Price of anarchy in congestion games

Last updated

The Price of Anarchy (PoA) is a concept in game theory and mechanism design that measures how the social welfare of a system degrades due to selfish behavior of its agents. It has been studied extensively in various contexts, particularly in congestion games (CG).

Contents

Example

The inefficiency of congestion games was first illustrated by Pigou in 1920, [1] using the following simple congestion game. Suppose there are two roads that lead from point A to point B:

Suppose there are 1000 drivers who need to go from A to B. Each driver wants to minimize his own delay, but the government would like to minimize the total delay (the sum of delays of all drivers).

In this example, selfish routing leads to a total delay that is 4/3 times higher than the optimum, so the price of anarchy is 4/3. In general, the price of anarchy may differ based on the type of congestion game, the structure of the network, and the delay functions. Various authors have computed upper and lower bounds on the PoA in various congestion games.

Effect of delay functions

To illustrate the effect of the delay functions on PoA, consider a variant of the above example in which the delay in road 1 is still 1 minute, but the delay in road 2 when x drivers use it is , for some d>1.

Therefore, the price of anarchy approaches infinity as .

Definitions

A congestion game (CG) is defined by a set of resources. For example, in a road network, each road is an individual resource. For each

resource, there is a delay function (aka cost function). The function maps the amount of congestion in the resource (e.g. the number of drivers choosing to use the road) to the delay experienced by each player using it. The total cost of a player is the total delay in all the resources he chooses. Each player chooses a strategy in order to minimize his own cost.

A Nash equilibirum is a situation in which no player can improve his delay by unilaterally changing his choice. The price of anarchy(PoA) is the ratio between the largest delay in Nash equilibrium, and the smallest possible delay overall. The price of stability (PoS) is the ratio between the smallest delay in Nash equilibrium (that is: the best possible equilibrium), and the smallest possible delay overall. The PoA and PoS can also be computed with respect to other equilibrium concepts, such as mixed equilibrium or correlated equilibrium.

There are several main classes of congestion games:

Another classification of CGs is based on the sets of strategies available to the players:

Moreover:

Atomic congestion games

Christodoulou and Koutsoupias [2] analyzed atomic unweighted CGs. They proved that the PoA when all delay functions are linear is exactly 2.5 (that is: the PoA is always at most 2.5, and in some cases it is exactly 2.5). They also gave upper and lower bounds for PoA when the delay functions are polynomials of bounded degree. In another paper, Christodoulou and Koutsoupias [3] analyzed the PoS of atomic unweighted congestion games with linear delay functions. They proved that the PoS is at most 1.6, and showed an example in which the PoS is 1.577. They also showed that the PoA of correlated equilibria in this case is exactly 2.5 for unweighted games and exactly 2.618 for weighed games.

Awerbuch, Azar and Epstein [4] analyzed analyzed atomic weighted CGs. They proved that the PoA when all delay functions are linear is exactly 2.618. They also showed that, when the delay functions are polynomials of degree d, the PoA is in .

Aland, Dumrauf, Gairing, Monien and Schoppmann [5] computed the exact PoA for atomic CGs, for delay functions that are polynomials of degree at most d:

The same bounds hold whenever no player can improve his expected cost by a unilateral deviation. Therefore, the worst-case PoA are the same with respect to pure Nash equilibrium, mixed Nash equilibrium, correlated equilibrium and coarse-correlated equilibrium. Moreover, the bounds hold for unweighted and weighted network congestion games.

Bhawalkar, Gairing and Roughgarden [6] analyze weighed CGs, and show how to compute the PoA for any class of cost functions (not necessarily polynomial). They also show that, under mild conditions on the allowable delay functions, the PoA with respect to pure Nash equilibria, mixed Nash equilibria, correlated equilibria and coarse correlated equilibria are always equal. They also show that, with polynomial cost functions, the worst-case PoA is attained on a simple network, consisting only of a set of parallel edges. They also show that the PoA of symmetric unweighted congestion games is always equal to the asymmetric ones.

Further results

De-Jong and Uetz [7] study sequential CGs, in which players pick their strategies sequentially rather than simultaneously. They analyze the PoA of subgame perfect equilibrium. They show that the sequential PoA with affine cost functions is exactly 1.5 for two players and ≈2.13 for three players, and at least 2.46 for four players. For singleton congestion games with affine cost functions, when there are n players, the sequential PoA is at most n-1; when , the sequential PoA is at least 2+1/e ≈ 2.37. For symmetric singleton atomic congestion games with affine cost functions, the sequential PoA is exactly 4/3.

