Stephen Marglin

Last updated
Stephen A. Marglin
Born
California, United States
NationalityAmerican
Academic career
Institution Harvard
Alma materHarvard
Influences Karl Marx
John Maynard Keynes
Friedrich Hayek
Website https://scholar.harvard.edu/marglin

Stephen Alan Marglin is an American economist. He is the Walter S. Barker Professor of Economics at Harvard University, a fellow of the Econometric Society, and a founding member of the World Economics Association. [1]

Contents

Background

Marglin grew up in a moderately left-wing [2] Jewish family and attended Hollywood High School in Los Angeles [3] before moving to Harvard for his university studies in 1955. [4] He earned membership into Phi Beta Kappa, [2] and graduated summa cum laude (1959). [4] He was subsequently honored with a Harvard Junior Fellowship (1960–63), [5] and was later a Guggenheim fellow. [6]

Career

Marglin started out as a neoclassical economist, and was regarded, even while still an undergraduate, as the star of Harvard's economics department. [4] Arthur Maass, the Frank G. Thomson Professor of Government, Emeritus, at Harvard, [7] once remembered how Marglin, "when he was just a senior, wrote two of the best chapters in a book published by a team of graduate students and professors." [4] His exceptional early contributions to neoclassical theory [4] led to his becoming a tenured professor at Harvard in 1968, one of the youngest in the history of the university. [2]

Since the late 1960s, Marglin, following the lead of people such as Samuel Bowles, Herbert Gintis, and Arthur MacEwan, rejected orthodox economics and began expressing dissenting views in his academic work. [3] [4] [8] According to his former teacher, James Duesenberry, Marglin's career subsequently "suffered" because of his department and the university authorities in general taking a negative view of this change. [4] Economist Brad DeLong noted in a similar vein that the wider community of "Ivy League economists" took a rather dim view of Marglin's post-tenure "deviancy", something that has "not been pretty" to observe. [9]

Marglin has published in areas including the foundations of cost–benefit analysis, the workings of the labor-surplus economy, the organization of production, the relationship between the growth of income and its distribution, and the process of macroeconomic adjustment. [10]

He wrote the widely discussed [11] 1971-1974 paper "What do bosses do?", first published in France by his friend André Gorz, [12] followed by a series of others, [13] in which he argued that

the most important innovation of the Industrial Revolution was not technological, but organizational: the linear hierarchy (master–journeyman–apprentice) typical of crafts in the premodern era was replaced by the pyramidal hierarchy (boss–foreman–worker) of the modern, capitalist enterprise. How did this happen? What hold did the capitalist have on the worker that permitted this new form of organization to thrive and eventually to dominate?

The conventional answer is superior efficiency, a better mousetrap. If the capitalist enterprise comes into existence because of its superior efficiency, then the boss can entice the worker by offering him more money than the worker could earn on his own. [...] By contrast, the answer in "Bosses" is that the capitalist organization of work came into existence not because of superior efficiency but in consequence of the rent-seeking activities of the capitalist. [14]

Elsewhere, Marglin argued: "The obstacles to liberating the workplace lie not only in the dominance of classes in whose interest it is to perpetuate the authoritarian workplace, but also in the dominance of the knowledge system that legitimizes the authority of the boss. In this perspective, to liberate the workplace it is hardly sufficient to overthrow capitalism. The commissar turned out to be an even more formidable obstacle to workers' control than the capitalist." [15]

His highly cited and influential work "What do bosses do?" came as part of Marglin's disagreement with fellow Harvard professor David Landes over aspects of the Industrial Revolution; [16] years later, Landes wrote "What do bosses really do?" in reply. [17]

Marglin is critical of those who explicitly set out to deny the normative aspect of economics—something that he believes "really started with the British economist Lionel Robbins" [18] —arguing that opposing ideology is "a methodological error [...] What is ideology, after all, but the unproved assumptions, beliefs, and values that must underlie any intellectual inquiry, or for that matter, any form of contemplation or action? [...] As long as we deny the ideological component of our theories, we shall never transcend it." [19]

