Natural economy

Last updated

Natural economy is a type of economy in which money is not used in the transfer of resources among people. It is a system of allocating resources through direct bartering, entitlement by law, or sharing out according to traditional custom. In the more complex forms of natural economy, some goods may act as a referent for fair bartering, but generally currency plays only a small role in allocating resources. As a corollary, the majority of goods produced in a system of natural economy are not produced for the purpose of exchanging them, but for direct consumption by the producers (subsistence). As such, natural economies tend to be self-contained, where all the goods consumed are produced domestically. [1]

The term has often been used in opposition to other forms of economy, most notably capitalism. [1] Rosa Luxemburg believed that the destruction of the natural economy was a necessary condition for the development of capitalism. [2] Karl Marx described the Inca Empire as a "natural economy"; it existed as an isolated society which was based on subsistence and barter without profitmaking, with some products functioning as commodity money. [3]

Other writers have used a more relative sense of natural economy. Belgian economic historian Henri Pirenne noted that medieval Europe has often been described as a natural economy despite the existence of money, since money played a much less significant role than in earlier or later periods. [4]

See also

References

  1. 1 2 Perrings, Charles (1985). "The Natural Economy Revisited". Economic Development and Cultural Change. 33 (4): 829–850. doi:10.1086/451497.
  2. Luxemburg, Rosa (1951). The Accumulation of Capital. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul. p.  369.
  3. Marx, Karl (1956). Capital, volume 2. Moscow: Progress Publishers. p. 119.; see also Louis Baudin, A socialist empire: the Incas of Peru (introd. Ludwig von Mises). Princeton: D. van Nostrand Company Inc., 1961, p. 172.
  4. Pirenne, Henri (1936). Economic and Social History of Medieval Europe. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul. pp. 103–104.