Catallactics

Last updated

Catallactics is a theory of the way the free market system reaches exchange ratios and prices. [1] [2] [3] [4] It aims to analyse all actions based on monetary calculation and trace the formation of prices back to the point where an agent makes his or her choices. [5] It explains prices as they are, rather than as they "should" be. The laws of catallactics are not value judgments, but aim to be exact, empirical, and of universal validity. It was used extensively by the Austrian School economist Ludwig von Mises. [6]

Contents

Etymology

The term catallactics or catallaxy, respectively, comes from the Greek verb καταλλάσσω which means to exchange, to reconcile. [7] [8]

Definition

Catallactics is a praxeological theory. The term catallaxy was used by Friedrich Hayek to describe "the order brought about by the mutual adjustment of many individual economies in a market." [9] Hayek was dissatisfied with the usage of the word "economy" because its Greek root, which translates as "household management", implies that economic agents in a market economy possess shared goals. He derived the word "Catallaxy" (Hayek's suggested Greek construction would be rendered καταλλαξία) from the Greek verb katallasso (καταλλάσσω) which meant not only "to exchange" but also "to admit in the community" and "to change from enemy into friend." [10]

According to Mises [11] and Hayek [12] it was Richard Whately who coined the term "catallactics". Whately's Introductory Lectures on Political Economy (1831) reads: [13] [14]

It is with a view to put you on your guard against prejudices thus created, (and you will meet probably with many instances of persons influenced by them,) that I have stated my objections to the name of Political-Economy. It is now, I conceive, too late to think of changing it. A. Smith, indeed, has designated his work a treatise on the "Wealth of Nations;" but this supplies a name only for the subject-matter, not for the science itself. The name I should have preferred as the most descriptive, and on the whole least objectionable, is that of CATALLACTICS, or the "Science of Exchanges."

See also

Notes

  1. "catallactics". Oxford English Dictionary third edition. Oxford University Press. December 2002. Retrieved 3 October 2023.
  2. "catallactics". Merriam Webster Dictionary (11th ed.). 2003. Retrieved 3 October 2023.
  3. "s.v. catallactics". The Oxford English Dictionary: Being a Corrected Re-Issue of with An Introduction, Supplement and Bibliography of a New English Dictionary on Historical Principles. Vol. 2 C. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 1933. p.  170 . Retrieved 3 October 2023 via Internet Archive.
  4. Rothbard, Murray N. (2008). "catallactics". In Durlauf, Steven N.; Blume, Lawrence E. (eds.). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics . Vol. 1 (2nd ed.). New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan. pp.  704-705 via Internet Archive.
  5. Rutherford, Donald (2002). "catallactics". Routledge Dictionary of Economics (2nd ed.). London and New York: Routledge. p.  75 via Internet Archive.
  6. Kirzner, Israel M. (2001). Ludwig von Mises: The Man and His Economics . Wilmington, Delaware: ISI Books. pp.  93-.
  7. Liddell, Henry George; Scott, Robert (1992). A Greek - English Lexicon . Oxford: Clarendon Press. p.  899 via Internet Archive.
  8. "s.v. καταλλάσσω". ΛΟΓΕΙΟΝ. Retrieved 30 September 2023.
  9. Hayek, F.A. (1976). Law, Legislation, and Liberty (The Mirage of Social Justice). Vol. 2. London: Routledge. pp.  108–109.
  10. Hayek, F.A. (1976). Law, Legislation, and Liberty (The Mirage of Social Justice). Vol. 2. London: Routledge. pp.  108–109. See also p. 185 n4.
  11. Mises, Ludwig (1949). Human Action: A Treatise on Economics. London: William Hodge and Company, Limited. p.  3 via Internet Archive.
  12. "Catallactics &education". Archived from the original on 2010-07-17. Retrieved 2010-07-14.
  13. Whately, Richard (1832). Introductory Lectures on Political Economy: Delivered in Eastern Term, MDCCCXXXI (2nd ed.). London: B. Fellowes. pp.  6-7 . Retrieved 27 September 2023 via Internet Archive.
  14. "Online Library of Liberty - Reading Lists - Ian Dunois' Free Market foundations". Archived from the original on 2010-07-17. Retrieved 2010-07-14. A footnote to this paragraph continues: "It is perhaps hardly necessary to observe, that I do not pretend to have classical authority for this use of the word Catallactics; nor do I deem it necessary to make any apology for using it without such authority. It would be thought, I conceive, an absurd pedantry to find fault with such words as "thermometer," "telescope," "pneumatics," "hydraulics," "geology," &c. on the ground that classical Greek writers have not employed them, or have taken them in a different sense. In the present instance, however, I am not sure that, if Aristotle had had occasion to express my meaning, he would not have used the very same word. In fact I may say he has used another part of the same verb in the sense of "exchanging;" (for the Verbals in are, to all practical purposes, to be regarded as parts of the verbs they are formed from) in the third book of the Nicom. Ethics he speaks of men who hold their lives so cheap, that they risked them in exchange for the most trifling gain (καταλλάττονται). The employment of this and kindred words in the sense of "reconcilement," is evidently secondary, reconciliation being commonly effected by a compensation; something accepted as an equivalent for loss or injury."