Marglin's 21st-century research has included analysis of the foundational assumptions of economics, concentrating on whether they represent universal human values or merely "reflect western culture and history." The Dismal Science (2008) looks at, amongst other things, the manner in which community is steadily gutted as human relations are replaced with market transactions. [20]

Marglin's most recent book is Raising Keynes: A Twenty-First-Century General Theory (2021). The book rescues the central insight of John Maynard Keynes' great work, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, that capitalism left to its own devices has no mechanism for guaranteeing full employment, and that consequently the government must provide a visible hand to work in tandem with the invisible hand of the market. "Rescues" because the mainstream view today is unchanged from the 1930s when Keynes wrote the General Theory: namely, that the problem is imperfections that impede the working of markets, warts on the body of capitalism rather than the body itself. Over the years the radical, heterodox Keynes was transformed by the mainstream into a super-sophisticated theorist of warts, specifically, a theorist of how capitalism can get stuck if wages are insufficiently flexible. The wart theory allowed economists to accept some of Keynes's policy insights, in particular the limitations of monetary policy and the necessity for countercyclical fiscal policy in extremis, while rejecting the idea that there is any more serious flaw than the warts themselves. And, supremely important, restricting the role of government to alleviating the warts is a strictly short-term, limited endeavor.

Raising Keynes shows how and why the orthodox reading of Keynes is wrong and substantiates Keynes's insight that, even if you strip capitalism of its warts, you still have a system that has no mechanism for reliably producing enough jobs. The state is needed not on an occasional, intermittent basis, but continually, in the long run as well as in emergencies.

In line with his view of economics teaching as "extremely narrow and restrictive," for some years Marglin offered an alternative to Greg Mankiw's course in introductory economics. [21] [22] [23] [24]

Partial publications list

Books

  • Raising Keynes: A Twenty-First-Century General Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. 2021.
  • The Dismal Science: How Thinking Like an Economist Undermines Community. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. 2008.
  • Decolonizing Knowledge: From Development to Dialogue. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 1996. (Co-editor with Frédérique Apffel-Marglin).
  • Dominating Knowledge: Development, Culture, and Resistance. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 1990b. (Co-editor with Apffel-Marglin).
  • The Golden Age of Capitalism: Reinterpreting the Postwar Experience. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 1990a. (Co-editor with Juliet Schor).
  • Growth, Distribution, and Prices . Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. 1984a. ISBN   9780674364158.
  • Value and Price in the Labour-Surplus Economy . Oxford: Clarendon Press. 1976. ISBN   978-0-19-828194-8.

Articles, papers, and chapters

Political and other views

A liberal in his earlier years, since the mid-1960s Marglin has been a Leftist, [3] and has even been labelled a Marxist, [2] though he describes himself as Marxist "only in the sense of not being anti-Marx." [4] He identifies as a cultural Jew and a secular humanist, and maintains his practice of Judaism for the sense of community it provides. [25]

Marglin was arrested in 1972 while demonstrating against the Vietnam War. [2] He supported the Occupy movement, [26] and contributed to a teach-in at Occupy Harvard. [27]

Personal life

Marglin is married to Christine Marglin (née Benvenuto). She is the author of Shiksa: The Gentile Woman in the Jewish World and Sex Changes: A Memoir of Marriage, Gender, and Moving On. Marglin's previous two marriages, to Carol Kurson (died 2020) and Frederique Apffel-Marglin, ended in divorce. From youngest to oldest, his children (including stepchildren) are Nasia Benvenuto-Ladin, 2021 high-school grad; Yael Benvenuto-Ladin, rising college senior; Gabriel Benvenuto-Ladin, working in theater production; Jessica Marglin, associate professor of Jewish Studies and religion, law, and history; Elizabeth Marglin, freelance writer; David Marglin, attorney; and Marc Weisskopf, professor of environmental epidemiology and physiology.

