Job guarantee

Last updated

Eleanor Roosevelt onsite one of the Works Progress Administration Projects, a job guarantee program in the United States Eleanor Roosevelt at Works Progress Administration site in Des Moines, Iowa - NARA - 195991.jpg
Eleanor Roosevelt onsite one of the Works Progress Administration Projects, a job guarantee program in the United States

A job guarantee is an economic policy proposal that aims to create full employment and price stability by having the state promise to hire unemployed workers as an employer of last resort (ELR). [1] It aims to provide a sustainable solution to inflation and unemployment.

Contents

The economic policy stance currently dominant around the world uses unemployment as a policy tool to control inflation. When inflation rises, the government pursues contractionary fiscal or monetary policy, with the aim of creating a buffer stock of unemployed people, reducing wage demands, and ultimately inflation. [2] When inflationary expectations subside, expansionary policy aims to produce the opposite effect.

By contrast, in a job guarantee program, a buffer stock of employed people (employed in the job guarantee program) is typically intended to provide the same protection against inflation without the social costs of unemployment, hence potentially fulfilling the dual mandate of full employment and price stability. [1]

Overview

A job guarantee is based on a buffer stock principle whereby the public sector offers a fixed wage job to anyone willing and able to work thereby establishing and maintaining a buffer stock of employed workers. [2] This buffer stock expands when private sector activity declines, and declines when private sector activity expands, much like today's unemployed buffer stocks.

A job guarantee thus fulfills an absorption function to minimize the real costs associated with the flux of the private sector. When private sector employment declines, public sector employment will automatically react and increase its payrolls. So in a recession, the increase in public employment will increase net government spending, and stimulate aggregate demand and the economy. Conversely, in a boom, the decline of public sector employment and spending caused by workers leaving their job guarantee jobs for higher paid private sector employment will lessen stimulation, so the job guarantee functions as an automatic stabilizer controlling inflation. The nation always remains fully employed, with a changing mix between private and public sector employment. Since the job guarantee wage is open to everyone, it will functionally become the national minimum wage. [3]

Under a job guarantee, people of working age who are not in full-time education and have less than 35 hours per week of paid employment would be entitled to the balance of 35 hours paid employment, undertaking work of public benefit at the minimum wage, though specifics may change depending on the model. The aim is to replace unemployment and underemployment with paid employment (up to the hours desired by workers), so that those who are at any point in time surplus to the requirements of the private sector (and mainstream public sector) can earn a wage rather than be underemployed or suffer poverty and social exclusion. [4]

A range of income support arrangements, including a generic work-tested benefit payment, could also be available to unemployed people, depending on their circumstances, as an initial subsistence income while arrangements are made to employ them.[ citation needed ]

Job guarantee theory is often associated with certain post-Keynesian economists, [5] particularly at the Centre of Full Employment and Equity (University of Newcastle, Australia), at the Levy Economics Institute (Bard College), and at University of Missouri – Kansas City including the affiliated Center for Full Employment and Price Stability. [6]

One theory was put forward by Hyman Minsky in 1965. [7] [8] Notable job guarantee theories were conceived independently by Bill Mitchell (1998), [9] and Warren Mosler (1997–98). [10] This work was then developed further by L. Randall Wray (1998). [11] A comprehensive treatment of it appears in Mitchell and Muysken (2008). [12]

Inflation control

A fixed job guarantee wage provides an in-built inflation control mechanism. Mitchell (1998) called the ratio of job guarantee employment to total employment the buffer employment ratio (BER). [13] The BER conditions the overall rate of wage demands. When the BER is high, real wage demands will be correspondingly lower. If inflation exceeds the government's announced target, tighter fiscal and monetary policy would be triggered to increase the BER, which entails workers transferring from the inflating sector to the fixed price job guarantee sector. [13] Ultimately this attenuates the inflation spiral. So instead of a buffer stock of unemployed being used to discipline the distributional struggle, a job guarantee policy achieves this via compositional shifts in employment.

Replacing the currently widely-used measure the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU), the BER that results in stable inflation is called the non-accelerating inflation buffer employment ratio (NAIBER). [13] It is a full employment steady state job guarantee level, which is dependent on a range of factors including the path of the economy. There is an issue about the validity of an unchanging nominal anchor in an inflationary environment. [13] A job guarantee wage would be adjusted in line with productivity growth to avoid changing real relativities. Its viability as a nominal anchor relies on the fiscal authorities reining in any private wage-price pressures.