Fotakis [8] studies the PoA of CGs with linearly-independent paths, which is an extension of the setting of parallel links.

Law, Huang and Liu [9] study the PoA of CGs in cognitive radio networks.

Gairing, Burkhard and Karsten [10] study the PoA of CGs with player-specific linear delay functions.

Mlichtaich [11] analyzes the effect of network topology on the efficiency of PNE in atomic CGs:

PoA of nonatomic congestion games

Roughgarden and Tardos [12] analyzed nonatomic CGs. They showed that, when the delay functions are polynomials of degree at most d, the PoA is in , which is substantially smaller than the PoA of atomic games. In particular, when d=1, the PoA is 4/3; this shows that Pigou's simple example is the worst case for linear delay functions.

Chau and Sim [13] extend the results of Roughgarden and Tardos by (1) considering symmetric cost maps and (2) incorporating elastic demands.

Correa, Schulz and Stier-Moses [14] present a short, geometric proof to the results on PoA for nonatomic CGs. They also give stronger bounds on the PoA when equilibrium costs are within reasonable limits of the fixed costs.

Blum, Even-Dar and Ligett [15] showed that all these PoA bounds apply under relatively weak behavioral assumptions: it is sufficient that all users achieve vanishing average regret over repeated plays of the game.

A useful concept in the analysis of PoA is smoothness. A delay function d is called -smooth if for all , . If the delay is smooth, is a Nash equilibrium, and is an optimal allocation, then . In other words, the price of anarchy is . [16]

Mlichtaich [17] analyzed singleton nonatomic CGs, with the following additional characteristics:

In such games, the equilibrium payoffs are always unique and Pareto-efficient, but may not maximize the sum of utilities. Moreover:

PoA of splittable congestion games

Roughgarden and Schoppmann [18] analyzed splittable congestion games. They showed that, when the delay functions are polynomials of degree at most d, the PoA is in . In particular, when d=1, the PoA is at most 3/2. The PoA for splittable games is smaller than for atomic games, but larger than nonatomic games. For example:

PoA with altruistic players

The basic CG model assumes that players are selfish - they care only about their own payoff. In fact, players may be altruistic and care about the social cost too. This can be modeled by assuming that the actual cost of each player is a weighted average of his own delay and the total delay. Altruism may have surprising effects on the system efficiency:

There are other papers studying the effect of altruism on the PoA. [21] [22] An alternative way to measure the effect of altruism on efficiency is via comparative statics: in a single game (not necessarily worst-case one), how does increasing the altruism coefficient affect the social cost? [23] [24] For some classes of CGs, the effect of altruism on efficiency may be negative. [25]

See also

Related Research Articles

In game theory, the best response is the strategy which produces the most favorable outcome for a player, taking other players' strategies as given. The concept of a best response is central to John Nash's best-known contribution, the Nash equilibrium, the point at which each player in a game has selected the best response to the other players' strategies.

Braess's paradox is the observation that adding one or more roads to a road network can slow down overall traffic flow through it. The paradox was first discovered by Arthur Pigou in 1920, and later named after the German mathematician Dietrich Braess in 1968.

Route assignment, route choice, or traffic assignment concerns the selection of routes between origins and destinations in transportation networks. It is the fourth step in the conventional transportation forecasting model, following trip generation, trip distribution, and mode choice. The zonal interchange analysis of trip distribution provides origin-destination trip tables. Mode choice analysis tells which travelers will use which mode. To determine facility needs and costs and benefits, we need to know the number of travelers on each route and link of the network. We need to undertake traffic assignment. Suppose there is a network of highways and transit systems and a proposed addition. We first want to know the present pattern of traffic delay and then what would happen if the addition were made.

The Stackelberg leadership model is a strategic game in economics in which the leader firm moves first and then the follower firms move sequentially. It is named after the German economist Heinrich Freiherr von Stackelberg who published Marktform und Gleichgewicht [Market Structure and Equilibrium] in 1934, which described the model. In game theory terms, the players of this game are a leader and a follower and they compete on quantity. The Stackelberg leader is sometimes referred to as the Market Leader.

In transportation engineering, traffic flow is the study of interactions between travellers and infrastructure, with the aim of understanding and developing an optimal transport network with efficient movement of traffic and minimal traffic congestion problems.