Notes

  1. "Marglin's Curriculum Vitae" (PDF). Retrieved 30 August 2015.
  2. 1 2 3 4 5 Groll, Elias J. (1 June 2009). "Radical Harvard economics professor defies 'established order' of the 1950s". The Harvard Crimson . Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  3. 1 2 3 Lee, Tom (12 May 1975). "The Radicalization of Stephen Marglin". The Harvard Crimson . Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  4. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Drucker, Linda S.; Rabinovitz, Jonathan D. (12 March 1980). "Stephen Marglin". The Harvard Crimson . Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  5. "Current and Former Junior Fellows: Listing by Term". Society of Fellows, Harvard University. Archived from the original on 2013-01-16. Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  6. "Stephen A. Marglin: 1975 Fellow, Economics". gf.org. Archived from the original on 4 January 2013. Retrieved 26 October 2012.
  7. Mansfield, Harvey; Cooper, Joseph; Rudolph, Susanne; Beer, Samuel (14 June 2007). "Arthur Maass: Faculty of Arts and Sciences—Memorial Minute". Harvard Gazette . Retrieved 9 November 2012.
    "Arthur Maass: 1954 Fellow, Political Science". John Simon Guggenheim Memorial Foundation. Archived from the original on 3 January 2013. Retrieved 9 November 2012.
  8. "MacEwan Accepts One-Year Contract In Economics Dept". The Harvard Crimson . 14 March 1974. Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  9. DeLong, Brad (20 June 2008). "Ask the Gemeinschaft: E. Roy Weintraub and Stephen Marglin Edition". Grasping Reality. Retrieved 30 August 2015.
  10. "Stephen Marglin: Biography". harvard.edu . Retrieved 18 August 2012.
  11. Willy Gianinazzi, André Gorz. Une vie, Paris, La Découverte, 2016, p. 160; Bryer 2002 , p. 17.
  12. Marglin, 1973, Marglin 1974 .
  13. Marglin 1975 ; Marglin 1979 ; Marglin 1984b ; Chapter 7 in Marglin 1990b; Marglin 1991 .
  14. Marglin 2008, pp.  153–4.
  15. Marglin, Stephen. "Why Is So Little Left Of The Left?". Z Papers (October–December 1992). Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  16. Tunzelmann 2001 , p.  10 . "[The] debate, in regard to the First Industrial Revolution, [...] between Stephen Marglin and David Landes [was] over which was the more potent symbol of that revolution—the factory, interpreted as a governance mechanism, or the machinery? Landes' original survey ( Landes 1969 ), drawn on his background in entrepreneurial history, had suggested a combination of technological and cultural factors explaining why Britain came first and why it later dropped behind. Marglin (1974), from a background in radical economics, instead took a strong labour-process view, in a paper entitled "What Do Bosses Do?" For him it was the control entrusted to the 'bosses' through the factory system that crucially defined that Industrial Revolution. Landes (1986) replied with a restatement more strongly favouring the technology as the sine qua non of early industrialisation. Both sides could accept some interdependence between governance changes and technological changes, but remained committed to their respective views about priority".
  17. Landes 1986.
  18. Interview with Marglin (2008). "Why Thinking Like an Economist Can Be Harmful to the Community". Challenge . 51 (2): 13–26. doi:10.2753/0577-5132510203. S2CID   154754425.
  19. Marglin 2002 , p. 48.
  20. The Dismal Science, from the book's page on the Harvard University Press website.
  21. White, Lawrence H. (10 March 2003). "Letter: Marglin Is Biased, Too". The Harvard Crimson . Retrieved 15 November 2012.
  22. Shea, Christopher (14 December 2011). "The Econ-Alternative at Harvard". WSJ.com . Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  23. Concerned students of Economics 10 (2 November 2011). "An Open Letter to Greg Mankiw". harvardpolitics.com . Retrieved 13 November 2013.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)
  24. "Stephen Marglin: Occupy Harvard, Economics and Ideology". The Institute Blog. Institute for New Economic Thinking. Archived from the original on 10 January 2012. Retrieved 10 December 2011.
  25. Fiske, Courtney A. (7 November 2007). "Dershowitz, Gross and Marglin reflect on being 'Jewish in 2007'". The Harvard Crimson . Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  26. "Economists Statement in Support of Occupy Wall Street". econ4.org. Retrieved 25 July 2013.
  27. "Stephen Marglin: Interviews and Lectures: Occupy Harvard Teach-In on Heterodox Economics". harvard.edu. 7 December 2011. Archived from the original on 22 May 2013. Retrieved 29 October 2012. His Occupy lecture is available on YouTube.

