Internationalization

Last updated

In economics, internationalization or internationalisation is the process of increasing involvement of enterprises in international markets, although there is no agreed definition of internationalization. [1] Internationalization is a crucial strategy not only for companies that seek horizontal integration globally but also for countries that addresses the sustainability of its development in different manufacturing as well as service sectors especially in higher education which is a very important context that needs internationalization to bridge the gap between different cultures and countries. [2] There are several internationalization theories which try to explain why there are international activities.

Contents

Entrepreneurs and enterprises

Those entrepreneurs who are interested in the field of internationalization of business need to possess the ability to think globally and have an understanding of international cultures. By appreciating and understanding different beliefs, values, behaviors and business strategies of a variety of companies within other countries, entrepreneurs will be able to internationalize successfully. Entrepreneurs must also have an ongoing concern for innovation, maintaining a high level of quality, be committed to corporate social responsibility, and continue to strive to provide the best business strategies and either goods or services possible while adapting to different countries and cultures.

Trade theories

Absolute cost advantage (Adam Smith, 1776)

Adam Smith claimed that a country should specialise in, and export, commodities in which it had an absolute advantage. [3] An absolute advantage existed when the country could produce a commodity with less costs per unit produced than could its trading partner. [3] By the same reasoning, it should import commodities in which it had an absolute disadvantage. [3]

While there are possible gains from trade with absolute advantage, comparative advantage extends the range of possible mutually beneficial exchanges. In other words, it is not necessary to have an absolute advantage to gain from trade, only a comparative advantage.

Comparative cost advantage (David Ricardo, 1817)

David Ricardo argued that a country does not need to have an absolute advantage in the production of any commodity for international trade between it and another country to be mutually beneficial. [4] Absolute advantage meant greater efficiency in production, or the use of less labor factor in production. [4] Two countries could both benefit from trade if each had a relative advantage in production. [4] Relative advantage simply meant that the ratio of the labor embodied in the two commodities differed between two countries, such that each country would have at least one commodity where the relative amount of labor embodied would be less than that of the other country. [4]

Gravity model of trade (Walter Isard, 1954)

The gravity model of trade in international economics, similar to other gravity models in social science, predicts bilateral trade flows based on the economic sizes of (often using GDP measurements) and distance between two units. The basic theoretical model for trade between two countries takes the form of:

with:

: Trade flow
: Country i and j
: Economic mass, for example GDP
: Distance
: Constant

The model has also been used in international relations to evaluate the impact of treaties and alliances on trade, and it has been used to test the effectiveness of trade agreements and organizations such as the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and the World Trade Organization (WTO).

Heckscher–Ohlin model (Eli Heckscher, 1966 & Bertil Ohlin, 1952)

The Heckscher–Ohlin model (H–O model), also known as the factors proportions development, is a general equilibrium mathematical model of international trade, developed by Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin at the Stockholm School of Economics. It builds on David Ricardo's theory of comparative advantage by predicting patterns of commerce and production based on the factor endowments of a trading region. The model essentially says that countries will export products that utilize their abundant and cheap factor(s) of production and import products that utilize the countries' scarce factor(s). [5]

The results of this work have been the formulation of certain named conclusions arising from the assumptions inherent in the model. These are known as:

Leontief paradox (Wassily Leontief, 1954)

Leontief's paradox in economics is that the country with the world's highest capital-per worker has a lower capital:labour ratio in exports than in imports.

This econometric find was the result of Professor Wassily W. Leontief's attempt to test the Heckscher-Ohlin theory empirically. In 1954, Leontief found that the U.S. (the most capital-abundant country in the world by any criteria) exported labor-intensive commodities and imported capital-intensive commodities, in contradiction with Heckscher-Ohlin theory.

Linder hypothesis (Staffan Burenstam Linder, 1961)

The Linder hypothesis (demand-structure hypothesis) is a conjecture in economics about international trade patterns. The hypothesis is that the more similar are the demand structures of countries the more they will trade with one another. Further, international trade will still occur between two countries having identical preferences and factor endowments (relying on specialization to create a comparative advantage in the production of differentiated goods between the two nations).

