Economies of agglomeration

Last updated

One of the major subfields of urban economics, economies of agglomeration (or agglomeration effects), explains, in broad terms, how urban agglomeration occurs in locations where cost savings can naturally arise. [1] This term is most often discussed in terms of economic firm productivity. However, agglomeration effects also explain some social phenomena, such as large proportions of the population being clustered in cities and major urban centers. [2] Similar to economies of scale, the costs and benefits of agglomerating increase the larger the agglomerated urban cluster becomes. [3] [4] Several prominent examples of where agglomeration has brought together firms of a specific industry are: Silicon Valley and Los Angeles being hubs of technology and entertainment, respectively, in California, United States; and London, United Kingdom, being a hub of finance. [1]

Contents

Economies of agglomeration have some advantages. As more firms in related fields of business cluster together, their costs of production tend to decline significantly (firms have multiple competing multiple suppliers; greater specialization and division of labor result). Even when competing firms in the same sector cluster, there may be advantages because the cluster attracts more suppliers and customers than a single firm could achieve alone. Cities form and grow to exploit economies of agglomeration.

Diseconomies of agglomeration are the opposite. For example, spatially concentrated growth in automobile-oriented fields may create problems of crowding and traffic congestion. The tension between economies and diseconomies allows cities to grow but keeps them from becoming too large.

At the foundational level, proximity—especially to other facilities and suppliers – is a driving force behind economic growth and is one explanation for why agglomeration effects are so evident in major urban centers. [2] [5] While the concentration of economic activity in cities has a positive effect on their development and growth, cities, in turn, help foster economic activity by accommodating population growth, driving wage increases, and facilitating technological change. [6]

Advantages of agglomeration

When firms form clusters of economic activity, particular development strategies flow into and throughout this area of economic activity. This helps accumulate information and the flow of new and innovative ideas among firms to achieve what economists call increasing returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale are internal economies of scale for a firm, and may allow for establishing more of the same firm outside the area or region. Economies of scale external to a firm result from spatial proximity and are referred to as agglomeration economies of scale. Agglomeration economies can be seen as the external condition for companies and the internal condition for the region.

Increasing returns to scale, according to Beckmann, is integral to understanding why urban centers form. These increasing returns to scale "give rise to [urban systems]," capturing "the trade-off between transportation costs and economies of scale". [6] Agglomeration economies exist when production is cheaper because of this clustering of economic activity. As a result of this clustering, it becomes possible to establish other businesses that may take advantage of these economies without joining any big organization. This process may help to urbanize areas as well.

Benefits arise from the spatial agglomeration of physical capital, companies, consumers, and workers: [7]

Disadvantages of agglomeration

While the existence of cities can only persist if the advantages outweigh the disadvantages, agglomeration would also lead to traffic congestion, pollution, and other negative externalities caused by the clustering of a population of firms and people. These adverse effects will cause economies of scale. [11] Another source of agglomeration diseconomies—higher crowding and increased waiting time—can be observed in disciplines or industries that are characterized by constrained access to relevant production facilities or resources. [12] As stated above, these factors are what decrease the pricing power of firms because of the many competitors in the area, as well as a shortage of labor and a lack of flexibility among firms for the laborers abound. Large cities experience these problems, and this tension between agglomeration economies and agglomeration dis-economies may contribute to the area's growth, control the growth of the area, or cause the area to experience a lack of growth.

The economies of agglomeration have also been shown to increase inequality both within urban areas and between urban and rural areas. [13] The Oxford development economist Paul Collier has proposed that the gains of agglomeration should be taxed as rents, which leads to behavior-distorting rent-seeking (Henry George theorem). This would be ethical and efficient in that gains would be better aligned with deserts, and rent-seeking would be curbed. Collier recommends a tax calculated by combining high-income and metropolitan locations, which can then be redistributed to other cities that have been hard hit by agglomeration. [14]

The disadvantages of agglomerations are to be mentioned: [7]

Types of economies

Two types of economies are considered large-scale and have external economies of scale: localization and urbanization economies. Localization economies arise from many firms in the same industry locating close to each other. There are three sources of localization economies: The first is the benefit of labor pooling, which is the accessibility that firms have to a variety of skilled laborers, which in turn provides employment opportunity for the laborers. The second benefit is the development of industries due to the increasing returns to scale in intermediate inputs for a product, and the third source is the relative ease of communication and exchange of supplies, laborers, and innovative ideas due to the proximity among firms.