Bibliography

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Capitalism</span> Economic system based on private ownership

Capitalism is an economic system based on the private ownership of the means of production and their operation for profit. The defining characteristics of capitalism include capital accumulation, competitive markets, price systems, private property, recognition of property rights, self-interest, economic freedom, meritocracy, work ethic, consumer sovereignty, economic efficiency, limited role of government, profit motive, a financial infrastructure of money and investment that makes possible credit and debt, entrepreneurship, commodification, voluntary exchange, wage labor, production of commodities and services, and a strong emphasis on innovation and economic growth. In a market economy, decision-making and investments are determined by owners of wealth, property, or ability to maneuver capital or production ability in capital and financial markets—whereas prices and the distribution of goods and services are mainly determined by competition in goods and services markets.

In economics, a free market is an economic system in which the prices of goods and services are determined by supply and demand expressed by sellers and buyers. Such markets, as modeled, operate without the intervention of government or any other external authority. Proponents of the free market as a normative ideal contrast it with a regulated market, in which a government intervenes in supply and demand by means of various methods such as taxes or regulations. In an idealized free market economy, prices for goods and services are set solely by the bids and offers of the participants.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Joseph Schumpeter</span> Austrian political economist (1883–1950)

Joseph Alois Schumpeter was an Austrian political economist. He served briefly as Finance Minister of Austria in 1919. In 1932, he emigrated to the United States to become a professor at Harvard University, where he remained until the end of his career, and in 1939 obtained American citizenship.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Economic history</span>

Economic history is the study of history using methodological tools from economics or with a special attention to economic phenomena. Research is conducted using a combination of historical methods, statistical methods and the application of economic theory to historical situations and institutions. The field can encompass a wide variety of topics, including equality, finance, technology, labour, and business. It emphasizes historicizing the economy itself, analyzing it as a dynamic entity and attempting to provide insights into the way it is structured and conceived.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Market economy</span> Type of economic system

A market economy is an economic system in which the decisions regarding investment, production, and distribution to the consumers are guided by the price signals created by the forces of supply and demand. The major characteristic of a market economy is the existence of factor markets that play a dominant role in the allocation of capital and the factors of production.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Post-Keynesian economics</span> School of economic thought

Post-Keynesian economics is a school of economic thought with its origins in The General Theory of John Maynard Keynes, with subsequent development influenced to a large degree by Michał Kalecki, Joan Robinson, Nicholas Kaldor, Sidney Weintraub, Paul Davidson, Piero Sraffa and Jan Kregel. Historian Robert Skidelsky argues that the post-Keynesian school has remained closest to the spirit of Keynes' original work. It is a heterodox approach to economics.

Laissez-faire is a type of economic system in which transactions between private groups of people are free from any form of economic interventionism. As a system of thought, laissez-faire rests on the following axioms: "the individual is the basic unit in society, i.e., the standard of measurement in social calculus; the individual has a natural right to freedom; and the physical order of nature is a harmonious and self-regulating system." The original phrase was laissez faire, laissez passer, with the second part meaning "let (things) pass". It is generally attributed to Vincent de Gournay.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Paul Sweezy</span> American Marxist economist (1910–2004)

Paul Marlor Sweezy was a Marxist economist, political activist, publisher, and founding editor of the long-running magazine Monthly Review. He is best remembered for his contributions to economic theory as one of the leading Marxian economists of the second half of the 20th century.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Deirdre McCloskey</span> American economist (born 1942)

Deirdre Nansen McCloskey is an American economist and academic. Since 2023 she has been a Distinguished Scholar and holder of the Isaiah Berlin Chair in Liberal Thought at the Cato Institute in Washington, D.C. From 2000 to 2015, she taught at the University of Illinois at Chicago, where she was Distinguished Professor of Economics History, and Professor of English and Communication. During those years, she taught economic history at the University of Gothenburg, economics at the University of the Free State, and philosophy at Erasmus University Rotterdam.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Hyman Minsky</span> American economist

