output, income, or wealth is distributed among individuals or among the factors of production. In general theory and in for example the U.S. National Income and Product Accounts, each unit of output corresponds to a unit of income. One use of national accounts is for classifying factor incomes and measuring their respective shares, as in national Income. But, where focus is on income of persons or households, adjustments to the national accounts or other data sources are frequently used. Here, interest is often on the fraction of income going to the top x percent of households, the next x percent, and so forth, and on the factors that might affect them.

Family economics applies economic concepts such as production, division of labor, distribution, and decision making to the family. It is used to explain outcomes unique to family—such as marriage, the decision to have children, fertility, polygamy, time devoted to domestic production, and dowry payments using economic analysis.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Étienne Wasmer</span> French professor and economist (born 1970)

Étienne Wasmer is a French professor and economist currently holding a Professorship at New York University in Abu Dhabi. Wasmer mainly focuses on the fields of labor economics, job search theory, discrimination and human capital. He teaches microeconomics and labor economics.

Household economics analyses all the decisions made by a household. These analyses are both at the microeconomic and macroeconomic level. This field analyses the structures of households, the behavior of family members, and their broader influence on society, including: decision making, division of labour within the household, allocation of time to household production, marriage, divorce, fertility, investment in children, and resource allocation. Malthus and Adam Smith studied the economics of the family in part by looking at the relationship between family size and living wage.

Intra-household bargaining refers to negotiations that occur between members of a household in order to arrive at decisions regarding the household unit, like whether to spend or save, whether to study or work.

Shoshana Grossbard is an economist and professor of economics emerita at San Diego State University. She is also a member of the Family Inequality Network, HCEO, University of Chicago and a research fellow at the Institute for the Study of Labor and the CESifo Institute. She is a well-published scholar as well as a founder of two organizations related to household economics: a journal, the Review of Economics of the Household founded in 2001 and the Society of Economics of the Household. The Society (SEHO) holds annual meetings since 2017.

Alan Manning is a British economist and professor of economics at the London School of Economics.

Joseph Gerard Altonji is an American labour economist and the Thomas DeWitt Cuyler Professor of Economics at Yale University. His fields of interest include macroeconomics and applied econometrics and in particular labour economics, being ranked as one of the foremost labour economists worldwide. In 2018, his contributions to the analysis of labour supply, family economics and discrimination were rewarded with the IZA Prize in Labor Economics.

Thomas Lemieux is a Canadian economist and professor at the University of British Columbia.

Garance Genicot is a Belgian-American economist and associate professor of economics at Georgetown University. She is a member of the Core Group at Theoretical Research in Development Economics (ThReD), a research associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Development Economics Program, a research associate at the Center for Economic and Policy Research (CPER) in both the Political Economy Program and in the Development Economics Program, a Fellow at the Bureau for Research and Economic Analysis of Development (BREAD) and a research fellow at the IZA Institute. From 2013 to 2018, she served as an External Member of the World Bank Research Management Committee. A more detailed overview of her work can be found on RePEc., Research Papers in Economics.

Erica Marie Field is an economist who currently works as Professor of Economics and Global Health at Duke University. Her research interests include development economics, labour economics, and health economics. In 2010, her research was awarded the Elaine Bennett Research Prize.

Ragui A. Assaad is an Egyptian economist and Professor of Planning and Public Affairs at the Humphrey School of Public Affairs. His research interests include labour economics, inequality and the economics of education. He ranks among the most prominent economists of Egypt.

Jere Richard Behrman is an American economist and the William R. Kenan Jr. Professor of Economics at the University of Pennsylvania. He belongs to the world's most prominent development and education economists and human capital scholars, with a strong focus on Central and South America.

Robert A. Pollak is an economist. Pollak has made contributions to the specification and estimation of consumer demand systems, social choice theory, the theory of the cost of living index, and since the early 1980s, to the economics of the family and to demography. He is currently the Hernreich Distinguished Professor of Economics at Washington University in St Louis, holding joint appointments in the Faculty of Arts & Sciences and in the Olin Business School.

