History of the cooperative movement in China

Last updated

The modern cooperative movement arose in the early 19th century as a response to the negative social consequences of the Industrial Revolution and thus was a response to the same conditions that begot the wider labor movement. Two men are typically credited with developing the modern concept of the cooperative enterprise: Robert Owen in Britain and Charles Fourier on the European continent. [1] They advocated that, instead of having businesses be owned by private individuals who pay workers wages and then keep all remaining profits, businesses be set up that gave ownership to the workers themselves as a class. These proposals soon developed into a social movement that was present in many countries; in 1895, the First International Co-operative Congress was held, which lead to the foundation of the International Co-operative Alliance. [2]

Marxism and cooperatives

Owen and Fourier both called themselves socialists at some point, and are typically regarded as belonging to the utopian socialist movement. Thus, they were criticized by Karl Marx for, above all, failing to recognize the fundamental role of class conflict in history, while cooperatives as a social form had a mixed reputation in early Marxist circles. On one hand, Marx both praised the development of cooperatives as a victory for the working class in his public speeches and in theoretical works such as Capital analyzed cooperatives as prefiguring, within capitalism, what labor relations will become in communism. [3] On the other hand, Marx insisted that the duty of cooperatives was to gain leverage for the working class to overthrow the capitalist system, thus he also worried that cooperatives might look out only for themselves instead of playing a role in the wider class struggle. [4] As a result, Marx and the wider communist movement would increasingly turn away from bottom-up organization of workers' cooperatives to aim for communist capture of state power as the 19th century progressed; however, this was for what they thought was political expediency, not theoretical necessity. The wider cooperative movement, for its part, continued to be led by people with a variety of opinions on political economy, but were for the most part non- or even anti-Marxist.

Early 20th century China

China's economic and political condition in the early 20th century is generally regarded as poor. Politically, China entered the 20th century still under the rule of an absolute monarch and while never outright conquered by a Western power, it was still made to sign the unequal treaties which forced China to accept exploitative trading terms and grant what was effectively legal independence to the territorial holdings of foreign powers. The Chinese Emperor was overthrown in 1911 and the Republic of China was proclaimed, but the young republic soon was broken apart by small warlords fighting each other. This dire political situation was accompanied by economic deprivation; outside of Shanghai, China had undergone essentially no industrialization, with most of the population being rural peasants with extremely small land holdings.

Traditional Chinese forms of mutual aid

Cooperative
Chinese 合作社

While cooperatives as a modern institution responding to the Industrial Revolution are typically credited to Owens and Fourier, the basic principle of mutual aid between those in need is as old as history itself. Pre-modern China's traditions of mutual aid are vast, differing from place to place and time to time. Some examples include: "buying the leg of an ox", whereby a poorer peasant could contribute some money toward a richer peasant's purchase of an ox, and be rewarded with the occasional use of that ox. [5]

Early cooperatives in China, 1919–1935

Xue Xianzhou, the "Father of Chinese Cooperatives"

One of the earliest people to promote cooperatives in China was the Chinese professor and banker Xue Xianzhou. In 1919, he, together with students from Fudan University, founded the Shanghai Cooperative Savings Bank. In 1927 he published a proposal entitled, A Plan for the Cooperativization of China. [6] The plan had three main points: first, it called for a National Cooperative Union "to direct training, planning, and 'practical application;'" second, for a Cooperative Training Institute "to conduct six years of training, divided equally between academic studies and practical work;" and third, for a National Cooperative Bank for "financially assisting cooperative enterprises, worker and agricultural enterprises, [and] lightly capitalized businesses." [7] Xue died suddenly in September 1927, not able to see his plans realized.