In game theory, a correlated equilibrium is a solution concept that is more general than the well known Nash equilibrium. It was first discussed by mathematician Robert Aumann in 1974. The idea is that each player chooses their action according to their private observation of the value of the same public signal. A strategy assigns an action to every possible observation a player can make. If no player would want to deviate from their strategy, the distribution from which the signals are drawn is called a correlated equilibrium.

In computational complexity theory, Polynomial Local Search (PLS) is a complexity class that models the difficulty of finding a locally optimal solution to an optimization problem. The main characteristics of problems that lie in PLS are that the cost of a solution can be calculated in polynomial time and the neighborhood of a solution can be searched in polynomial time. Therefore it is possible to verify whether or not a solution is a local optimum in polynomial time. Furthermore, depending on the problem and the algorithm that is used for solving the problem, it might be faster to find a local optimum instead of a global optimum.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Double auction</span>

A double auction is a process of buying and selling goods with multiple sellers and multiple buyers. Potential buyers submit their bids and potential sellers submit their ask prices to the market institution, and then the market institution chooses some price p that clears the market: all the sellers who asked less than p sell and all buyers who bid more than p buy at this price p. Buyers and sellers that bid or ask for exactly p are also included. A common example of a double auction is stock exchange.

Competitive equilibrium is a concept of economic equilibrium, introduced by Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu in 1951, appropriate for the analysis of commodity markets with flexible prices and many traders, and serving as the benchmark of efficiency in economic analysis. It relies crucially on the assumption of a competitive environment where each trader decides upon a quantity that is so small compared to the total quantity traded in the market that their individual transactions have no influence on the prices. Competitive markets are an ideal standard by which other market structures are evaluated.

In game theory, a game is said to be a potential game if the incentive of all players to change their strategy can be expressed using a single global function called the potential function. The concept originated in a 1996 paper by Dov Monderer and Lloyd Shapley.

In game theory, an epsilon-equilibrium, or near-Nash equilibrium, is a strategy profile that approximately satisfies the condition of Nash equilibrium. In a Nash equilibrium, no player has an incentive to change his behavior. In an approximate Nash equilibrium, this requirement is weakened to allow the possibility that a player may have a small incentive to do something different. This may still be considered an adequate solution concept, assuming for example status quo bias. This solution concept may be preferred to Nash equilibrium due to being easier to compute, or alternatively due to the possibility that in games of more than 2 players, the probabilities involved in an exact Nash equilibrium need not be rational numbers.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">All-pay auction</span>

In economics and game theory, an all-pay auction is an auction in which every bidder must pay regardless of whether they win the prize, which is awarded to the highest bidder as in a conventional auction. As shown by Riley and Samuelson (1981), equilibrium bidding in an all pay auction with private information is revenue equivalent to bidding in a sealed high bid or open ascending price auction.

Algorithmic game theory (AGT) is an area in the intersection of game theory and computer science, with the objective of understanding and design of algorithms in strategic environments.

The Price of Anarchy (PoA) is a concept in economics and game theory that measures how the efficiency of a system degrades due to selfish behavior of its agents. It is a general notion that can be extended to diverse systems and notions of efficiency. For example, consider the system of transportation of a city and many agents trying to go from some initial location to a destination. Here, efficiency means the average time for an agent to reach the destination. In the 'centralized' solution, a central authority can tell each agent which path to take in order to minimize the average travel time. In the 'decentralized' version, each agent chooses its own path. The Price of Anarchy measures the ratio between average travel time in the two cases.

In game theory, the price of stability (PoS) of a game is the ratio between the best objective function value of one of its equilibria and that of an optimal outcome. The PoS is relevant for games in which there is some objective authority that can influence the players a bit, and maybe help them converge to a good Nash equilibrium. When measuring how efficient a Nash equilibrium is in a specific game we often also talk about the price of anarchy (PoA), which is the ratio between the worst objective function value of one of its equilibria and that of an optimal outcome.

Congestion games (CG) are a class of games in game theory. They represent situations which commonly occur in roads, communication networks, oligopoly markets and natural habitats. There is a set of resources ; there are several players who need resources ; each player chooses a subset of these resources ; the delay in each resource is determined by the number of players choosing a subset that contains this resource. The cost of each player is the sum of delays among all resources he chooses. Naturally, each player wants to minimize his own delay; however, each player's choices impose a negative externality on the other players, which may lead to inefficient outcomes.

In game theory, a job scheduling game is a game that models a scenario in which multiple selfish users wish to utilize multiple processing machines. Each user has a single job, and he needs to choose a single machine to process it. The incentive of each user is to have his job run as fast as possible.