Location theory

Location theory is concerned with the geographic location of economic activity; it has become an integral part of economic geography, regional science, and spatial economics. Location theory addresses the questions of what economic activities are located where and why. Location theory rests like microeconomic theory generally on the assumption that agents act in their own self-interest. Thus firms choose locations that maximize their profits and individuals choose locations, that maximize their utility.

Market imperfection theory (Stephen Hymer, 1976 & Charles P. Kindleberger, 1969 & Richard E. Caves, 1971)

In economics, a market failure is a situation wherein the allocation of production or use of goods and services by the free market is not efficient. Market failures can be viewed as scenarios where individuals' pursuit of pure self-interest leads to results that can be improved upon from the societal point of view. [6] The first known use of the term by economists was in 1958, [7] but the concept has been traced back to the Victorian philosopher Henry Sidgwick. [8]

Market imperfection can be defined as anything that interferes with trade. [9] This includes two dimensions of imperfections. [9] First, imperfections cause a rational market participant to deviate from holding the market portfolio. [9] Second, imperfections cause a rational market participant to deviate from his preferred risk level. [9] Market imperfections generate costs which interfere with trades that rational individuals make (or would make in the absence of the imperfection). [9]

The idea that multinational corporations (MNEs) owe their existence to market imperfections was first put forward by Stephen Hymer, Charles P. Kindleberger and Caves. [10] The market imperfections they had in mind were, however, structural imperfections in markets for final products. [11]

According to Hymer, market imperfections are structural, arising from structural deviations from perfect competition in the final product market due to exclusive and permanent control of proprietary technology, privileged access to inputs, scale economies, control of distribution systems, and product differentiation, [12] but in their absence markets are perfectly efficient. [11]

By contrast, the insight of transaction costs theories of the MNEs, simultaneously and independently developed in the 1970s by McManus (1972), Buckley and Casson (1976), Brown (1976) and Hennart (1977, 1982), is that market imperfections are inherent attributes of markets, and MNEs are institutions to bypass these imperfections. [11] Markets experience natural imperfections, i.e. imperfections that are because the implicit neoclassical assumptions of perfect knowledge and perfect enforcement are not realized. [13]

New Trade Theory

New Trade Theory (NTT) is the economic critique of international free trade from the perspective of increasing returns to scale and the network effect. Some economists have asked whether it might be effective for a nation to shelter infant industries until they had grown to a sufficient size large enough to compete internationally.

New Trade theorists challenge the assumption of diminishing returns to scale, and some argue that using protectionist measures to build up a huge industrial base in certain industries will then allow those sectors to dominate the world market (via a network effect).

Specific factors model

In this model, labour mobility between industries is possible while capital is immobile between industries in the short-run. Thus, this model can be interpreted as a 'short run' version of the Heckscher-Ohlin model.

Traditional approaches

The Porter diamond The Porter Diamond.svg
The Porter diamond

Diamond model (Michael Porter)

The diamond model is an economical model developed by Michael Porter in his book The Competitive Advantage of Nations, where he published his theory of why particular industries become competitive in particular locations. [15]

The diamond model consists of six factors: [15]

The Porter thesis is that these factors interact with each other to create conditions where innovation and improved competitiveness occurs. [15]

Diffusion of innovations (Rogers, 1962)

Diffusion of innovation is a theory of how, why, and at what rate new ideas and technology spread through cultures. Everett Rogers introduced it in his 1962 book, Diffusion of Innovations, writing that "Diffusion is the process by which an innovation is communicated through certain channels over time among the members of a social system." [16]

Eclectic paradigm (John H. Dunning)