The China International Famine Relief Commission and cooperatives

Another major strand of the cooperative movement in China came about as a result of Western charitable responses to the 1920–1921 famine. In February 1921, the China International Famine Relief Commission was chartered to manage the distribution of Western funds raised for Chinese famine relief. [8] Among its various actions, beginning in Hubei in 1923 it started sponsoring the formation of rural credit cooperatives, which peasants would buy into and then be able to take out loans for capital improvement of their farms. [9] These proved quite popular and spread quickly, such that the CIFRC also experimented with sponsoring other forms of cooperatives, such as the mutual aid society, though it is unclear what exactly these did. [10] As the number of credit and other cooperatives expanded, it drew the attention of commercial banks, and eventually the Nationalist government. In 1935 the Cooperative Law was passed, and responsibility for overseeing cooperatives in the Republic of China was transferred to the Cooperative Department of the Ministry of Industries. [11]

Diverse cooperatives in Nationalist China, 1935–1949

Cooperatives and the Guomindang

Chinese Industrial Cooperative movement

The Guomindang's growing state influence over the cooperative movement was, like all other aspects of Chinese society, upended by the Japanese invasion of 1937. Most cooperative activity, whether CIFRC-inspired, state-directed, or relatively independent, was concentrated in Hebei, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, and Shandong, and thus the diverse strands of the prior movement were almost entirely snuffed out by the invasion. [12] Out of this cooperative vacuum emerged what is likely the most infamous cooperative movement in history: the Chinese Industrial Cooperative movement; aka Indusco; aka Gung-ho .

Indusco was founded by three foreigners – Helen Snow, Edgar Snow, and Rewi Alley – all of whom were long-term Communist sympathizers and were thus for most of their time in China contemptuous of cooperatives, for the same reasons as the later Marx or the early Lenin was. However, in the aftermath of the invasion, Helen Snow, first by herself then in conversation with her husband and Alley, an old friend, developed the idea of a network of rural light-industry cooperatives which would supply the Nationalist army fighting against the Japanese, thus achieving a dual purpose of war support for the country and economic development among the peasantry. [13] After the three of them worked every lead they had with Guomindang leaders, including Song Qingling, on August 5, 1938, the Chinese Industrial Cooperative Association was founded by an act of the President of the Executive Yuan, Kong Xiangxi. [14] A Chinese associate of Alley, Liu Guangpei, was appointed General Secretary of the Association, and Alley was appointed Technical Advisor. [15] Under Kong's patronage, they set out to organize industrial cooperatives in the countryside as in Snow's plan.

The movement failed. 21st century scholar Jenny Clegg says that Indusco fell "so far short of its ambitions ... as to cast doubt on its credibility." [16] A Japanese intelligence officer reported at the time that the movement was "ludicrous" (馬鹿馬鹿しい). [17] Out of a stated goal of forming 30,000 cooperatives, at its high-water mark in 1941 the movement had organized only 1,867. [18]

Despite the failures, the Chinese Industrial Cooperative movement is noteworthy for several reasons. First, it was the first cooperative movement in China that put industry at the forefront. Second, it was an example of a movement, born of the urgency of the war, that had no qualms about being aggressive with its agenda, yet also trying to balance this with maintaining a traditional cooperative emphasis on grassroots decision-making. Finally, it was the first explicitly left-wing cooperative movement in China: all three founders were Communist sympathizers who sought the approval of Mao. [19]

Cooperatives with the Communists in Yan’an

When the remnants of the Communist party arrived in Shaanxi after the Long March, the government they established had extremely limited resources, so cooperatives were appealing not only for ideological reasons, but also for practical ones: self-organizing enterprises would require less of scarce state resources than state-directed ones. This was part of the spirit of the Yan’an Rectification Drive, whereby popular management (民辦) was the order of the day. [20] The difficulty in establishing cooperatives, however, lay in the fact that in many areas the populace was so uneducated that the administrative tasks necessary to run an organization like a cooperative were utterly lacking. For this reason the concept of the mutual aid team emerged, as a simple structure that would not require separate administrative skills and yet would both ideologically encourage communal values among the populace and also, hopefully, lead to increased yields. [20] These mutual aid teams were very similar to traditional forms of collaboration and they often simply replicated legacy social relations of aid between kin, although the Communists did their best to encourage the formation of new networks of aid. [21] As mutual aid teams became more experienced throughout the 40s, the Communists encouraged them to remain in formation year-long, and, when not engaged in the fundamentals of sowing and reaping, put their combined efforts on reclamation of farmland and capital improvements. [22] These efforts produced clear benefit to the populace, and were part of the reason that the Communists were able to maintain their power. [23]