Core-periphery model

While localization and urbanization economies and their sources are crucial to sustaining agglomeration economies and cities, it is important to understand the long-term result of the function of agglomeration economies, which relates to the core-periphery model. The core-periphery model features an amount of economic activity in one main area surrounded by a remote area of less dense activity. The concentration of this economic activity in one area (usually a city center) allows for the growth and expansion of activity into other and surrounding areas because of the cost-minimizing location decisions of firms within these agglomeration economies to sustain high productivity and advantages, which therefore allow them to grow outside of the city (core) and into the periphery. A small decrease in the fixed cost of production can increase the range of locations for further establishment of firms, leading to loss of concentration in the city and possibly the development of a new city outside the original city where agglomeration and increasing returns to scale existed.

If localization economies were the main factor contributing to why cities exist with the exclusion of urbanization economies, then it would make sense for each firm in the same industry to form its city. However, in a more realistic sense, cities are more complex than that, which is why the combination of localization and urbanization economies forms large cities.

Source of economies

From the localization of firms emerges labor market pooling. Large populations of skilled laborers enter the area and can exchange knowledge, ideas, and information. The more firms there are in this area, the greater the competition is to obtain workers, resulting in higher wages for the workers. However, the fewer firms there are and the more workers there are at a location the lower the wage for those workers.

The second contribution to localization economies is the access to specialized goods and services provided for clustering firms. This access to specialized goods and services is known as an intermediate input. It provides increasing returns on scale for each of the firms located within that area because of the proximity to available sources needed for production. If intermediate inputs are tradable, a core-periphery notion will have many firms located near each other to be closer to their required sources. Suppose there are tradable resources and services nearby but no related industries in the same area. In that case, there are no networking linkages, and therefore makes it difficult for all firms in the area to obtain resources and increase production. The decreased transportation costs associated with the clustering of firms lead to an increase in the likelihood of a core-periphery pattern; the result will be that more intermediate inputs will be focused at the core and, therefore, will attract more firms in related industries.

The third source relating to localization economies is technological spillovers. One final advantage of this source is that clustering in specific fields leads to quicker diffusion or adoption of ideas. For production to be at its maximum and firms to sell their products, they require some feasible access to capital markets. New forms of technology can create problems and involve risk; the clustering of firms creates an advantage to reduce the uncertainty and complications involved with using new technology through information flow. The capital flow and technology industry is concentrated within specific areas, and therefore, it is to the advantage of the firm to locate near these areas. This technological impact, specifically in the communications field, will provide and dismiss the barrier between firms in the same industry located further away and nearby, leading to a greater concentration of information flow and economic production and activity. Furthermore, technological spillovers may be more beneficial to smaller cities in terms of their growth than larger cities because of the existing informational networks that already helped them form and grow.

See also

Sources

Further reading

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economies of scale</span> Cost advantages obtained via scale of operation

In microeconomics, economies of scale are the cost advantages that enterprises obtain due to their scale of operation, and are typically measured by the amount of output produced per unit of time. A decrease in cost per unit of output enables an increase in scale. At the basis of economies of scale, there may be technical, statistical, organizational or related factors to the degree of market control.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Megacity</span> Metropolitan area with a total population in excess of ten million people

A megacity is a very large city, typically with a population of more than 10 million people. The United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs in its 2018 "World Urbanization Prospects" report defines megacities as urban agglomerations with over 10 million inhabitants. A University of Bonn report holds that they are "usually defined as metropolitan areas with a total population of 10 million or more people". Elsewhere in other sources, from five to eight million is considered the minimum threshold, alongside a population density of at least 2,000 per square kilometre. The terms conurbation, metropolis, and metroplex are also applied to the latter.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Urbanization</span> Process of population movement to cities