No relative wage effects

Mitchell and Muysken believe that a job guarantee introduces no relative wage effects and the rising demand does not necessarily invoke inflationary pressures because it is, by definition, satisfying the net savings desire of the private sector. [14] Additionally, in today's demand constrained economies, firms are likely to increase capacity utilisation to meet the higher sales volumes. Given that the demand impulse is less than required in the NAIRU economy, if there were any demand-pull inflation it would be lower under a job guarantee. [14] There are no new problems faced by employers who wish to hire labour to meet the higher sales levels. Any initial rise in demand will stimulate private sector employment growth while reducing job guarantee employment and spending. However, these demand pressures are unlikely to lead to accelerating inflation while the job guarantee pool contains workers employable by the private sector. [14]

Wage bargaining

While a job guarantee policy frees wage bargaining from the general threat of unemployment, several factors offset this:

List of job guarantee programs

A billboard informing the public of the presence of Expanded Public Works Programme (EPWP) workers employed at the Groot Winterhoek Wilderness Area. The EPWP is an attempt by government to alleviate South Africa's unemployment crisis. Expanded Public Works Programme poster at the Groot Winterhoek Wilderness Area.jpg
A billboard informing the public of the presence of Expanded Public Works Programme (EPWP) workers employed at the Groot Winterhoek Wilderness Area. The EPWP is an attempt by government to alleviate South Africa's unemployment crisis.

Programs for adults

Programs for youth

Advocacy

The Labour Party under Ed Miliband went into the 2015 UK general election with a promise to implement a limited job guarantee (specifically, part-time jobs with guaranteed training included for long-term unemployed youth) if elected; [41] however, they lost the election.

Bernie Sanders supports a federal jobs guarantee for the United States and Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez included a jobs-guarantee program as one of her campaign pledges when she ran for, and won, her seat in the U.S. House of Representatives in 2018. [42] [43]