Mutual aid teams were not the full extent of the Communists’ dreams, however. In the areas where the Communists had stronger control and more concentrated personnel they pursued cooperatives with aplomb. Ideally, all productive activity would be organized into cooperative form, and the Communists held up as a model the "comprehensive" cooperative of Liulin village near Yan’an. [20] This single cooperative "combined more than 20 activities which, along with enterprises such as handicraft workshops, retail shops, porterage and team farming, included the collection of grain and salt taxes, the mediation of disputes, marriage brokerage and the management of welfare granaries." [20] This was, of course, exceptional; most cooperatives were far more limited in scope, but the extent of the Liulin cooperative does demonstrate how appropriate the Communists found the cooperative form for almost any problem of economic organization during the uncertainty and limitedness of the Yan’an years.

Statistics

The following statistics are compiled from surveys carried out by the Nationalist government. They do not capture all cooperative activity going on in China, and evince some clear data quality issues, but nevertheless give an impression of the growth and changes in cooperative activity during the period.

Cooperatives in China by year and type [24]
YearTotalCredit (%)Agriculture (%)Industrial (%)Marketing (%)Consumption (%)Utility (%)Insurance (%)Other (%)
19311,57687.505.465.460.823.430.542.22
193526,22458.808.908.908.7023.60
1940133,54287.007.001.702.001.400.300.100.50
1945172,05338.0018.004.9011.0014.002.801.909.40
1949170,18129.4022.704.8013.9014.002.502.1010.60

Cooperatives during the Maoist period, 1949–1978

Chronology

Land Reform Movement, 1946–1953

As justification for the Second United Front, Mao developed the concept of New Democracy, wherein he saw the Communist Party as leading, in alliance with capitalist and other bourgeois elements, a mass nationalist revolution against colonialism and not a proletarian revolution against capitalism, which would be put off for a later, more appropriate moment. [25] Once the Japanese had been defeated in the Second Sino-Japanese War and the Guomindang had been defeated in the Chinese Civil War, the Party believed that the time had come to promote socialism in China, yet it was subject to the constraint that it had allowed many of its allies to continue to operate in capitalist ways, and it could not turn against them all at once. As a result, at the founding of the People's Republic in 1949, Party leadership was agreed that the socialist transformation of China was to proceed slowly. [26] To strengthen the Party's influence in the countryside, which remained quite tenuous, the Party launched the Land Reform campaign to promote class struggle and land redistribution, which were seen as inseparable; there was to be no redistribution of land without getting the peasantry emotionally and physically involved in the Revolution through class struggle. [27] Through the process of Land Reform, rural land was redistributed from those who were deemed landlords and rich peasants to those who were deemed poor peasants and tenant farmers, so that at the end of a campaign all households within a village would have approximately equal amounts of land. The Land Reform campaign in itself had nothing to do with cooperatives; it strictly reallocated land between individual households, while recruiting families to join their new property into cooperatives was the focus of later campaigns. By 1953, the Land Reform campaign was complete.

Early promotion of cooperatives, 1951–1955

The period of 1951–1955 was characterized by frequently changing government policy regarding the economic forms of rural life, though cooperatives feature prominently throughout. The government would hold a single position for months, then abruptly shift to a different position as it struggled to navigate several tensions present in the rural economy:

  • First, the Party had from its earliest moments seen agricultural surplus as the economic advantage with which it would support the industrialization of the nation. Accordingly, many voices within the government held that the highest priority regarding rural economic policy should be to maintain rising agricultural output, with all other concerns secondary. [28]
  • Second, the Party held as a foundational goal the establishment of a classless, socialist society. Under this framework, Land Reform had been a crucial step forward in combating inequality. However, there remained a worrisome possibility that the richer middle peasants, with their landlords competitors now removed, would dominate in the remaining elements of an individual market economy, while the newly landed poor peasants, still getting adjusted to their new station, would be taken advantage of and fall behind, and thus class inequality would re-emerge. [29] Consequently, some party members urged more rapid promotion of cooperatives and other structures that would protect equality among the peasantry.
  • Finally, in most of the Party's thinking, an agricultural cooperative, being much larger than an individual farm plot, would require industrialized agriculture methods. [30] Since China's industrial capacity was so low, and Soviet aid in industrialization would be insufficient to make up the difference, many party members thought that the transition to cooperatives would be technically impossible in the short term.