Robert Allen Moffitt is an American economist; he is currently the Krieger-Eisenhower Professor of Economics at Johns Hopkins University. His areas of research include the economics of tax and transfer programs, especially welfare programs, the analysis of earnings instability in the labor market, the economics of the family, and applied microeconometrics.

Aysit Tansel is a Turkish economist and Professor of Economics at the Middle East Technical University in Ankara. Her research revolves mainly around labour economics, with a focus on the economics of education. She ranks among the foremost Turkish economists in terms of research output.

References

  1. Profile of Shelly Lundberg at UCSB. Retrieved March 28th, 2018.
  2. Shelly Lundberg ranks 4th among 667 population economists registered on IDEAS/RePEc. Retrieved March 28th, 2018.
  3. Profile of Shelly Lundberg as Professor Emeritus at the University of Washington. Retrieved March 28th, 2018.
  4. Webpage of Shelly Lundberg on the website of the University of California, Santa Barbara. Retrieved March 28th, 2018.
  5. Vitenskapelig ansatte ved Institutt for økonomi, University of Bergen. Archived February 23rd, 2013.]
  6. Profile of Shelly Lundberg on the website of the IZA Institute of Labor Economics. Retrieved March 28th, 2018.
  7. Curriculum vitae of Shelly Lundberg (status: June 2017). Retrieved March 28th, 2018.
  8. Szuchman, P. (January 7th, 2011). Economists in Love: Shelly Lundberg & Dick Startz. Its The Dishes. Retrieved March 28th, 2018.
  9. Profile of Shelly Lundberg at UCSB. Retrieved March 28th, 2018.
  10. Lundberg, S. (1985). The Added Worker Effect. Journal of Labor Economics, 3(1), pp. 11-37.
  11. Lundberg, S.J. (1988). Labor Supply of Husbands and Wives: A Simultaneous Equations Approach. Review of Economics and Statistics, 70(2), pp. 224-235.
  12. Lundberg, S., Rose, E. (2000). Parenthood and the earnings of married men and women. Labour Economics, 7(6), pp. 689-710.
  13. Lundberg, S., Rose, E. (2002). The Effects of Sons and Daughters on Men's Labor Supply and Wages. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), pp. 251-268.
  14. Lundberg, S. (2005). Sons, Daughters, and Parental Behaviour. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 21(3), pp. 340-356.
  15. Lundberg, S., Pollak, R.A. (1991). Separate Spheres Bargaining and the Marriage Market. Journal of Political Economy, 101(6), pp. 988-1010.
  16. Lundberg, S., Pollak, R.A. (1994). Noncooperative Bargaining Models of Marriage. American Economic Review, 84(2), pp. 132-137.
  17. Lundberg, S., Pollak, R.A. (1996). Bargaining and Distribution in Marriage. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(4), pp. 139-158.
  18. Lundberg, S.J., Pollak, R.A., Wales, T.J. (1997). Do Husbands and Wives Pool Their Resources? Evidence from the United Kingdom Child Benefit. Journal of Human Resources, 32(3), pp. 463-480.
  19. Lundberg, S., Pollak, R. (2003). Efficiency in Marriage. Review of Economics of the Household, 1(3), pp. 153-167.
  20. Lundberg, S., Startz, R., Stillman, S. (2003). The retirement-consumption puzzle: a marital bargaining approach. Journal of Public Economics, 87(5-6), pp. 1199-1218.
  21. Lundberg, S., Plotnick, R.D. (1995). Adolescent Premarital Childbearing: Do Economic Incentives Matter? Journal of Labor Economics, 13(2), pp. 177-200.
  22. Klepinger, D., Lundberg, S., Plotnick, R. (1999). How Does Adolescent Fertility Affect the Human Capital and Wages of Young Women? Journal of Human Resources, 34(3), pp. 421-448.
  23. Klepinger, D.H., Lundberg, S., Plotnick, R.D. (1995). Adolescent fertility and the educational attainment of young women. Family Planning Perspectives, 27(1), pp. 23-28.
  24. Lundberg, S., Startz, R. (1983). Private Discrimination and Social Intervention in Competitive Labor Markets. American Economic Review, 73(3), pp. 340-347.
  25. Lundberg, S., Rose, E. (2003). Child gender and the transition to marriage. Demography, 40(2), pp. 333-349.