The Failure of the New Economics

Last updated
The Failure of the New Economics
TheFailureOfTheNewEconomics.jpg
First edition
Author Henry Hazlitt
CountryUnited States
LanguageEnglish
Subject Economics
PublisherVan Nostrand
Publication date
1959
Pages458 pp.
OCLC 264550952

The Failure of the "New Economics" subtitled An Analysis of The Keynesian Fallacies, (1959) is a book by Henry Hazlitt offering a detailed critique of John Maynard Keynes' work The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (1936).

Contents

Overview

Hazlitt's critical analysis of The General Theory Hazlitt embarked on this project because, in his view, although general critiques of Keynes and The General Theory had been made, no critic had completed a detailed analysis of the work. [1]

Reception

The Failure of the "New Economics" sold well but did not have a large impact on the general public or academia. [2] Economic professor Louis Hacker, writing in The New York Times , called Hazlitt's efforts to debunk Keynes a "heroic and perhaps even a Sisyphean task...Mr. Hazlitt, for his part, has written a technical book which is not obscure—although it is difficult reading" and predicted that Hazlitt will be attacked for his book. Hacker ended his review by stating: "Mr. Hazlitt nails his colors to the mast...If, here and there, he exaggerates and claims too much, his polemics are all to the good. He has written a very important book." [3] In 1959, the New York Times Book Review included The Failure of the "New Economics" in its list of "250 Outstanding Books Published in the Past Year." [4]

Austrian economist Ludwig von Mises called it "a devastating criticism of the Keynesian doctrines." [5] Gene Epstein referred to it as a "fantastic read, a lucid, lively, obsessive dissection of the most influential and most overrated economics book of this century: The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money...A must-read for economists and laymen alike." [6] A review in the New York University Law Review stated: "Henry Hazlitt has shown the work of John Maynard Keynes to be irresponsible, obscurantist, and often simply silly...No one who reads The Failure of the "New Economics" can henceforward take seriously the doctrines associated with the name of Keynes." [7]

A review in the Labor Law Journal noted that The Failure of the "New Economics" "subjects Keynes's celebrated work to a penetrating critical analysis, chapter by-chapter and theorem-by-theorem." [8] A review in Challenge stated: "It is, of course, true that Keynes' ideas have been accepted too uncritically by many economists, and Hazlitt's well-written book should go far toward dispelling such unquestioning acceptance" but that Hazlitt failed to recognize that allowing depressions to "'grind themselves out' in the 'long run' will no longer be tolerated." [9] A review in the Italian journal Giornale degli Economisti e Annali di Economia hoped new opinions like the ones expressed in The Failure of the "New Economics" will help change traditional economic theories promulgated by universities. [10] The Journal of Demographic Economics (originally named the Louvain Economic Review in English) called The Failure of the "New Economics" an "important work...The author analyzes in detail different chapters of the General Theory and highlights the major weaknesses of the ideas that are developed there. This study leads...to a condemnation of Keynesian principles of economic policy." [11]

Keynesian economist Kenneth K. Kurihara wrote that The Failure of the "New Economics" "reflected the critical and hostile attitude of American business circles toward Keynesian analysis and policy." [12]

A review in the Economic Record was critical of Hazlitt's comprehension of demand curves, elasticities, and multipliers and wrote: "[Hazlitt] flattered himself that he could turn mathematical purblindness into a virtue...It is a pity, because the author certainly writes in a vigorous, somewhat sardonic, style of his own...the author is apt to light his rockets at the wrong end. Thus the audience, instead of being treated to some really illuminating fireworks, is merely smothered by stifling clouds of acrid dust." [13]

Reviewer Joseph McKenna, writing in the American Economic Review , commented that while the General Theory is "far from perfect" Hazlitt "does little to improve matters." McKenna stated that Hazlitt failed to clear up the ambiguities in definitions from the General Theory and ignores the fact that the General Theory applies only in conditions of unemployment. Furthermore, McKenna criticizes Hazlitt's positions on mathematical formulas, aggregation, and depressions and writes: "Although Hazlitt clears up many minor points in the General Theory, his analysis of the major ones is completely unsatisfactory." [14]

Post-Keynesian economist Abba P. Lerner criticized Hazlitt for his assumption of a world with full employment where wages rates are permitted to fall during a depression. Lerner also criticized Hazlitt for "missing some of the basic elements of the Keynesian analysis" such as failing to distinguish between thrift and savings and his interpretation of Say's law. [15]

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Keynesian economics</span> Group of macroeconomic theories

Keynesian economics are the various macroeconomic theories and models of how aggregate demand strongly influences economic output and inflation. In the Keynesian view, aggregate demand does not necessarily equal the productive capacity of the economy. Instead, it is influenced by a host of factors – sometimes behaving erratically – affecting production, employment, and inflation.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">John Maynard Keynes</span> English economist (1883–1946)