These tensions were on full display in the early years of the PRC. In 1949 and 1950, the Seventh Central Committee repeatedly affirmed that the long-term future of Chinese agriculture lay in cooperatives, but that the development of cooperatives would take a long time and was not to be rushed. [31] In November 1952 the Central Rural Work Department was created to oversee the process of cooperativization and Deng Zihui was appointed as its head. [32] Deng and Mao advocated a gradual approach to the socialization of agriculture, encouraging the formation of simple Mutual Aid Teams in most villages, and then, in those villages which were especially eager for socialism, the establishment of Elementary Agricultural Production Cooperatives. [32]

The "high tide" of cooperativization, 1955–1958

On July 31, 1955, Mao delivered the report "On the Co-operative Transformation of Agriculture", in which he unexpectedly critiqued the pace of cooperative development so far and urged that peasant farmers be organized into cooperatives much more quickly. [33] His words were heeded, and by the end of 1958 most of the population had been organized into Advanced Agricultural Production Cooperatives.

Great Leap Forward and collectivization, 1958–1978

In 1958, as part of the Great Leap Forward, the Advanced Agricultural Production Cooperatives were transformed into the People's Communes. These institutions were conceived of as top-down, local units of the state and are so far from the bottom-up, autonomous associations of the Owenite tradition that they are not regarded as cooperatives by the wider cooperative movement, nor were they called cooperatives in Chinese. For the rest of the Maoist period, it was the People's Communes, not cooperatives, that were the primary, often the only, economic institution that played a role in people's lives.

Types of cooperatives

The Communists were already running into difficulties with maintaining enough qualified personnel to implement their agenda in Yan’an, and after their victory in the Civil War, their personnel shortages became gargantuan, which led to the recruitment of sometimes extremely ill-prepared cadres. [34] Consequently, the intended plans of the Communist leadership could become something else entirely in the hands of local cadres working in a particular village. Hence, any description of how cooperatives were intended to work in the early Maoist period can vary greatly from cooperatives as implemented; the extreme shortage of cadres with requisite skills and the constantly changing political environment led to rules broken as often as observed, and for that matter, rules rewritten almost as soon as they were published. [35] Nevertheless, there were templates that informed the process of cooperativization, which are listed here.

Mutual Aid Team

  1. Chisholm 1911, p. 83.
  2. ICA 2022.
  3. Jossa 2005, p. 5.
  4. Jossa 2005, p. 12.
  5. Shue 1980, p. 151.
  6. Reynolds 1975, p. 156.
  7. Reynolds 1975, p. 158.
  8. Nathan 1965, p. 11.
  9. Nathan 1965, p. 30.
  10. Nathan 1965, p. 36.
  11. Reynolds 1975, p. 164.
  12. Reynolds 1975, p. 165.
  13. Reynolds 1975, p. 60.
  14. Reynolds 1975, p. 127.
  15. Reynolds 1975, p. 130.
  16. Clegg 2012, p. 307.
  17. Reynolds 1975, p. 179.
  18. Reynolds 1975, p. 151.
  19. Reynolds 1975, p. 214.
  20. 1 2 3 4 Keating 1994, p. 1032.
  21. Keating 1994, p. 1038.
  22. Keating 1994, p. 1049.
  23. Keating 1994, p. 1050.
  24. Lai 1989, p. 61.
  25. Mao 1939.
  26. Teiwes & Sun 1993, p. 6.
  27. Shue 1980, p. 82.
  28. Teiwes & Sun 1993, p. 5.
  29. 1 2 Shue 1980, p. 147.
  30. Shue 1980, p. 146.
  31. Teiwes & Sun 1993, p. 28.
  32. 1 2 Teiwes & Sun 1993, p. 7.
  33. Stettner & Oram 1987, p. 5.
  34. Shue 1980, p. 67.
  35. Shue 1980, p. 209.
  36. Shue 1980, p. 145.
  37. Shue 1980, p. 144.
  38. Shue 1980, p. 204.
  39. Shue 1980, p. 203.
  40. Shue 1980, p. 215.
  41. Shue 1980, p. 231.
  42. Shue 1980, p. 287.
  43. Shue 1980, p. 288-296.
  44. 1 2 Eyferth 2009, p. 129.
  45. Schran 1964, p. 152.
  46. Schran 1964, p. 154.
  47. Eyferth 2009, p. 117.
  48. Eyferth 2009, p. 121.