Bibliography

Related Research Articles

The Austrian School is a heterodox school of economic thought that advocates strict adherence to methodological individualism, the concept that social phenomena result primarily from the motivations and actions of individuals and their self interest. Austrian school theorists hold that economic theory should be exclusively derived from basic principles of human action.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Carl Menger</span> Founder of the Austrian School of economics (1840–1921)

Carl Menger von Wolfensgrün was an Austrian economist and the founder of the Austrian School of economics. Menger contributed to the development of the theories of marginalism and marginal utility, which rejected cost-of-production theory of value, such as developed by the classical economists such as Adam Smith and David Ricardo. As a departure from such, he would go on to call his resultant perspective, the subjective theory of value.

The economic calculation problem is a criticism of using economic planning as a substitute for market-based allocation of the factors of production. It was first proposed by Ludwig von Mises in his 1920 article "Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth" and later expanded upon by Friedrich Hayek.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Friedrich Hayek</span> Austrian–British economist, philosopher, Nobel Laureate

Friedrich August von Hayek, often referred to by his initials F. A. Hayek, was an Austrian-British economist and political philosopher who made contributions to economics, political philosophy, psychology, intellectual history, and other fields. Hayek shared the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences with Gunnar Myrdal for work on money and economic fluctuations, and the interdependence of economic, social and institutional phenomena. His account of how prices communicate information is widely regarded as an important contribution to economics that led to him receiving the prize.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Israel Kirzner</span> American economist

Israel Meir Kirzner is a British-born American economist, historian, rabbi, and Talmudist closely identified with the Austrian School.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Ludwig Lachmann</span> German economist (1906–1990)

Ludwig Maurits Lachmann was a German economist, economic theorist and important contributor to the Austrian School of Economics. Lachmann, Israel Kirzner, and Murray Rothbard were the three primary catalysts of the Austrian 'revival', beginning in 1974. He wrote on economic theory, history, and methodology, as well as on the application of Hermeneutics to economic thought, in order to interpret economic phenomena.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Wilhelm Röpke</span> German economist (1899–1966)

Wilhelm Röpke was a German economist and social critic, best known as one of the spiritual fathers of the social market economy. A Professor of Economics, first in Jena, then in Graz, Marburg, Istanbul, and finally Geneva, Röpke theorised and collaborated to organise the post-World War II economic re-awakening of the war-wrecked German economy, deploying a program referred to as ordoliberalism, a more conservative variant of German liberalism.