Hyman Philip Minsky was an American economist, a professor of economics at Washington University in St. Louis, and a distinguished scholar at the Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. His research attempted to provide an understanding and explanation of the characteristics of financial crises, which he attributed to swings in a potentially fragile financial system. Minsky is sometimes described as a post-Keynesian economist because, in the Keynesian tradition, he supported some government intervention in financial markets, opposed some of the financial deregulation of the 1980s, stressed the importance of the Federal Reserve as a lender of last resort and argued against the over-accumulation of private debt in the financial markets.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Criticism of Marxism</span>

Criticism of Marxism has come from various political ideologies, campaigns and academic disciplines. This includes general intellectual criticism about dogmatism, a lack of internal consistency, criticism related to materialism, arguments that Marxism is a type of historical determinism or that it necessitates a suppression of individual rights, issues with the implementation of communism and economic issues such as the distortion or absence of price signals and reduced incentives. In addition, empirical and epistemological problems are frequently identified.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Richard D. Wolff</span> American Marxian economist (born 1942)

Richard David Wolff is an American Marxian economist known for his work on economic methodology and class analysis. He is a professor emeritus of economics at the University of Massachusetts Amherst and a visiting professor in the graduate program in international affairs of the New School. Wolff has also taught economics at Yale University, City University of New York, University of Utah, University of Paris I (Sorbonne), and The Brecht Forum in New York City.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Herbert Gintis</span> American economist (1940–2023)

Herbert Gintis was an American economist, behavioral scientist, and educator known for his theoretical contributions to sociobiology, especially altruism, cooperation, epistemic game theory, gene-culture coevolution, efficiency wages, strong reciprocity, and human capital theory. Throughout his career, he worked extensively with economist Samuel Bowles. Their landmark book, Schooling in Capitalist America, had multiple editions in five languages since it was first published in 1976. Their book, A Cooperative Species: Human Reciprocity and its Evolution was published by Princeton University Press in 2011.

Richard M. Goodwin was an American mathematician and economist.

Frédérique Apffel-Marglin is a professor emerita of anthropology. She taught at Smith College in Massachusetts.

Throughout modern history, a variety of perspectives on capitalism have evolved based on different schools of thought.

<i>An Essay on Marxian Economics</i> 1942 book by Joan Robinson

An Essay on Marxian Economics is an analytical essay written by in 1942 by economist Joan Robinson. The essay deals with the orthodox teachings of capital accumulation, the essential demand crisis and real wages by comparing it to Karl Marx's Das Kapital. It is a wide-ranging critique on Marx and Orthodox economics while also arguing for a long-term economic view that builds on the problems that Marx first identified in the exploitative nature of capitalism.

William Henry Locke Anderson was an American economist and professor at the University of Michigan. During the first half of his career, he did research on macroeconomics; during the second half, he focused on Marxist economics and became an editor of Monthly Review, a Marxist journal.

Marxian economics, or the Marxian school of economics, is a heterodox school of political economic thought. Its foundations can be traced back to Karl Marx's critique of political economy. However, unlike critics of political economy, Marxian economists tend to accept the concept of the economy prima facie. Marxian economics comprises several different theories and includes multiple schools of thought, which are sometimes opposed to each other; in many cases Marxian analysis is used to complement, or to supplement, other economic approaches. Because one does not necessarily have to be politically Marxist to be economically Marxian, the two adjectives coexist in usage, rather than being synonymous: They share a semantic field, while also allowing both connotative and denotative differences. An example of this can be found in the works of Soviet economists like Lev Gatovsky, who sought to apply Marxist economic theory to the objectives, needs, and political conditions of the socialist construction in the Soviet Union, contributing to the development of Soviet Political Economy.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Comparison of Marxian and Keynesian economics</span>

Marxism and Keynesianism is a method of understanding and comparing the works of influential economists John Maynard Keynes and Karl Marx. Both men's works has fostered respective schools of economic thought that have had significant influence in various academic circles as well as in influencing government policy of various states. Keynes' work found popularity in developed liberal economies following the Great Depression and World War II, most notably Franklin D. Roosevelt's New Deal in the United States in which strong industrial production was backed by strong unions and government support. Marx's work, with varying degrees of faithfulness, led the way to a number of socialist states, notably the Soviet Union and the People's Republic of China. The immense influence of both Marxian and Keynesian schools has led to numerous comparisons of the work of both economists along with synthesis of both schools.