The eclectic paradigm is a theory in economics and is also known as the OLI-Model. [17] [18] It is a further development of the theory of internalization and published by John H. Dunning in 1993. [19] The theory of internalization itself is based on the transaction cost theory. [19] This theory says that transactions are made within an institution if the transaction costs on the free market are higher than the internal costs. This process is called internalization. [19]

For Dunning, not only the structure of organization is important. [19] He added three additional factors to the theory: [19]

Foreign direct investment theory

Foreign direct investment (FDI) in its classic form is defined as a company from one country making a physical investment into building a factory in another country. It is the establishment of an enterprise by a foreigner. [20] Its definition can be extended to include investments made to acquire lasting interest in enterprises operating outside of the economy of the investor. [21] The FDI relationship consists of a parent enterprise and a foreign affiliate which together form a multinational corporation (MNC). In order to qualify as FDI the investment must afford the parent enterprise control over its foreign affiliate. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) defines control in this case as owning 10% or more of the ordinary shares or voting power of an incorporated firm or its equivalent for an unincorporated firm; lower ownership shares are known as portfolio investment. [22]

Monopolistic advantage theory (Stephen Hymer)

The monopolistic advantage theory is an approach in international business which explains why firms can compete in foreign settings against indigenous competitors [23] and is frequently associated with the seminal contribution of Stephen Hymer. [24]

Prior to Stephen Hymer’s doctoral thesis, The International Operations of National Firms: A Study of foreign direct Investment, theories did not adequately explain why firms engaged in foreign operations. Hymer started his research by analyzing the motivations behind foreign investment of US corporations in other countries. Neoclassical theories, dominant at the time, explained foreign direct investments as capital movements across borders based on perceived benefits from interest rates in other markets, there was no need to separate them from any other kind of investment (Ietto-Guilles, 2012).

He effectively differentiated Foreign Direct Investment and portfolio investments by including the notion of control of foreign firms to FDI Theory, which implies control of the operation; whilst portfolio foreign investment confers a share of ownership but not control. Stephen Hymer focused on and considered FDI and MNE as part of the theory of the firm. (Hymer, 1976: 21)

He also dismissed the assumption that FDIs are motivated by the search of low costs in foreign countries, by emphasizing the fact that local firms are not able to compete effectively against foreign firms, even though they have to face foreign barriers (cultural, political, lingual etc.) to market entry. He suggested that firms invest in foreign countries in order to maximize their specific firm advantages in imperfect markets, that is, markets where the flow of information is uneven and allows companies to benefit from a competitive advantage over the local competition.

Stephen Hymer also suggested a second determinant for firms engaging in foreign operations, removal of conflicts. When a rival company is operating in a foreign market or is willing to enter one, a conflict situation arises. Through FDI, a multinational can share or take complete control of foreign production, effectively removing conflict. This will lead to the increase of market power for the specific firm, increasing imperfections in the market as a whole (Ietto-Guilles, 2012)

A final determinant for multinationals making direct investments is the distribution of risk through diversification. By choosing different markets and production locations, the risk inherent to foreign operations are spread and reduced.

All of these motivations for FDI are built on market imperfections and conflict. A firm engaging in direct investment could then reduce competition, eliminate the conflicts and exploit the firm specific advantages making them capable of succeeding in a foreign market.

Stephen Hymer can be considered the father of international business because he effectively studied multinationals from a different perspective than the existing literature, by approaching multinationals as national companies with international operations, regarded as expansions from home operations. He analyzed the activities of the MNEs and their impact on the economy, gave an explanation for the large flow of foreign investments by US corporations at a time where they were incomplete, and envisioned the ethical conflicts that could arise from the increase in power of MNEs.