Urbanization is the population shift from rural to urban areas, the corresponding decrease in the proportion of people living in rural areas, and the ways in which societies adapt to this change. It can also mean population growth in urban areas instead of rural ones. It is predominantly the process by which towns and cities are formed and become larger as more people begin living and working in central areas.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economic geography</span> Subfield of human geography and economics

Economic geography is the subfield of human geography that studies economic activity and factors affecting it. It can also be considered a subfield or method in economics. There are four branches of economic geography.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Urban geography</span> Subdiscipline of geography concentrating on urban areas

Urban geography is the subdiscipline of geography that derives from a study of cities and urban processes. Urban geographers and urbanists examine various aspects of urban life and the built environment. Scholars, activists, and the public have participated in, studied, and critiqued flows of economic and natural resources, human and non-human bodies, patterns of development and infrastructure, political and institutional activities, governance, decay and renewal, and notions of socio-spatial inclusions, exclusions, and everyday life. Urban geography includes different other fields in geography such as the physical, social, and economic aspects of urban geography. The physical geography of urban environments is essential to understand why a town is placed in a specific area, and how the conditions in the environment play an important role with regards to whether or not the city successfully develops. Social geography examines societal and cultural values, diversity, and other conditions that relate to people in the cities. Economic geography is important to examine the economic and job flow within the urban population. These various aspects involved in studying urban geography are necessary to better understand the layout and planning involved in the development of urban environments worldwide.

Urban economics is broadly the economic study of urban areas; as such, it involves using the tools of economics to analyze urban issues such as crime, education, public transit, housing, and local government finance. More specifically, it is a branch of microeconomics that studies the urban spatial structure and the location of households and firms.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Kuznets curve</span> Hypothesized relationship between economic development and inequality level

The Kuznets curve expresses a hypothesis advanced by economist Simon Kuznets in the 1950s and 1960s. According to this hypothesis, as an economy develops, market forces first increase and then decrease economic inequality. The Kuznets curve appeared to be consistent with experience at the time it was proposed. However, since the 1970s, inequality has risen in the US and other developed countries, which invalidates the hypothesis.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Masahisa Fujita</span> Japanese economist

Masahisa Fujita is a Japanese economist who has studied regional science and Urban economics and International Trade, Spatial Economy. He is a professor at Konan University and an adjunct professor at Institute of Economic Research, Kyoto University.

New trade theory (NTT) is a collection of economic models in international trade theory which focuses on the role of increasing returns to scale and network effects, which were originally developed in the late 1970s and early 1980s. The main motivation for the development of NTT was that, contrary to what traditional trade models would suggest, the majority of the world trade takes place between countries that are similar in terms of development, structure, and factor endowments.

Regional economics is a sub-discipline of economics and is often regarded as one of the fields of the social sciences. It addresses the economic aspect of the regional problems that are spatially analyzable so that theoretical or policy implications can be the derived with respect to regions whose geographical scope ranges from local to global areas.

A business cluster is a geographic concentration of interconnected businesses, suppliers, and associated institutions in a particular field. Clusters are considered to increase the productivity with which companies can compete, nationally and globally. Accounting is a part of the business cluster. In urban studies, the term agglomeration is used. Clusters are also important aspects of strategic management.

Spatial inequality refers to the unequal distribution of income and resources across geographical regions. Attributable to local differences in infrastructure, geographical features and economies of agglomeration, such inequality remains central to public policy discussions regarding economic inequality more broadly.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Urbanization in China</span> Overview of urbanization in China

Urbanization in China increased in speed following the initiation of the reform and opening policy. By the end of 2023, China had an urbanization rate of 66.2% and is expected to reach 75-80% by 2035.

Innovation economics is new, and growing field of economic theory and applied/experimental economics that emphasizes innovation and entrepreneurship. It comprises both the application of any type of innovations, especially technological, but not only, into economic use. In classical economics this is the application of customer new technology into economic use; but also it could refer to the field of innovation and experimental economics that refers the new economic science developments that may be considered innovative. In his 1942 book Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, economist Joseph Schumpeter introduced the notion of an innovation economy. He argued that evolving institutions, entrepreneurs and technological changes were at the heart of economic growth. However, it is only in recent years that "innovation economy," grounded in Schumpeter's ideas, has become a mainstream concept".