See also

Footnotes

  1. 1 2 Wray, L. Randall (23 August 2009). "Job Guarantee". New Economic Perspectives. Retrieved 31 July 2018.
  2. 1 2 corporateName=Commonwealth Parliament; address=Parliament House, Canberra. "Jobs Guarantee". www.aph.gov.au. Retrieved 6 April 2021.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  3. "Job Guarantee -". 9 October 2014. Retrieved 6 April 2021.
  4. Tcherneva, Pavlina R. (2018). "The Job Guarantee: Design, Jobs, and Implementation". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3155289. hdl: 10419/209145 . ISSN   1556-5068. S2CID   169092426.
  5. Wray, L. Randall (August 2001), The Endogenous Money Approach, Center for Full Employment and Price Stability, archived from the original on 15 March 2017, retrieved 5 October 2009
  6. Center for Full Employment and Price Stability
  7. ( Minsky 1965 )
  8. ( Wray 2009 )
  9. W.F. Mitchell (1998) "The Buffer Stock Employment Model - Full Employment without a NAIRU" Journal of Economic Issues 32(2), 547-55
  10. W.B. Mosler (1997-98) "Full Employment and Price Stability" Journal of Post Keynesian Economics , 20(2), 167-182
  11. L. Randall Wray (1998) Understanding Modern Money: The Key to Full Employment and Price Stability, Edward Elgar: Northampton, MA.
  12. W.F. Mitchell and J. Muysken (2008). Full Employment Abandoned: Shifting Sands and Policy failures Archived 22 February 2015 at the Wayback Machine ,. Edward Elgar: Cheltenham. Revised: January 2009 Archived 24 July 2011 at the Wayback Machine
  13. 1 2 3 4 http://www.fullemployment.net/publications/wp/2000/00-01.pdf [ bare URL PDF ]
  14. 1 2 3 http://pombo.free.fr/mitchellmuysken.pdf [ bare URL PDF ]
  15. Mitchell, William F. (June 1998). "The Buffer Stock Employment Model and the NAIRU: The Path to Full Employment". Journal of Economic Issues. 32 (2): 547–555. doi:10.1080/00213624.1998.11506063. ISSN   0021-3624.
  16. "Guaranteed Jobs: 46% Favor This New Dem Big Government Idea". Investor's Business Daily. 2 May 2018.
  17. Leighninger, Robert D. (2007). Long-Range Public Investment: The Forgotten Legacy of the New Deal. Columbia, S.C.: University of South Carolina Press. ISBN   9781570036637.
  18. Ellis, Luci (12 June 2019). "Watching the Invisibles". Reserve Bank of Australia.
  19. Australia, scheme=AGLSTERMS AglsAgent; corporateName=Reserve Bank of. "The Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment (NAIRU) | Explainer | Education". Reserve Bank of Australia. Retrieved 29 June 2023.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  20. "Universal Declaration of Human Rights - Human rights at your fingertips - Human rights at your fingertips | Australian Human Rights Commission". humanrights.gov.au. Retrieved 1 December 2022.
  21. Saulnier, Raymond J. (1977). "A Critique of the Humphrey Hawkins Bill". Business Horizons. 20: 20–24. doi:10.1016/0007-6813(77)90084-2.
  22. "Ministerio de Trabajo, Empleo y Seguridad Social". Ministerio de Trabajo, Empleo y Seguridad Social.
  23. Breitkreuz, Rhonda; Stanton, Carley-Jane; Brady, Nurmaiya; Pattison-Williams, John; King, E. D.; Mishra, Chudhury; Swallow, Brent (2017). "The Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme: A Policy Solution to Rural Poverty in India?". Development Policy Review. 35 (3): 397–417. doi: 10.1111/dpr.12220 . ISSN   1467-7679.
  24. Datta, Polly (2009). "Attaining Sustainable Rural Infrastructure through the National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme in India". Commonwealth Journal of Local Governance: 143–152. doi: 10.5130/cjlg.v0i4.1353 .
  25. "Expanded Public Works Programme". South African Government.
  26. "World's first universal jobs guarantee experiment starts in Austria | University of Oxford". www.ox.ac.uk. 2 November 2020. Retrieved 21 June 2023.
  27. Szigetvari, András (3 December 2022). "Pilotprojekt im Marienthal: Wie eine Jobgarantie des AMS das Leben verändert" [PIlot project in Marienthal: How a job guarantee of the AMS changes lives]. Der Standard (in German). Retrieved 28 December 2022.
  28. Kasy, Maximilian; Lehner, Lukas (April 2023). "Employing the Unemployed of Marienthal: Evaluation of a Guaranteed Job Program". Stone Center Working Paper Series (67). doi:10.2139/ssrn.4431385. hdl: 10419/272038 .
  29. "World's first universal job guarantee boosts wellbeing and eliminates…". INET Oxford. Retrieved 21 June 2023.
  30. Romeo, Nick (10 December 2022). "What Happens When Jobs Are Guaranteed?". The New Yorker. ISSN   0028-792X . Retrieved 21 June 2023.
  31. "Opinion Factsheet". cor.europa.eu. Retrieved 21 June 2023.
  32. "OECD". read.oecd-ilibrary.org. Retrieved 21 June 2023.
  33. Schutter, Olivier de; Rights, UN Human Rights Council Special Rapporteur on Extreme Poverty and Human (18 April 2023). "The employment guarantee as a tool in the fight against poverty :: report of the Special Rapporteur on Extreme Poverty and Human Rights, Olivier De Schutter".{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  34. Unit (JCPI), Job Creation through Public Investment (2 September 2021). "Public Employment Initiatives and the COVID-19 crisis". www.ilo.org. Retrieved 21 June 2023.
  35. Park, Jeong (3 March 2021). "Guaranteed work: California commission calls for government jobs program after pandemic". Sacramento Bee. Retrieved 3 February 2024.
  36. 1 2 "The Youth Guarantee". European Commission.
  37. ESCUDERO, VERÓNICA (August 2017). "The European Youth Guarantee: A systematic review of its implementation across countries" (PDF). International Labour Office Research Department Working Papers (21): 1.
  38. Hummeluhr, Niels (November 1997). "Youth guarantees in the Nordic countries" (PDF).{{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  39. ESCUDERO, VERÓNICA (August 2017). "The European Youth Guarantee: A systematic review of its implementation across countries" (PDF). International Labour Office Research Department Working Papers (21): 2.
  40. Pem, Damchoe (12 September 2015). "Guaranteed Employment Program going strong but can improve". The Bhutanese. Retrieved 3 February 2024.
  41. "Labour extends jobs guarantee for long-term unemployed". BBC News . 10 March 2014. Retrieved 6 January 2017.
  42. Paddison, Laura (6 July 2018). "What Is A Federal Jobs Guarantee?". HuffPost. Retrieved 3 March 2020.
  43. Goldstein, Steve (27 June 2018). "Jobs-guarantee idea gets new focus after Ocasio-Cortez victory". MarketWatch. Retrieved 4 March 2020.