Non-availability approach (Irving B. Kravis, 1956)

The non-availability explains international trade by the fact that each country imports the goods that are not available at home. [25] This unavailability may be due to lack of natural resources (oil, gold, etc.: this is absolute unavailability) or to the fact that the goods cannot be produced domestically, or could only be produced at prohibitive costs (for technological or other reasons): this is relative unavailability. [26] On the other hand, each country exports the goods that are available at home. [26]

Technology gap theory of trade (Michael Posner)

The technology gap theory describes an advantage enjoyed by the country that introduces new goods in a market. As a consequence of research activity and entrepreneurship, new goods are produced and the innovating country enjoys a monopoly until the other countries learn to produce these goods: in the meantime they have to import them. Thus, international trade is created for the time necessary to imitate the new goods (imitation lag). [25]

Uppsala model

The Uppsala model [27] is a theory that explains how firms gradually intensify their activities in foreign markets. [28] It is similar to the POM model. [29] The key features of both models are the following: firms first gain experience from the domestic market before they move to foreign markets; firms start their foreign operations from culturally and/or geographically close countries and move gradually to culturally and geographically more distant countries; firms start their foreign operations by using traditional exports and gradually move to using more intensive and demanding operation modes (sales subsidiaries etc.) both at the company and target country level. [30]

Updated Uppsala model

The Updated Uppsala model [31] is a further progression of the original Uppsala model. Like the Uppsala model, the Updated Uppsala model is a theory that explains firm internationalization as a process of gradual commitment. However, instead of an increased commitment to other markets, the theory posits that firms commit to business networks. [32] Firms thereby utilize the established relationships with other firms to internationalize within their network, e.g. by localizing production at a foreign production site of the client. [33]

Learning portal model

The Learning Portal Model [34] is a new theory that was originally developed to explain the emergence and catch-up of multinational firms from the emerging markets. The theory explains that latecomer firms (from both, advanced and emerging markets) can use springboarding strategies to leapfrog certain technological development stages and accelerate their catch‐up with incumbent leading firms in their industry. To do so, the catching-up firms establish learning portals in knowledge hubs to acquire knowledge and assets, which they exploit to compete in global markets.

Further theories

Contingency theory

Contingency theory refers to any of a number of management theories. Several contingency approaches were developed concurrently in the late 1960s. They suggested that previous theories such as Weber's bureaucracy and Frederick Winslow Taylor's scientific management had failed because they neglected that management style and organizational structure were influenced by various aspects of the environment: the contingency factors. There could not be "one best way" for leadership or organization.

Contract theory

In economics, contract theory studies how economic actors can and do construct contractual arrangements, generally in the presence of asymmetric information. Contract theory is closely connected to the field of law and economics. One prominent field of application is managerial compensation.

Economy of scale

Economies of scale, in microeconomics, are the cost advantages that a business obtains due to expansion. They are factors that cause a producer’s average cost per unit to fall as output rises. [35] Diseconomies of scale are the opposite. Economies of scale may be utilized by any size firm expanding its scale of operation.

Internalisation theory (Peter J. Buckley & Mark Casson, 1976; Rugman, 1981)

Product life-cycle theory

As first articulated by Raymond Vernon in 1966, a product goes through a life cycle consisting of four stages: "new product", "growth product", "maturity product" and "obsolescence product". The conditions in which a product is sold change over time and must be managed as it moves through this succession of stages. This is called product life cycle management. [36]

Transaction cost theory

The theory of the firm consists of a number of economic theories which describe the nature of the firm, company, or corporation, including its existence, its behaviour, and its relationship with the market.

Ronald Coase set out his transaction cost theory of the firm in 1937, making it one of the first (neo-classical) attempts to define the firm theoretically in relation to the market. [37] Coase sets out to define a firm in a manner which is both realistic and compatible with the idea of substitution at the margin, so instruments of conventional economic analysis apply. He notes that a firm’s interactions with the market may not be under its control (for instance because of sales taxes), but its internal allocation of resources are: “Within a firm, ... market transactions are eliminated and in place of the complicated market structure with exchange transactions is substituted the entrepreneur ... who directs production.” He asks why alternative methods of production (such as the price mechanism and economic planning), could not either achieve all production, so that either firms use internal prices for all their production, or one big firm runs the entire economy.