Knowledge spillover is an exchange of ideas among individuals. Knowledge spillover is usually replaced by terminations of technology spillover, R&D spillover and/or spillover (economics) when the concept is specific to technology management and innovation economics. In knowledge management economics, knowledge spillovers are non-rival knowledge market costs incurred by a party not agreeing to assume the costs that has a spillover effect of stimulating technological improvements in a neighbor through one's own innovation. Such innovations often come from specialization within an industry.

Cluster theory is a theory of strategy.

Economic globalization is one of the three main dimensions of globalization commonly found in academic literature, with the two others being political globalization and cultural globalization, as well as the general term of globalization. Economic globalization refers to the widespread international movement of goods, capital, services, technology and information. It is the increasing economic integration and interdependence of national, regional, and local economies across the world through an intensification of cross-border movement of goods, services, technologies and capital. Economic globalization primarily comprises the globalization of production, finance, markets, technology, organizational regimes, institutions, corporations, and people.

Thierry Mayer is a French economist and Professor of Economics at Sciences Po. He belongs to the most frequently-cited economists in the field of international trade. In 2006, Mayer and Etienne Wasmer were awarded the Best Young Economist of France Award by Cercle des économistes and Le Monde.

Gianmarco Ireo Paolo Ottaviano is an Italian economist and Professor of Economics at Bocconi University.

John Vernon Henderson is a Canadian-American economist and an academic. He is a Research Affiliate at the International Growth Centre, Director of the Urbanisation in Developing Countries Program, and a School Professor of Economic Geography at the London School of Economics.