Related Research Articles

A minimum wage is the lowest remuneration that employers can legally pay their employees—the price floor below which employees may not sell their labor. Most countries had introduced minimum wage legislation by the end of the 20th century. Because minimum wages increase the cost of labor, companies often try to avoid minimum wage laws by using gig workers, by moving labor to locations with lower or nonexistent minimum wages, or by automating job functions. Minimum wage policies can vary significantly between countries or even within a country, with different regions, sectors, or age groups having their own minimum wage rates. These variations are often influenced by factors such as the cost of living, regional economic conditions, and industry-specific factors.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Unemployment</span> People without work and actively seeking work

Unemployment, according to the OECD, is people above a specified age not being in paid employment or self-employment but currently available for work during the reference period.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Humphrey–Hawkins Full Employment Act</span> 1978 United States law requiring the Federal Reserve to perform certain functions

The Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act is an act of legislation by the United States government.

Full employment is a situation in which there is no cyclical or deficient-demand unemployment. Full employment does not entail the disappearance of all unemployment, as other kinds of unemployment, namely structural and frictional, may remain. For instance, workers who are "between jobs" for short periods of time as they search for better employment are not counted against full employment, as such unemployment is frictional rather than cyclical. An economy with full employment might also have unemployment or underemployment where part-time workers cannot find jobs appropriate to their skill level, as such unemployment is considered structural rather than cyclical. Full employment marks the point past which expansionary fiscal and/or monetary policy cannot reduce unemployment any further without causing inflation.

The Phillips curve is an economic model, named after Bill Phillips, that correlates reduced unemployment with increasing wages in an economy. While Phillips did not directly link employment and inflation, this was a trivial deduction from his statistical findings. Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow made the connection explicit and subsequently Milton Friedman and Edmund Phelps put the theoretical structure in place.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Underemployment</span> Underutilization of workers talents or skills in employment

Underemployment is the underuse of a worker because their job does not use their skills, offers them too few hours, or leaves the worker idle. It is contrasted with unemployment, where a person lacks a job at all despite wanting one.

The natural rate of unemployment is the name that was given to a key concept in the study of economic activity. Milton Friedman and Edmund Phelps, tackling this 'human' problem in the 1960s, both received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for their work, and the development of the concept is cited as a main motivation behind the prize. A simplistic summary of the concept is: 'The natural rate of unemployment, when an economy is in a steady state of "full employment", is the proportion of the workforce who are unemployed'. Put another way, this concept clarifies that the economic term "full employment" does not mean "zero unemployment". It represents the hypothetical unemployment rate consistent with aggregate production being at the "long-run" level. This level is consistent with aggregate production in the absence of various temporary frictions such as incomplete price adjustment in labor and goods markets. The natural rate of unemployment therefore corresponds to the unemployment rate prevailing under a classical view of determination of activity.

Fiscalism is a term sometimes used to refer the economic theory that the government should rely on fiscal policy as the main instrument of macroeconomic policy. Fiscalism in this sense is contrasted with monetarism, which is associated with reliance on monetary policy. Fiscalists reject monetarism in a non-convertible floating rate system as inefficient if not also ineffective

Employers of last resort (ELR) are employers in an economy to whom workers go for jobs when no other jobs are available; the term is by analogy with "lender of last resort". The phrase is used in two senses:

Reserve army of labour is a concept in Karl Marx's critique of political economy. It refers to the unemployed and underemployed in capitalist society. It is synonymous with "industrial reserve army" or "relative surplus population", except that the unemployed can be defined as those actually looking for work and that the relative surplus population also includes people unable to work. The use of the word "army" refers to the workers being conscripted and regimented in the workplace in a hierarchy under the command or authority of the owners of capital.