Theory of the growth of the firm (Edith Penrose, 1959)

While at Johns Hopkins, Penrose participated in a research project on the growth of firms. She came to the conclusion that the existing theory of the firm was inadequate to explain how firms grow. Her insight was to realise that the 'Firm' in theory is not the same thing as 'flesh and blood' organizations that businessmen call firms. This insight eventually led to the publication of her second book, The Theory of the Growth of the Firm in 1959.

See also

Related Research Articles

Comparative advantage in an economic model is the advantage over others in producing a particular good. A good can be produced at a lower relative opportunity cost or autarky price, i.e. at a lower relative marginal cost prior to trade. Comparative advantage describes the economic reality of the gains from trade for individuals, firms, or nations, which arise from differences in their factor endowments or technological progress.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Bertil Ohlin</span> Swedish economist and politician (1899–1979)

Bertil Gotthard Ohlin was a Swedish economist and politician. He was a professor of economics at the Stockholm School of Economics from 1929 to 1965. He was also leader of the People's Party, a social-liberal party which at the time was the largest party in opposition to the governing Social Democratic Party, from 1944 to 1967. He served briefly as Minister of Commerce and Industry from 1944 to 1945 in the Swedish coalition government during World War II. He was President of the Nordic Council in 1959 and 1964.

This is a list of international trade topics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Foreign direct investment</span> Purchase of an asset

A foreign direct investment (FDI) refers to purchase of an asset in another country, such that it gives direct control to the purchaser over the asset. In other words, it is an investment in the form of a controlling ownership in a business, in real estate or in productive assets such as factories in one country by an entity based in another country. It is thus distinguished from a foreign portfolio investment or foreign indirect investment by a notion of direct control.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Heckscher–Ohlin model</span> Economic model for international trade

The Heckscher–Ohlin model is a general equilibrium mathematical model of international trade, developed by Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin at the Stockholm School of Economics. It builds on David Ricardo's theory of comparative advantage by predicting patterns of commerce and production based on the resources of a trading region. The model essentially says that countries export the products which use their relatively abundant and cheap factors of production, and import the products which use the countries' relatively scarce factors.

New trade theory (NTT) is a collection of economic models in international trade theory which focuses on the role of increasing returns to scale and network effects, which were originally developed in the late 1970s and early 1980s. The main motivation for the development of NTT was that, contrary to what traditional trade models would suggest, the majority of the world trade takes place between countries that are similar in terms of development, structure, and factor endowments.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Heckscher–Ohlin theorem</span> Macroeconomic trade theorem

The Heckscher–Ohlin theorem is one of the four critical theorems of the Heckscher–Ohlin model, developed by Swedish economist Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin. In the two-factor case, it states: "A capital-abundant country will export the capital-intensive good, while the labor-abundant country will export the labor-intensive good."

Intra-industry trade refers to the exchange of similar products belonging to the same industry. The term is usually applied to international trade, where the same types of goods or services are both imported and exported.

International business refers to the trade of Goods and service goods, services, technology, capital and/or knowledge across national borders and at a global or transnational scale.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Gravity model of trade</span> Bilateral trade flow model

The gravity model of international trade in international economics is a model that, in its traditional form, predicts bilateral trade flows based on the economic sizes and distance between two units. Research shows that there is "overwhelming evidence that trade tends to fall with distance."

Stephen Herbert Hymer was a Canadian economist. His research focused on the activities of multinational firms, which was the subject of his PhD dissertation The International Operations of National Firms: A Study of Direct Foreign Investment, presented in 1960, but published posthumously in 1976, by the Department of Economics from Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Charles P. Kindleberger, his thesis supervisor, submitted it for publication, as mentioned by him on the introduction of Hymer's thesis dissertation.

In international economics, international factor movements are movements of labor, capital, and other factors of production between countries. International factor movements occur in three ways: immigration/emigration, capital transfers through international borrowing and lending, and foreign direct investment. International factor movements also raise political and social issues not present in trade in goods and services. Nations frequently restrict immigration, capital flows, and foreign direct investment.