In algorithmic game theory, a succinct game or a succinctly representable game is a game which may be represented in a size much smaller than its normal form representation. Without placing constraints on player utilities, describing a game of players, each facing strategies, requires listing utility values. Even trivial algorithms are capable of finding a Nash equilibrium in a time polynomial in the length of such a large input. A succinct game is of polynomial type if in a game represented by a string of length n the number of players, as well as the number of strategies of each player, is bounded by a polynomial in n.

Mean-field game theory is the study of strategic decision making by small interacting agents in very large populations. It lies at the intersection of game theory with stochastic analysis and control theory. The use of the term "mean field" is inspired by mean-field theory in physics, which considers the behavior of systems of large numbers of particles where individual particles have negligible impacts upon the system. In other words, each agent acts according to his minimization or maximization problem taking into account other agents’ decisions and because their population is large we can assume the number of agents goes to infinity and a representative agent exists.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Price of anarchy in auctions</span>

The Price of Anarchy (PoA) is a concept in game theory and mechanism design that measures how the social welfare of a system degrades due to selfish behavior of its agents. It has been studied extensively in various contexts, particularly in auctions.

References

  1. A., Pigou (1920). The Economics of Welfare.
  2. Christodoulou, George; Koutsoupias, Elias (2005-05-22). "The price of anarchy of finite congestion games". Proceedings of the thirty-seventh annual ACM symposium on Theory of computing. STOC '05. New York, NY, USA: Association for Computing Machinery. pp. 67–73. doi:10.1145/1060590.1060600. ISBN   978-1-58113-960-0. S2CID   2670556.
  3. Christodoulou, George; Koutsoupias, Elias (2005). "On the Price of Anarchy and Stability of Correlated Equilibria of Linear Congestion Games". In Brodal, Gerth Stølting; Leonardi, Stefano (eds.). Algorithms – ESA 2005. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. Vol. 3669. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer. pp. 59–70. doi:10.1007/11561071_8. ISBN   978-3-540-31951-1.
  4. Awerbuch, Baruch; Azar, Yossi; Epstein, Amir (2005-05-22). "The Price of Routing Unsplittable Flow". Proceedings of the thirty-seventh annual ACM symposium on Theory of computing. STOC '05. New York, NY, USA: Association for Computing Machinery. pp. 57–66. doi:10.1145/1060590.1060599. ISBN   978-1-58113-960-0. S2CID   379922.
  5. Aland, Sebastian; Dumrauf, Dominic; Gairing, Martin; Monien, Burkhard; Schoppmann, Florian (January 2011). "Exact Price of Anarchy for Polynomial Congestion Games". SIAM Journal on Computing. 40 (5): 1211–1233. doi:10.1137/090748986. ISSN   0097-5397.
  6. Bhawalkar, Kshipra; Gairing, Martin; Roughgarden, Tim (2014-10-28). "Weighted Congestion Games: The Price of Anarchy, Universal Worst-Case Examples, and Tightness". ACM Transactions on Economics and Computation. 2 (4): 14:1–14:23. doi:10.1145/2629666. ISSN   2167-8375. S2CID   2292866.
  7. de Jong, Jasper; Uetz, Marc (2014). "The Sequential Price of Anarchy for Atomic Congestion Games". In Liu, Tie-Yan; Qi, Qi; Ye, Yinyu (eds.). Web and Internet Economics. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. Vol. 8877. Cham: Springer International Publishing. pp. 429–434. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-13129-0_35. ISBN   978-3-319-13129-0.
  8. Fotakis, Dimitris (2010-07-01). "Congestion Games with Linearly Independent Paths: Convergence Time and Price of Anarchy". Theory of Computing Systems. 47 (1): 113–136. doi:10.1007/s00224-009-9205-7. ISSN   1433-0490. S2CID   1166496.
  9. Law, Lok Man; Huang, Jianwei; Liu, Mingyan (October 2012). "Price of Anarchy for Congestion Games in Cognitive Radio Networks". IEEE Transactions on Wireless Communications. 11 (10): 3778–3787. doi:10.1109/TWC.2012.083112.120371. ISSN   1558-2248. S2CID   11916283.