John Maynard Keynes, 1st Baron Keynes was an English economist and philosopher whose ideas fundamentally changed the theory and practice of macroeconomics and the economic policies of governments. Originally trained in mathematics, he built on and greatly refined earlier work on the causes of business cycles. One of the most influential economists of the 20th century, he produced writings that are the basis for the school of thought known as Keynesian economics, and its various offshoots. His ideas, reformulated as New Keynesianism, are fundamental to mainstream macroeconomics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Post-Keynesian economics</span> School of economic thought

Post-Keynesian economics is a school of economic thought with its origins in The General Theory of John Maynard Keynes, with subsequent development influenced to a large degree by Michał Kalecki, Joan Robinson, Nicholas Kaldor, Sidney Weintraub, Paul Davidson, Piero Sraffa and Jan Kregel. Historian Robert Skidelsky argues that the post-Keynesian school has remained closest to the spirit of Keynes' original work. It is a heterodox approach to economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">John Hicks</span> British economist (1904–1989)

Sir John Richards Hicks was a British economist. He is considered one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. The most familiar of his many contributions in the field of economics were his statement of consumer demand theory in microeconomics, and the IS–LM model (1937), which summarised a Keynesian view of macroeconomics. His book Value and Capital (1939) significantly extended general-equilibrium and value theory. The compensated demand function is named the Hicksian demand function in memory of him.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Henry Hazlitt</span> American journalist & writer (1894–1993)

Henry Stuart Hazlitt was an American journalist who wrote about business and economics for such publications as The Wall Street Journal, The Nation, The American Mercury, Newsweek, and The New York Times.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Paul Samuelson</span> American economist (1915–2009)

Paul Anthony Samuelson was an American economist who was the first American to win the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. When awarding the prize in 1970, the Swedish Royal Academies stated that he "has done more than any other contemporary economist to raise the level of scientific analysis in economic theory". Economic historian Randall E. Parker has called him the "Father of Modern Economics", and The New York Times considers him to be the "foremost academic economist of the 20th century".

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Stockholm School (economics)</span> School of economic thought (1930s)

The Stockholm School is a school of economic thought. It refers to a loosely organized group of Swedish economists that worked together, in Stockholm, Sweden primarily in the 1930s.

<i>The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money</i> 1936 book by John Maynard Keynes

The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money is a book by English economist John Maynard Keynes published in February 1936. It caused a profound shift in economic thought, giving macroeconomics a central place in economic theory and contributing much of its terminology – the "Keynesian Revolution". It had equally powerful consequences in economic policy, being interpreted as providing theoretical support for government spending in general, and for budgetary deficits, monetary intervention and counter-cyclical policies in particular. It is pervaded with an air of mistrust for the rationality of free-market decision making.

<i>Economics in One Lesson</i> Book by Henry Hazlitt

Economics in One Lesson is an introduction to economics written by Henry Hazlitt and first published in 1946. It is based on Frédéric Bastiat's essay Ce qu'on voit et ce qu'on ne voit pas.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Underconsumption</span>

Underconsumption is a theory in economics that recessions and stagnation arise from an inadequate consumer demand, relative to the amount produced. In other words, there is a problem of overproduction and overinvestment during a demand crisis. The theory formed the basis for the development of Keynesian economics and the theory of aggregate demand after the 1930s.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Abba P. Lerner</span> Russian-British economist (1903–1982)

Abraham "Abba" Ptachya Lerner was a Russian-born American-British economist.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Alvin Hansen</span> American economist

Alvin Harvey Hansen was an American economist who taught at the University of Minnesota and was later a chair professor of economics at Harvard University. Often referred to as "the American Keynes", he was a widely read popular author on economic issues, and an influential advisor to the government on economic policy. Hansen helped create the Council of Economic Advisors and the Social Security system. He is best remembered today for introducing Keynesian economics in the United States in the 1930s and 40s.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Permanent income hypothesis</span> Economic model explaining consumption pattern formation

The permanent income hypothesis (PIH) is a model in the field of economics to explain the formation of consumption patterns. It suggests consumption patterns are formed from future expectations and consumption smoothing. The theory was developed by Milton Friedman and published in his A Theory of Consumption Function, published in 1957 and subsequently formalized by Robert Hall in a rational expectations model. Originally applied to consumption and income, the process of future expectations is thought to influence other phenomena. In its simplest form, the hypothesis states changes in permanent income, rather than changes in temporary income, are what drive changes in consumption.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Neoclassical synthesis</span> Postwar academic movement in economics

The neoclassical synthesis (NCS), neoclassical–Keynesian synthesis, or just neo-Keynesianism was a neoclassical economics academic movement and paradigm in economics that worked towards reconciling the macroeconomic thought of John Maynard Keynes in his book The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (1936). It was formulated most notably by John Hicks (1937), Franco Modigliani (1944), and Paul Samuelson (1948), who dominated economics in the post-war period and formed the mainstream of macroeconomic thought in the 1950s, 60s, and 70s.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Paul Davidson (economist)</span> American macroeconomist (born 1930)

Paul Davidson is an American macroeconomist who has been one of the leading spokesmen of the American branch of the post-Keynesian school in economics. He is a prolific writer and has actively intervened in important debates on economic policy from a position critical of mainstream economics.