Spontaneous order, also named self-organization in the hard sciences, is the spontaneous emergence of order out of seeming chaos. The term "self-organization" is more often used for physical changes and biological processes, while "spontaneous order" is typically used to describe the emergence of various kinds of social orders in human social networks from the behavior of a combination of self-interested individuals who are not intentionally trying to create order through planning. Proposed examples of systems which evolved through spontaneous order or self-organization include the evolution of life on Earth, language, crystal structure, the Internet, Wikipedia, and a free market economy.

Catallaxy or catallactics is an alternative expression for the word "economy". Whereas the word economy suggests that people in a community possess a common and congruent set of values and goals, catallaxy suggests that the emergent properties of a market are the outgrowths of the diverse and disparate goals of the individuals in a community.

Richard M. Ebeling is an American libertarian author who was the president of the Foundation for Economic Education (FEE) from 2003 to 2008. Ebeling is currently the BB&T Distinguished Professor of Ethics and Free Enterprise Leadership at The Citadel in Charleston, South Carolina.

Hermann Heinrich Gossen was a German economist who is often regarded as the first to elaborate, in detail, a general theory of marginal utility.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Criticism of socialism</span> Overview of criticism of an economic system and political ideology

Criticism of socialism is any critique of socialist economics and socialist models of organization and their feasibility, as well as the political and social implications of adopting such a system. Some critiques are not necessarily directed toward socialism as a system but rather toward the socialist movement, parties, or existing states. Some critics consider socialism to be a purely theoretical concept that should be criticized on theoretical grounds, such as in the economic calculation problem and the socialist calculation debate, while others hold that certain historical examples exist and that they can be criticized on practical grounds. Because there are many types of socialism, most critiques are focused on a specific type of socialism, that of the command economy and the experience of Soviet-type economies that may not apply to all forms of socialism as different models of socialism conflict with each other over questions of property ownership, economic coordination and how socialism is to be achieved. Critics of specific models of socialism might be advocates of a different type of socialism.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Jesús Huerta de Soto</span> Spanish economist of the Austrian School (born 1956)

Jesús Huerta de Soto Ballester is a Spanish economist of the Austrian School. He is a professor in the Department of Applied Economics at King Juan Carlos University of Madrid, Spain and a Senior Fellow at the Mises Institute.

Henry Dunning Macleod was a Scottish economist and lawyer.

Peter Joseph Boettke is an American economist of the Austrian School. He is currently a professor of economics and philosophy at George Mason University; the BB&T Professor for the Study of Capitalism, vice president for research, and director of the F.A. Hayek Program for Advanced Study in Philosophy, Politics, and Economics at the Mercatus Center at GMU.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Ludwig von Mises</span> Austrian–American economist (1881–1973)

Ludwig Heinrich Edler von Mises was a Ukraine-born Austrian–American Austrian School economist, historian, logician, and sociologist. Mises wrote and lectured extensively on the societal contributions of classical liberalism and the power of consumers. He is best known for his work on praxeology studies comparing communism and capitalism.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Edwin Cannan</span> British economist and economic historian

Edwin Cannan was a British economist and historian of economic thought. He taught at the London School of Economics from 1895 to 1926.

Bruce J. Caldwell is an American historian of economics, Research Professor of Economics at Duke University, and Director of the Center for the History of Political Economy. Prior to holding this position, Caldwell was the Joe Rosenthal Excellence Professor of Economics at the University of North Carolina at Greensboro. In 1979, he received his Ph.D. in Economics from the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill and did post-doctoral work at New York University, where he was influenced by both Ludwig Lachmann and Israel Kirzner.

Ronald Hamowy was a Canadian academic, known primarily for his contributions to political and social academic fields. At the time of his death, he was professor emeritus of intellectual history at the University of Alberta in Edmonton, Canada. Hamowy was closely associated with the political ideology of libertarianism and his writings and scholarship place particular emphasis on individual liberty and the limits of state action in a free society. He is associated with a number of prominent American libertarian organizations.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Theodore Gregory</span> British economist (1890–1970)

Sir Theodore Emmanuel Gugenheim Gregory was a British economist.