  10. Gairing, Martin; Monien, Burkhard; Tiemann, Karsten (2006). "Routing (Un-) Splittable Flow in Games with Player-Specific Linear Latency Functions". In Bugliesi, Michele; Preneel, Bart; Sassone, Vladimiro; Wegener, Ingo (eds.). Automata, Languages and Programming. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. Vol. 4051. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer. pp. 501–512. doi:10.1007/11786986_44. ISBN   978-3-540-35905-0.
  11. Milchtaich, Igal (2006-11-01). "Network topology and the efficiency of equilibrium". Games and Economic Behavior. 57 (2): 321–346. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2005.09.005. hdl: 10419/259308 . ISSN   0899-8256.
  12. Roughgarden, Tim; Tardos, Éva (2004-05-01). "Bounding the inefficiency of equilibria in nonatomic congestion games". Games and Economic Behavior. 47 (2): 389–403. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2003.06.004. ISSN   0899-8256. S2CID   10778635.
  13. Chau, Chi Kin; Sim, Kwang Mong (2003-09-01). "The price of anarchy for non-atomic congestion games with symmetric cost maps and elastic demands". Operations Research Letters. 31 (5): 327–334. doi:10.1016/S0167-6377(03)00030-0. ISSN   0167-6377.
  14. Correa, José R.; Schulz, Andreas S.; Stier-Moses, Nicolás E. (2008-11-01). "A geometric approach to the price of anarchy in nonatomic congestion games". Games and Economic Behavior. Special Issue in Honor of Michael B. Maschler. 64 (2): 457–469. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2008.01.001. ISSN   0899-8256. S2CID   1175580.
  15. Blum, Avrim; Even-Dar, Eyal; Ligett, Katrina (2006-07-23). "Routing without regret". Proceedings of the twenty-fifth annual ACM symposium on Principles of distributed computing. PODC '06. New York, NY, USA: Association for Computing Machinery. pp. 45–52. doi:10.1145/1146381.1146392. ISBN   978-1-59593-384-3. S2CID   2352710.
  16. Eva Tardos, Lecture notes: Price of Anarchy in nonatomic congestion games, Spring 2012.
  17. Milchtaich, Igal (2004-01-01). "Social optimality and cooperation in nonatomic congestion games". Journal of Economic Theory. 114 (1): 56–87. doi:10.1016/S0022-0531(03)00106-6. ISSN   0022-0531.
  18. Roughgarden, Tim; Schoppmann, Florian (2015-03-01). "Local smoothness and the price of anarchy in splittable congestion games". Journal of Economic Theory. Computer Science and Economic Theory. 156: 317–342. doi:10.1016/j.jet.2014.04.005. ISSN   0022-0531.
  19. Caragiannis, Ioannis; Kaklamanis, Christos; Kanellopoulos, Panagiotis; Kyropoulou, Maria; Papaioannou, Evi (2010). "The Impact of Altruism on the Efficiency of Atomic Congestion Games". In Wirsing, Martin; Hofmann, Martin; Rauschmayer, Axel (eds.). Trustworthly Global Computing. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. Vol. 6084. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer. pp. 172–188. doi:10.1007/978-3-642-15640-3_12. ISBN   978-3-642-15640-3.
  20. Chen, Po-An; Keijzer, Bart De; Kempe, David; Schäfer, Guido (2014-10-28). "Altruism and Its Impact on the Price of Anarchy". ACM Transactions on Economics and Computation. 2 (4): 17:1–17:45. doi:10.1145/2597893. ISSN   2167-8375. S2CID   9160585.
  21. Chen, Po-An; Kempe, David (2008-07-08). "Altruism, selfishness, and spite in traffic routing". Proceedings of the 9th ACM conference on Electronic commerce. EC '08. New York, NY, USA: Association for Computing Machinery. pp. 140–149. doi:10.1145/1386790.1386816. ISBN   978-1-60558-169-9. S2CID   6999363.
  22. Hoefer, Martin; Skopalik, Alexander (2013-12-01). "Altruism in Atomic Congestion Games". ACM Transactions on Economics and Computation. 1 (4): 21:1–21:21. arXiv: 0807.2011 . doi:10.1145/2542174.2542177. ISSN   2167-8375. S2CID   13835397.
  23. Milchtaich, Igal (2021-03-01). "Internalization of social cost in congestion games". Economic Theory. 71 (2): 717–760. doi:10.1007/s00199-020-01274-0. ISSN   1432-0479. S2CID   253723298.
  24. Milchtaich, Igal (2006-03-01). "Comparative statics of games between relatives". Theoretical Population Biology. 69 (2): 203–210. doi:10.1016/j.tpb.2005.08.002. ISSN   0040-5809. PMID   16194555.
  25. Milchtaich, Igal (2012-07-01). "Comparative statics of altruism and spite". Games and Economic Behavior. 75 (2): 809–831. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2012.02.015. ISSN   0899-8256.