The Product Life Cycle Theory is an economic theory that was developed by Raymond Vernon in response to the failure of the Heckscher–Ohlin model to explain the observed pattern of international trade. The theory suggests that early in a product's life-cycle all the parts and labor associated with that product come from the area where it was invented. After the product becomes adopted and used in the world markets, production gradually moves away from the point of origin. In some situations, the product becomes an item that is imported by its original country of invention. A commonly used example of this is the invention, growth and production of the personal computer with respect to the United States.

The eclectic paradigm, also known as the OLI Model or OLI Framework, is a theory in economics. It is a further development of the internalization theory and published by John H. Dunning in 1979. Modern Trade Theory incorporates this paradigm using the Grossman-Hart-Moore Theory of the firm

International trade theory is a sub-field of economics which analyzes the patterns of international trade, its origins, and its welfare implications. International trade policy has been highly controversial since the 18th century. International trade theory and economics itself have developed as means to evaluate the effects of trade policies.

Internalization theory is a branch of economics that is used to analyse international business behaviour. Internalization theory focuses on imperfections in intermediate product markets. Two main kinds of intermediate product are distinguished: knowledge flows linking research and development (R&D) to production, and flows of components and raw materials from an upstream production facility to a downstream one. Most applications of the theory focus on knowledge flow. Proprietary knowledge is easier to appropriate when intellectual property rights such as patents and trademarks are weak. Even with strong protections firms protect their knowledge through secrecy. Instead of licensing their knowledge to independent local producers, firms exploit it themselves in their own production facilities. In effect, they internalise the market in knowledge within the firm. The theory claims the internalization leads to larger, more multinational enterprises, because knowledge is a public good. Development of a new technology is concentrated within the firm and the knowledge then transferred to other facilities.

The Reading School of International Business is widely understood in the field of international business (IB), management and economics to embody a stream of conceptual, and theoretically-driven empirical research, and consists of a group of economists that have a common approach to analyzing multinational enterprise and foreign direct investment. Some are based in the Department of Economics and in Henley Business School at the University of Reading, England, but membership is international. The Reading School builds upon the pathbreaking theoretical work of Peter Buckley and Mark Casson on internalization theory. This was complemented by simultaneous work by John Dunning as he developed the eclectic paradigm of international business as an envelope explanation containing three principal drivers of foreign direct investment, comprising ownership (O); location (L); and internalization (I). The Reading School approach continues through the work of its academic disciples around the world, as well as through The John Dunning Centre at Henley Business School, University of Reading, under the directorship of Rajneesh Narula.

The springboard theory or springboard perspective is an international business theory that elucidates the unique motives, processes and behaviors of international expansion of emerging market multinational enterprises. Springboard theory was developed by Luo and Tung (2007), and has since been used to examine EM MNEs. At the core of this theory is the argument that EM MNEs systematically and recursively use international expansion as a springboard to acquire critical resources needed to compete more effectively against their global rivals at home and abroad and to reduce their vulnerability to institutional and market constraints at home. These efforts are systematic in the sense that “springboard” steps are deliberately designed as a grand plan to facilitate firm growth and as a long-range strategy to establish more solidly their competitive positions in the global marketplace. They are also recursive because such “springboard” activities are recurrent and revolving.

Thierry Mayer is a French economist and Professor of Economics at Sciences Po. He belongs to the most frequently-cited economists in the field of international trade. In 2006, Mayer and Etienne Wasmer were awarded the Best Young Economist of France Award by Cercle des économistes and Le Monde.