Modern monetary theory or modern money theory (MMT) is a heterodox macroeconomic theory that describes currency as a public monopoly and unemployment as evidence that a currency monopolist is overly restricting the supply of the financial assets needed to pay taxes and satisfy savings desires. According to MMT, governments do not need to worry about accumulating debt since they can create new money by using fiscal policy in order to pay interest. MMT argues that the primary risk once the economy reaches full employment is inflation, which acts as the only constraint on spending. MMT also argues that inflation can be addressed by increasing taxes on everyone to reduce the spending capacity of the private sector.

Active labour market policies (ALMPs) are government programmes that intervene in the labour market to help the unemployed find work, but also for the underemployed and employees looking for better jobs. In contrast, passive labour market policies involve expenditures on unemployment benefits and early retirement. Historically, labour market policies have developed in response to both market failures and socially/politically unacceptable outcomes within the labor market. Labour market issues include, for instance, the imbalance between labour supply and demand, inadequate income support, shortages of skilled workers, or discrimination against disadvantaged workers.

The White Paper Full Employment in Australia, published in 1945, was the defining document of the official economic policy in Australia until the 1970s. For the first time, the Australian government accepted an obligation to guarantee full employment and to intervene as necessary to implement that guarantee. The preparation of the paper was ordered by The Australian Labor Party Prime Minister John Curtin and his Employment Minister John Dedman and undertaken by a group of economists headed by H.C. Coombs.

Non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) is a theoretical level of unemployment below which inflation would be expected to rise. It was first introduced as NIRU by Franco Modigliani and Lucas Papademos in 1975, as an improvement over the "natural rate of unemployment" concept, which was proposed earlier by Milton Friedman.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Unemployment in the United States</span> Explanation of unemployment in the United States, presently and historically

Unemployment in the United States discusses the causes and measures of U.S. unemployment and strategies for reducing it. Job creation and unemployment are affected by factors such as economic conditions, global competition, education, automation, and demographics. These factors can affect the number of workers, the duration of unemployment, and wage levels.

Full Employment Abandoned: Shifting Sands and Policy Failures is a book on macroeconomic issues written by economists Bill Mitchell and Joan Muysken and first published in 2008.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Department of Labour (Australia)</span> Australian government department, 1972–1974

The Department of Labour was an Australian government department that existed between December 1972 and June 1974. This department was created and operated under the Whitlam government, with Clyde Cameron appointed as minister. The Department of Labour was a catalyst for the increase in the national minimum wage and pushed for the equalising of pay rates between men and women. During this period, Cameron pushed for paid maternity and annual leave. They also worked to reduce the number of industrial disputes for the Conciliation and Arbitration Commission. Many attribute the department's employment of wage indexation policies as a contributing factor to the 1975 economic recession.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Rania Antonopoulou</span> Greek economist and politician

Ourania "Rania" Antonopoulou a.k.a. Rania Antonopoulos is a Greek heterodox economist and Syriza politician. After the January 2015 election, MP Alexis Tsipras named her as the Greek Alternate Minister for Combating Unemployment in his cabinet tasked to implement a job guarantee policy based on her previous work experience and a specific study for Greece with other colleagues at the Levy Economics Institute. She remains a Syriza member. On the 5th of September 2018 she was appointed by the Greek Government as the Permanent Representative of Greece (Ambassador) to the OECD in Paris, France, entrusting her to represent the country despite the severe media attack she had been subjected to a few months earlier. Between February and August 2015, she also was a member of the Hellenic Parliament.

Unemployment in Hungary measured by the Hungarian Central Statistical Office shows the rate of unemployed individuals out of the labor force. The European Union's own statistical office, Eurostat also makes reports and predictions about the Hungarian job market and the unemployment rate in the country. The KSH's most recent unemployment data shows the unemployment rate for men 15–74 to be 3.3% and 4.1% for women.

In economics, non-accelerating inflation buffer employment ratio (NAIBER) refers to a systemic proposal for an in-built inflation control mechanism devised by economists Bill Mitchell and Warren Mosler, and advocated by Modern Money Theory as replacement for NAIRU. The concept of NAIBER is related to the idea of a job guarantee aimed to create full employment and price stability, by having the state promise to hire unemployed workers as an employer of last resort (ELR).

References

Further reading