Banco della Piazza di Rialto

Last updated

Rialto Square in Venice, where the bank operated San Polo, 30100 Venice, Italy - panoramio (140).jpg
Rialto Square in Venice, where the bank operated

The Banco della Piazza di Rialto, sometimes referred to as Banco di Rialto, was the first public bank of the Republic of Venice, operating on the eponymous Rialto Square. It was in activity from 1587 to 1637, when it succumbed to the competition from the Banco del Giro, a separate public institution that had been established in 1619.

Contents

The Banco della Piazza di Rialto was relatively short-lived, and was not the first public bank with features of an early central bank in Europe, a concept that was pioneered by the Taula de canvi de Barcelona in 1401 (even though proposals were made for such an entity in Venice in the 14th century). Even so, it had considerable influence in the development of European finance, and provided the direct model for the establishment of the Bank of Amsterdam in 1609. [1] :182 [2] :209

Background

An early proposal for a banco per Comune, a public municipal bank that would complement the operation of Venice's private banks, was made to the Venetian Senate by Senator Giovanni Dolfin in 1356. [3] A comparable proposal was made again in 1374 by a committee headed by Michele Morosini. [3] :43

These proposals were rejected, however, and the Venetian system kept relying on private bankers competing on Rialto Square. The number of such banks, however, decreased gradually, from eight to ten in the early 14C to a handful from the late 15C and eventually only one, the Pisani-Tiepolo house, in the third quarter of the 16th century. When that bank ran into distress in 1576, it was supported by the state through a loan from the city mint, but eventually succumbed to a run in 1584. After some debate, the Senate invited applications from private businessmen, but none was forthcoming.

Banco della Piazza di Rialto

On 11 April 1587, the Senate eventually decided to establish a public bank, the Banco della Piazza di Rialto, which however would be managed by a private banker on the state's payroll. After some back-and-forth, this scheme was replaced later in 1587 by a three-year public concession under which the concessionary had unlimited liability and was required to close all positions at the end of his term. [1] :42 The bank was required to keep its money fully convertible into coin. [1] :225 In 1593, a law granted legal tender status to deposits at the bank, and required citizens to settle all bills of exchange through it. [2] :210

At its peak, the bank had around four thousand depositors, with a balance sheet reaching close to a million ducats at the end of the 16th century. Such deposits were used actively as a dominant means of payment for commercial transactions. [2] :209 At its presumed peak in 1618, the total amount of deposits at the bank reached 1.7 million ducats. [4] :165

The bank was subject to banking supervision by the Provveditori sopra Banchi, specialized magistrates established earlier in the 16th century. [1] :124

From 1619 on, the Banco della Piazza di Rialto had to compete with the Banco del Giro, initially established as a temporary clearing mechanism. In January 1627, the Senate resolved to relocate the Banco di Rialto in the premises of the Banco Giro, as its activity had already shrunk markedly. [4] :166 By 1630, the Banco del Giro's monetary issuance was twice that of the Banco della Piazza di Rialto, whose business further declined in the 1630s. It ceased activity in 1637, and was formally closed by a decree of January 1638. [1] :44 Throughout its existence, the Banco della Piazza di Rialto maintained full convertibility of its currency. [2] :210

Historiographical debate about a medieval "Bank of Venice"

Several 19th century authors described a "Bank of Venice" formed in the 12th century, calling it Europe's first national bank and an innovator of non-redeemable debt-based money. [5] Archival research has duly corrected these accounts, distinguishing between the Republic's financing offices, the business of its private bankers, and the much later Banco della Piazza di Rialto, the Republic's first actual public bank. According to the misrepresentation, the Republic collected a prestito in 1157 or 1171 to support its trade wars against the Byzantine Empire. When the Byzantine–Venetian war of 1171 ended in a disastrous defeat, the Republic was ruined and Doge Vitale II Michiel was assassinated. With no means of repaying the loan, the Republic promptly converted it to a perpetual annuity (or in some accounts, offered lenders nothing at all). The legend claims that citizens adopted this imaginary money, finding it more convenient than coins, and the Chamber of Loans became the public bank.

Henry Dunning Macleod's Theory and Practice of Banking (1856) called the story a "great current delusion," while at the same time arguing that the Monti were important forerunners of deposit banking. [6] Sidney Dean's History of Banking (1884) collected several descriptions of the supposed early bank. It noted that researchers had been unable to find documentation of the bank as described, but dismissed this as an oversight of the Venetians. [5] Charles F. Dunbar emphasized the weakness of the legend in 1892. He presented recently published archives as evidence that private deposit bankers operated in Venice by 1318 and were its only bankers until 1584. [7] He made no mention of the activities of the Grain Office, which were examined only later. [3]

See also

References

  1. 1 2 3 4 5 Stefano Ugolini (2017). The Evolution of Central Banking: Theory and History. Palgrave Macmillan.
  2. 1 2 3 4 Ulrich Bindseil (2019). Central Banking Before 1800: A Rehabilitation. Oxford University Press. ISBN   978-0-19-884999-5.
  3. 1 2 3 Gino Luzzatto (1964). "Les banques publiques de Venise (siècles XVI-XVIII)". In Johannes Gerard van Dillen (ed.). History of the Principal Public Banks. Frank Cass & Co. p. 42.
  4. 1 2 Ugo Tucci (1981), "Il Banco della Piazza di Rialto, première banque publique vénitienne", Cahiers de la Méditerranée: 155–169
  5. 1 2 Dean, Sidney (1884). History of Banking and Banks.
  6. Macleod, Henry Dunning (1856). The Theory and Practice of Banking. Vol. 1.
  7. Dunbar, Charles F. (April 1892). "The Bank of Venice". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 6 (3): 308–335.