Related Research Articles

Agrarianism is a social and political philosophy that promotes subsistence agriculture, family farming, widespread property ownership, and political decentralization. Adherents of agrarianism tend to value traditional bonds of local community over urban modernity. Agrarian political parties sometimes aim to support the rights and sustainability of small farmers and poor peasants against the wealthy in society.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Deng Xiaoping</span> Chinese communist leader (1904–1997)

Deng Xiaoping was a Chinese revolutionary and statesman who served as the paramount leader of the People's Republic of China (PRC) from December 1978 to November 1989. After Chinese Communist Party chairman Mao Zedong's death in 1976, Deng rose to power and led China through its process of Reform and Opening Up and the development of the country's socialist market economy. Deng developed a reputation as the "Architect of Modern China" and his ideological contributions to socialism with Chinese characteristics are described as Deng Xiaoping Theory.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Mao Zedong</span> Chinese communist leader (1893–1976)

Mao Zedong was a Chinese politician, Marxist theorist, military strategist, poet, and revolutionary who was the founder of the People's Republic of China (PRC). He led the country from its establishment in 1949 until his death in 1976, while also serving as the chairman of the Chinese Communist Party during that time. His theories, military strategies and policies are known as Maoism.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Maoism</span> Variety of Marxism–Leninism developed by Mao Zedong

Maoism, also known as Mao Zedong Thought, is a variety of Marxism–Leninism that Mao Zedong developed while trying to realize a socialist revolution in the agricultural, pre-industrial society of the Republic of China and later the People's Republic of China. A difference between Maoism and traditional Marxism–Leninism is that a united front of progressive forces in class society would lead the revolutionary vanguard in pre-industrial societies rather than communist revolutionaries alone. This theory, in which revolutionary praxis is primary and ideological orthodoxy is secondary, represents urban Marxism–Leninism adapted to pre-industrial China. Later theoreticians expanded on the idea that Mao had adapted Marxism–Leninism to Chinese conditions, arguing that he had in fact updated it fundamentally and that Maoism could be applied universally throughout the world. This ideology is often referred to as Marxism–Leninism–Maoism to distinguish it from the original ideas of Mao.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">People's commune</span> Former rural administrative division of the Peoples Republic of China (1958-83)

The people's commune was the highest of three administrative levels in rural areas of the People's Republic of China during the period from 1958 to 1983, until they were replaced by townships. Communes, the largest collective units, were divided in turn into production brigades and production teams. The communes had governmental, political, and economic functions during the Cultural Revolution. The people's commune was commonly known for collectivizing living and working practices, especially during the Great Leap Forward. The scale of the commune and its ability to extract income from the rural population enabled commune administrations to invest in large-scale mechanization, infrastructure, and industrial projects. The communes did not, however, meet many of their long-term goals, such as facilitating the construction of socialism in the rural areas, liberating women from housework, and creating sustainable agriculture practices in the countryside. They ranged in number from 50,000 to 90,000.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Ten Major Relationships</span>

On the Ten Major Relationships is a speech by Mao Zedong which outlines how the People's Republic of China would construct socialism different from the model of development undertaken by the Soviet Union. It was delivered by Mao during an enlarged session of a Politburo meeting of the Chinese Communist Party on April 25, 1956 and further elaborated in the 7th Supreme State Conference on May 2 the same year.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Gao Gang</span> Chinese politician (1905–1954)

Gao Gang was a Chinese Communist Party (CCP) leader during the Chinese Civil War and the early years of the People's Republic of China (PRC) before he became the victim of the first major purge within the party since before 1949. The events surrounding Gao's purge, the so-called "Gao Gang Affair", are still the subject of debate: a limited amount of research has been done on the topic, partly because of the relatively small amount of information available.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Zhang Wentian</span> Chinese politician (1900–1976)

Zhang Wentian was a Chinese politician who was a high-ranking leader of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP).