Axel Leijonhufvud was a Swedish economist and professor emeritus at the University of California, Los Angeles (UCLA), and professor at the University of Trento, Italy. Leijonhufvud focused his studies on macroeconomic monetary theory. In his defining book On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes (1968) he focuses on a critique of the interpretation of Keynesian economic theory by Keynesian economists. He goes on to call the standard neoclassical synthesis interpretation of the Keynes' General Theory as having misunderstood and misinterpreted Keynes. In one of his papers, "Life Among the Econ" (1973), he takes a comical yet critical look at the inherent clannish nature of economists; the paper was considered a devastating takedown of economics and economists.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Keynesian Revolution</span> Economic theory

The Keynesian Revolution was a fundamental reworking of economic theory concerning the factors determining employment levels in the overall economy. The revolution was set against the then orthodox economic framework, namely neoclassical economics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">History of macroeconomic thought</span>

Macroeconomic theory has its origins in the study of business cycles and monetary theory. In general, early theorists believed monetary factors could not affect real factors such as real output. John Maynard Keynes attacked some of these "classical" theories and produced a general theory that described the whole economy in terms of aggregates rather than individual, microeconomic parts. Attempting to explain unemployment and recessions, he noticed the tendency for people and businesses to hoard cash and avoid investment during a recession. He argued that this invalidated the assumptions of classical economists who thought that markets always clear, leaving no surplus of goods and no willing labor left idle.

<i>Where Keynes Went Wrong</i>

Where Keynes Went Wrong: And Why World Governments Keep Creating Inflation, Bubbles, and Busts is a non-fiction work by Hunter Lewis. It was first published in 2009.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Mabel F. Timlin</span> Canadian economist

Mabel Timlin was a Canadian economist who in 1950, became the first tenured woman economics professor at a Canadian university. Timlin was a pioneer in the field of economics and is best known for her work and interpretation of Keynesian theory, as well as Canadian immigration policy and post WWII monetary stabilization policy. In addition to her successful research career, Timlin was the first woman to serve as vice president and president of the Canadian Political Science Association. She was also one of the first women and one of the very few Canadian economists to serve on the Executive Committee of the American Economic Association.

References

  1. The Failure of the "New Economics", pp 4-9
  2. Claar, Victor V.; Forster, Greg (April 2019). The Keynesian Revolution and Our Empty Economy : We're All Dead. Springer Publishing. pp. 183–184. ISBN   978-3-030-15808-8. OCLC   1091895856.
  3. Hacker, Louis M. (June 28, 1959). "John Maynard Keynes: He Casts a Long Shadow, but Was He Right?". New York Times . ProQuest   114668166 . Retrieved August 16, 2021 via ProQuest.
  4. "250 Outstanding Books Published in the Past Year...A Christmas Guide". New York Times . November 29, 1959. ProQuest   114859995 . Retrieved August 16, 2021 via ProQuest.
  5. A Man for Many Seasons, The Freeman Archived 2010-12-09 at the Wayback Machine
  6. Epstein, Gene (September 27, 1999). "The Broken-Window Fallacy Strikes Again". Barrons . Retrieved 2021-08-16.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: url-status (link)
  7. Petro, Sylvester (March 1960). "Book Reviews". New York University Law Review . 35: 862–864. ISSN   0028-7881. OCLC   46988231 via HeinOnline.
  8. Stewart, Henry, ed. (November 1960). "The Free Market". Labor Law Journal . Wolters Kluwer. 11: 1048–1049 via HeinOnline.
  9. "Reading Report". Challenge . Routledge. 7 (10): 70. 1959-07-01. doi:10.1080/05775132.1959.11468958. ISSN   0577-5132.
  10. D. (1959). "The economy, liberty and the State by C. B. Hoover; The failure of the " New Economics " by H. Hazlitt". Giornale degli Economisti e Annali di Economia (in Italian). 18 (11/12): 720–721. ISSN   0017-0097. JSTOR   23237505 via JSTOR.
  11. "H. Hazlitt, The Failure of the "New Economics". An Analysis of the Keynesian Fallacies". Recherches Économiques de Louvain (in French). Cambridge University Press. 26 (2): 133. March 1960. doi:10.1017/S1373971900070657. ISSN   1373-9719. S2CID   251330580.
  12. Kurihara, Kenneth K. (1963). "The Keynesian Impact On American Economic Thinking and Policy". The Centennial Review. Michigan State University Press. 7 (1): 65. ISSN   0162-0177. JSTOR   23737559 via JSTOR.
  13. Bernardelli, H. (April 1960). "Reviews". Economic Record . 36 (74): 279–300. doi:10.1111/j.1475-4932.1960.tb00518.x. ISSN   0013-0249 via Wiley Online Library.
  14. McKenna, Joseph P. "Review: The Failure of the New Economics." American Economic Review . Volume 50, No. 1. March 1960. pp. 188–190. JSTOR   1813478
  15. Lerner, Abba P. (1960). "Review of The Failure of the "New Economics"". The Review of Economics and Statistics . MIT Press. 42 (2): 234–235. doi:10.2307/1926551. ISSN   0034-6535. JSTOR   1926551 via JSTOR.