Kevin Iyk Ibeh is a British-Nigerian academic, author and speaker. He is the Pro Vice-Chancellor (International) at Birkbeck, University of London, and a Commissioner of the Commonwealth Scholarship Commission. He is most known for his work on firm internationalization and developing economies, as well as his work on how non-dominant firms, including small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) and entrepreneurial firms, capitalize on growth opportunities internationally. Among his authored works are publications in academic journals, including Journal of World Business, Journal of Business Ethics, British Journal of Management, Journal of Business Research, International Business Review, and European Journal of Marketing as well as books such as Contemporary Challenges to International Business and Growth Frontiers in International Business.

References

  1. Susman, Gerald I. (2007). Small and Medium-sized Enterprises and the Global Economy. Young et al., 2003. Edward Elgar Publishing. p. 281. ISBN   978-1-84542-595-1.
  2. Adel, H. M.; Zeinhom, G. A.; Mahrous, A. A. (2018). "Effective management of an internationalization strategy: A case study on Egyptian–British universities' partnerships". International Journal of Technology Management & Sustainable Development. 17 (2): 183–202. doi:10.1386/tmsd.17.2.183_1. S2CID   159384176.
  3. 1 2 3 Ingham, Barbara (2004). International economics: a European focus. Pearson Education. p. 336. ISBN   0-273-65507-8.
  4. 1 2 3 4 Hunt, E. K. (2002). History of economic thought: A critical perspective. M.E. Sharpe. p. 120. ISBN   0-7656-0607-0.
  5. Blaug, Mark (1992). The methodology of economics, or, How economists explain. Cambridge University Press. p. 190. ISBN   0-521-43678-8.
  6. Krugman, Paul, Wells, Robin, Economics, Worth Publishers, New York, (2006)
  7. Bator, Francis M. (August 1958). "The Anatomy of Market Failure". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 72 (3). The MIT Press: 351–379. doi:10.2307/1882231. JSTOR   1882231.
  8. Medema, Steven G. (July 2004). "Mill, Sidgwick, and the Evolution of the Theory of Market Failure" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2007-09-27. Retrieved 2007-06-23.
  9. 1 2 3 4 5 DeGennaro, Ramon P. (December 2005). "Market Imperfections" (PDF). Working Paper. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta - Working Paper Series. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2010-04-01. Retrieved 2009-03-17.
  10. Pitelis, Christos; Roger Sugden (2000). The nature of the transnational firm. Hymer (1960, published in 1976), Kindleberger (1969) & Caves (1971). Routledge. p. 74. ISBN   0-415-16787-6.
  11. 1 2 3 Pitelis, Christos; Roger Sugden (2000). The nature of the transnational firm. Routledge. p. 224. ISBN   0-415-16787-6.
  12. Pitelis, Christos; Roger Sugden (2000). The nature of the transnational firm. Bain (1956). Routledge. p. 74. ISBN   0-415-16787-6.
  13. Pitelis, Christos; Roger Sugden (2000). The nature of the transnational firm. Dunning & Rugman (1985), Teece (1981). Routledge. p. 74. ISBN   0-415-16787-6.
  14. Traill, Bruce; Eamonn Pitts (1998). Competitiveness in the Food Industry. Porter (1990, p. 127). Springer. p. 19. ISBN   0-7514-0431-4.
  15. 1 2 3 Traill, Bruce; Eamonn Pitts (1998). Competitiveness in the Food Industry. Springer. p. 301. ISBN   0-7514-0431-4.
  16. Rogers, Everett M. (2003).Diffusion of Innovations, 5th ed.. New York, NY: Free Press.
  17. 1 2 Hagen, Antje (1997). Deutsche Direktinvestitionen in Grossbritannien, 1871–1918 (Dissertation) (in German). Jena: Franz Steiner Verlag. p. 32. ISBN   3-515-07152-0.
  18. 1 2 3 4 Twomey, Michael J. (2000). A Century of Foreign Investment in the Third World (Book). Routledge. p. 8. ISBN   0-415-23360-7.