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Yan'an Rectification Movement</span> 1942–45 Chinese Communist Party political effort

The Yan'an Rectification Movement was a political mass movement led by the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) from 1942 to 1945. The movement took place in the Yan'an Soviet, a revolutionary base area centered on the remote city of Yan'an. Although it was during the Second Sino-Japanese War, the CCP was experiencing a time of relative peace when they could focus on internal affairs.

The economic history of China describes the changes and developments in China's economy from the founding of the People's Republic of China (PRC) in 1949 to the present day. The speed of China's transformation in this period from one of the poorest countries to one of the world's largest economies is unmatched in history.

The mass line is the political, organizational and leadership method developed by Mao Zedong and the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) during the Chinese Communist Revolution. It refers to formulating policy based on theory, implementing it based on people's real world conditions, revising theory and policy based on actual practice, and using that revised theory as the guide to future practice. In Maoist terms, it is summarized by the phrase, "To the masses - from the masses - to the masses".

The sent-down, rusticated, or "educated" youth, also known as the zhiqing, were the young people who—beginning in the 1950s until the end of the Cultural Revolution, willingly or under coercion—left the urban districts of the People's Republic of China to live and work in rural areas as part of the "Up to the Mountains and Down to the Countryside Movement".

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Yan'an Forum</span> 1942 forum on revolutionary cultural production

The Yan'an Forum on Literature and Art was a May 1942 forum held in the Yan'an Soviet and a significant event in the Yan'an Rectification Movement. It is most notable for the speeches given by Mao Zedong, later edited and published as Talks at the Yan'an Forum on Literature and Art which dealt with the role of literature and art in the country. The two main points were that (1) all art should reflect the life of the working class and consider them as an audience, and (2) that art should serve politics, and specifically the advancement of socialism. The excesses of the latter point during the Cultural Revolution led to current Chinese Communist Party policy rejecting that point, but retaining Mao's encouragement of peasant-focused art and literature.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Collective farming</span> Type of agricultural organization

Collective farming and communal farming are various types of "agricultural production in which multiple farmers run their holdings as a joint enterprise". There are two broad types of communal farms: agricultural cooperatives, in which member-owners jointly engage in farming activities as a collective; and state farms, which are owned and directly run by a centralized government. The process by which farmland is aggregated is called collectivization. In some countries, there have been both state-run and cooperative-run variants. For example, the Soviet Union had both kolkhozy and sovkhozy.

Agrarian socialism is a political ideology that promotes social ownership of agrarian and agricultural production as opposed to private ownership. Agrarian socialism involves equally distributing agricultural land among collectivized peasant villages. Many agrarian socialist movements have tended to be rural, locally focused, and traditional. Governments and political parties seeking agrarian socialist policies have existed throughout the world, in regions including Europe, Asia, North America, Latin America, and Africa.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Deng Zihui</span> Chinese revolutionary and politician (1896-1972)

Deng Zihui was a Chinese communist revolutionary and one of the most influential leaders of the People's Republic of China during the 1940s and 1950s. He was one of the major military leaders of China during the Chinese Civil War along with Mao Zedong, Zhou Enlai, Peng Dehuai and Lin Biao.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Li Jingquan</span> Chinese politician (1908–1989)

Li Jingquan was a Chinese politician and the first Party Committee Secretary (governor) of Sichuan following the establishment of the People's Republic of China in 1949. He supported many of Mao Zedong's policies including the Great Leap Forward.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Land Reform Movement</span> Chinese campaign led by Mao Zedong (1946–1953)

The Land Reform Movement, also known by the Chinese abbreviation Tǔgǎi (土改), was a mass movement led by the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) leader Mao Zedong during the late phase of the Chinese Civil War after the Second Sino-Japanese War ended in 1945 and in the early People's Republic of China, which achieved land redistribution to the peasantry. Landlords – whose status was theoretically defined through the percentage of income derived from exploitation as opposed to labor – had their land confiscated and they were subjected to mass killing by the CCP and former tenants, with the estimated death toll ranging from hundreds of thousands to millions. The campaign resulted in hundreds of millions of peasants receiving a plot of land for the first time.