References

  1. 1 2 3 4 Ellison, Glenn; Glaeser, Edward L. (May 1999). "The Geographic Concentration of Industry: Does Natural Advantage Explain Agglomeration?". The American Economic Review. 89 (2): 311–316. doi:10.1257/aer.89.2.311. JSTOR   117127 via JSTOR.
  2. 1 2 3 4 Puga, Diego (3 February 2010). "The magnitude and causes of agglomeration economies". Journal of Regional Science. 50 (1): 203–219. Bibcode:2010JRegS..50..203P. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9787.2009.00657.x. S2CID   17848032 via Wiley Online Library.
  3. Combes, Pierre-Philippe; Duranton, Gilles; Gobillon, Laurent (March 2011). "The identification of agglomeration economies". Journal of Economic Geography. 11 (2): 253–266. doi:10.1093/jeg/lbq038 via Oxford Academic.
  4. 1 2 Duranton, Gilles; Puga, Diego (August 2003). "Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies" (PDF). NBER Working Paper Series (9931): 1–61 via National Bureau of Economic Research.
  5. Glaeser, Edward (29 July 2011). "Cities, productivity, and quality of life". Science. 333 (6042): 592–594. Bibcode:2011Sci...333..592G. doi:10.1126/science.1209264. PMID   21798941. S2CID   998870 via JSTOR.
  6. 1 2 Beckmann, Martin J (1995). "Economic Growth in a Central Place System". In Giersch, Herbet (ed.). Urban Agglomeration and Economic Growth. Publications of the Egon-Sohmen-Foundation. pp. 107–115. doi:10.1007/978-3-642-79397-4_4. ISBN   978-3-642-79399-8 via SpringerLink.
  7. 1 2 "Economies of agglomeration". SetThings. 3 November 2014. Retrieved July 22, 2017.
  8. Glaeser, Edward L; Gottlieb, Joshua D (December 2009). "The Wealth of Cities: Agglomeration Economies and Spatial Equilibrium in the United States". Journal of Economic Literature. 47 (4): 983–1028. doi:10.1257/jel.47.4.983. S2CID   59054155 via ProQuest.
  9. Kyriakopoulou, Efthymia; Xepappadeas, Anastasios (May 2017). "Atmospheric pollution in rapidly growing industrial cities: spatial policies and land use patterns". Journal of Economic Geography. 17 (3): 607–634. doi:10.1093/jeg/lbw018. hdl: 11585/580210 via Oxford Academic.
  10. Liang, Jiaochen; Goetz, Stephan J. (December 2018). "Technology intensity and agglomeration economies". Research Policy. 47 (10): 1990–1995. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2018.07.006 . S2CID   158504616.
  11. "Model cities". 2008. Retrieved April 23, 2013.
  12. Borowiecki, Karol J. (2015) Agglomeration Economies in Classical Music, Papers in Regional Science, 94(3): 443-68.
  13. Romero, Jessie and Schwartzman. Inequality in and across Cities. Economic Brief. October 2018, No. 18-10. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
  14. Collier, Paul (2018). The Future of Capitalism: Facing the New Anxieties. pps. 136-40. Penguin. ISBN   9780241333891
  15. Hashmi, Shujahat Haider; Fan, Hongzhong; Fareed, Zeeshan; Shahzad, Farrukh (2021-03-01). "Asymmetric nexus between urban agglomerations and environmental pollution in top ten urban agglomerated countries using quantile methods". Environmental Science and Pollution Research. 28 (11): 13404–13424. Bibcode:2021ESPR...2813404H. doi:10.1007/s11356-020-10669-4. ISSN   1614-7499. PMID   33180285. S2CID   226302283.
  16. Byrne, Christopher D.; Targher, Giovanni (February 2022). "Non-alcoholic fatty liver disease-related risk of cardiovascular disease and other cardiac complications". Diabetes, Obesity and Metabolism. 24 (S2): 28–43. doi:10.1111/dom.14484. ISSN   1462-8902. PMID   34324263. S2CID   236496262.
  17. Tao, Jing; Wang, Ying; Zameer, Hashim (2023-03-24). "Can urban spatial structure adjustment mitigate air pollution effect of economic agglomeration? New evidence from the Yangtze River Delta region, China". Environmental Science and Pollution Research. 30 (20): 57302–57315. doi:10.1007/s11356-023-26561-w. ISSN   1614-7499. PMID   36964467. S2CID   257739565.
  18. Shiu, Alice; Lam, Pun-Lee (2004-01-01). "Electricity consumption and economic growth in China". Energy Policy. 32 (1): 47–54. doi:10.1016/S0301-4215(02)00250-1. ISSN   0301-4215.
  19. Fuerst, Franz; Warren-Myers, Georgia (2018-08-01). "Does voluntary disclosure create a green lemon problem? Energy-efficiency ratings and house prices". Energy Economics. 74: 1–12. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2018.04.041. ISSN   0140-9883. S2CID   158243513.
  20. Williamson, Jeffrey G. (July 1965). "Regional Inequality and the Process of National Development: A Description of the Patterns". Economic Development and Cultural Change. 13 (4, Part 2): 1–84. doi:10.1086/450136. ISSN   0013-0079. S2CID   153694729.
  21. Deiwiks, Christa; Cederman, Lars-Erik; Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede (March 2012). "Inequality and conflict in federations". Journal of Peace Research. 49 (2): 289–304. doi:10.1177/0022343311431754. ISSN   0022-3433. S2CID   110425780.
  22. Lessmann, Christian (2014-01-01). "Spatial inequality and development — Is there an inverted-U relationship?". Journal of Development Economics. 106: 35–51. doi:10.1016/j.jdeveco.2013.08.011. hdl: 10419/52441 . ISSN   0304-3878. S2CID   26165923.
  23. Wu, JunJie (2019-10-05). "Agglomeration: Economic and Environmental Impacts". Annual Review of Resource Economics. 11 (1): 419–438. doi: 10.1146/annurev-resource-100518-094151 . ISSN   1941-1340. S2CID   197835295.
  24. Takeuchi, Ai; Seki, Erika (2023-02-01). "Coordination and free-riding problems in the provision of multiple public goods". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 206: 95–121. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2022.11.022. hdl: 11094/73432 . ISSN   0167-2681. S2CID   221134561.
  25. Aghion, Philippe; Cai, Jing; Dewatripont, Mathias; Du, Luosha; Harrison, Ann; Legros, Patrick (2015-10-01). "Industrial Policy and Competition". American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics. 7 (4): 1–32. doi:10.1257/mac.20120103. ISSN   1945-7707. S2CID   263328590.