  19. 1 2 3 4 5 Falkenhahn, Alexander; Roman Stanslowski (2001-11-27). "Das Eklektische Paradigma des John Dunning" (PDF). Seminar paper (in German). Retrieved 2009-02-19.[ permanent dead link ]
  20. O'Sullivan, Arthur; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003). Economics: Principles in Action . Upper Saddle River, New Jersey 07458: Pearson Prentice Hall. p.  551. ISBN   0-13-063085-3.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location (link)
  21. Foreign Direct Investment, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, www.unctad.org
  22. International Monetary Fund, 1993. Balance of Payments Manual, fifth edition (Washington, D.C.)
  23. Bürgel, Oliver (2000). The internationalisation of British start-up companies in high-technology industries. Springer (Zentrum für Europäische Wirtschaftsforschung). p. 48. ISBN   3-7908-1292-7.
  24. Bürgel, Oliver (2000). The internationalisation of British start-up companies in high-technology industries. Hymer (1976); Hymer's original thesis was completed in 1960, but it was only after his death, in 1976, that it was published by the MIT. By that time, his ideas had already found widespread acceptance. Springer (Zentrum für Europäische Wirtschaftsforschung). p. 48. ISBN   3-7908-1292-7.
  25. 1 2 Gandolfo, Giancarlo (1998). International Trade Theory and Policy: With 12 Tables. Irving B. Kravis (1956). Springer. pp. 233–234. ISBN   3-540-64316-8.
  26. 1 2 Gandolfo, Giancarlo (1998). International Trade Theory and Policy: With 12 Tables. Springer. p. 544. ISBN   3-540-64316-8.
  27. Elgar, Edward (2003). Learning in the Internationalisation Process of Firms. Johanson & Wiedersheim-Paul (1975), Johanson & Vahlne (1977). p. 261. ISBN   1-84064-662-4 . Retrieved 2009-03-21.
  28. Blomstermo, Anders; Dharma Deo Sharma (2003). Learning in the internationalisation process of firms. Edward Elgar. pp. 36–53. ISBN   978-1-84064-662-7.
  29. Elgar, Edward (2003). Learning in the Internationalisation Process of Firms. Luostarinen (1979). p. 261. ISBN   1-84064-662-4 . Retrieved 2009-03-21.
  30. Elgar, Edward (2003). Learning in the Internationalisation Process of Firms. p. 261. ISBN   1-84064-662-4 . Retrieved 2009-03-21.
  31. Johanson, J.; Vahlne, J.-E. (2009). "The Uppsala internationalization process model revisited: From liability of foreignness to liability of outsidership". Journal of International Business Studies. 40 (9): 1411–1431. doi:10.1057/jibs.2009.24. S2CID   17711333 . Retrieved April 29, 2021.
  32. Johanson, J.; Vahlne, J.-E. (2013). "The Uppsala model on evolution of the multinational business enterprise: From internalization to coordination of networks". International Marketing Review. 30 (3): 189–210. doi:10.1108/02651331311321963 . Retrieved April 29, 2021.
  33. Hertenstein, P.; Sutherland, D.; Anderson, J. (2017). "Internationalization within networks: Exploring the relationship between inward and outward FDI in China's auto components industry". Asia Pacific Journal of Management. 34: 69–96. doi:10.1007/s10490-015-9422-3. S2CID   55924013 . Retrieved April 29, 2021.
  34. Hertenstein, P.; Alon, I. (2021). "A learning portal model of emerging markets multinationals". Global Strategy Journal. 12: 134–162. doi: 10.1002/gsj.1400 .
  35. O'Sullivan, Arthur; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003). Economics: Principles in Action . Upper Saddle River, New Jersey 07458: Pearson Prentice Hall. p.  157. ISBN   0-13-063085-3.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location (link)
  36. Vernon, Raymond (1966). "International Investment and International Trade in the Product Cycle. in: Quarterly Journal of Economics". Quarterly Journal of Economics. Cambridge: 191. ISSN   0033-5533.[ permanent dead link ]
  37. Coase, Ronald H., "The Nature of the Firm", Economica 4, pp 386–405, 1937.