The 1st Five-Year Plan was the first five-year plan adopted by the People's Republic of China after its establishment in 1949. It lasted from 1953 until 1957.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Beidaihe Conference (1958)</span>

The Beidaihe Conference of 1958 was an enlarged meeting held by the Politburo of the Chinese Communist Party Central Committee from August 17 to 30 1958. It also involved a conference of provincial industrial secretaries and other relevant local leaders from the 25th to the 31st.

References

  • Chisholm, Hugh, ed. (1911). "Co-operation"  . Encyclopædia Britannica (11th ed.). Cambridge University Press.
  • Clegg, Jenny (2008). "Reforming China's Cooperative Economy: Issues and Experiences". In Harvie, Charles; Lee, Boon-Chye (eds.). Small and Medium Sized Enterprises in East Asia: Sectoral and Regional Dimensions. Small and Medium Sized Enterprises in East Asia. Edward Elgar. pp. 177–193. ISBN   978-1-84064-809-6.
  • Clegg, Jenny (2012). "Mass- and Elite-Based Strategies for Cooperative Development in Wartime Nationalist China: Western Views on the 'Gung Ho' Industrial Cooperative Experience". European Journal of East Asian Studies. 11 (2): 305–327. doi:10.1163/15700615-20121109. JSTOR   23615461.
  • Eyferth, Jacob (2009). Eating Rice from Bamboo Roots: The Social History of a Community of Handicraft Papermakers in Rural Sichuan, 1920–2000. Harvard East Asian Monographs. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. ISBN   978-0-674-03288-0.
  • Fitzgerald, John (1997). "Warlords, Bullies, and State Building in Nationalist China: The Guangdong Cooperative Movement, 1932–1936". Modern China. 23 (4): 420–458. doi:10.1177/009770049702300403. JSTOR   189394. S2CID   146794107.
  • Jossa, Bruno (2005). "Marx, Marxism and the Cooperative Movement". Cambridge Journal of Economics. 29 (1): 3–18. doi:10.1093/cje/bei012. JSTOR   23603445.
  • Keating, Pauline (1994). "The Yan'an Way of Co-Operativization". The China Quarterly. 140 (140): 1025–1051. doi:10.1017/S0305741000052899. JSTOR   655193. S2CID   154894595.
  • Lai, Cheng-chung (1989). "The Structure and Characteristics of the Chinese Co-operative System: 1928-49". International Journal of Social Economics. 16 (2): 59–66. doi:10.1108/03068298910133052.
  • Mao, Zedong (1939). "The Chinese Revolution and the Chinese Communist Party". Marxists Internet Archive (published 2004). Retrieved 2022-06-11.
  • Nathan, Andrew James (1965). A History of the China International Famine Relief Commission. Harvard East Asian Monographs. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
  • "Our history". International Cooperative Alliance. Retrieved 2022-06-08.
  • Reynolds, Douglas (1975). The Chinese Industrial Cooperative Movement And The Political Polarization Of Wartime China, 1938–1945 (PhD). Columbia University.
  • Schran, Peter (1964). "Handicrafts in Communist China". The China Quarterly. 17 (17): 151–173. doi:10.1017/S0305741000041722. JSTOR   3451147. S2CID   154328123.
  • Shue, Vivienne (1980). Peasant China in Transition: The Dynamics of Development toward Socialism, 1949–1956. Berkeley: University of California Press. ISBN   0520037340.
  • Stettner, Nora; Oram, Bert (1987). Changes in China: The Role of Co-Operatives in the New Socialism. Manchester: Holyoake Books. ISBN   0851951481.
  • Teiwes, Frederick C.; Sun, Warren, eds. (1993). The Politics of Agricultural Cooperativization in China: Mao, Deng Zihui, and the "High Tide" of 1955. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. ISBN   1-56324-382-2.
  • Zanasi, Margherita (2007). "Exporting Development: The League of Nations and Republican China". Comparative Studies in Society and History. 49 (1): 143–169. doi:10.1017/S0010417507000436. JSTOR   4497685. S2CID   146430784.
Mutual Aid Team
Simplified Chinese 互助组
Traditional Chinese 互助組