Kinetic exchange models of markets

Last updated

Kinetic exchange models are multi-agent dynamic models inspired by the statistical physics of energy distribution, which try to explain the robust and universal features of income/wealth distributions.

Contents

Understanding the distributions of income and wealth in an economy has been a classic problem in economics for more than a hundred years. Today it is one of the main branches of econophysics.

Data and basic tools

In 1897, Vilfredo Pareto first found a universal feature in the distribution of wealth. After that, with some notable exceptions, this field had been dormant for many decades, although accurate data had been accumulated over this period. Considerable investigations with the real data during the last fifteen years (1995–2010) revealed [1] that the tail (typically 5 to 10 percent of agents in any country) of the income/wealth distribution indeed follows a power law. However, the majority of the population (i.e., the low-income population) follows a different distribution which is debated to be either Gibbs or log-normal.

Basic tools used in this type of modelling are probabilistic and statistical methods mostly taken from the kinetic theory of statistical physics. Monte Carlo simulations often come handy in solving these models.

Overview of the models

Since the distributions of income/wealth are the results of the interaction among many heterogeneous agents, there is an analogy with statistical mechanics, where many particles interact. This similarity was noted by Meghnad Saha and B. N. Srivastava in 1931 [2] and thirty years later by Benoit Mandelbrot. [3] In 1986, an elementary version of the stochastic exchange model was first proposed by J. Angle. [4]

In the context of kinetic theory of gases, such an exchange model was first investigated by A. Dragulescu and V. Yakovenko. [5] [6] The main modelling effort has been put to introduce the concepts of savings, [7] [8] and taxation [9] in the setting of an ideal gas-like system. Basically, it assumes that in the short-run, an economy remains conserved in terms of income/wealth; therefore law of conservation for income/wealth can be applied. Millions of such conservative transactions lead to a steady state distribution of money (gamma function-like in the Chakraborti-Chakrabarti model with uniform savings, [7] and a gamma-like bulk distribution ending with a Pareto tail [10] in the Chatterjee-Chakrabarti-Manna model with distributed savings [8] ) and the distribution converges to it. The distributions derived thus have close resemblance with those found in empirical cases of income/wealth distributions.

Though this theory had been originally derived from the entropy maximization principle of statistical mechanics, it had been shown by A. S. Chakrabarti and B. K. Chakrabarti [11] that the same could be derived from the utility maximization principle as well, following a standard exchange-model with Cobb-Douglas utility function. Recently it has been shown [12] that an extension of the Cobb-Douglas utility function (in the above-mentioned Chakrabarti-Chakrabarti formulation) by adding a production savings factor leads to the desired feature of growth of the economy in conformity with some earlier phenomenologically established growth laws in the economics literature. The exact distributions produced by this class of kinetic models are known only in certain limits and extensive investigations have been made on the mathematical structures of this class of models. [13] [14] The general forms have not been derived so far.

Criticisms

This class of models has attracted criticisms from many dimensions. [15] It has been debated for long whether the distributions derived from these models are representing the income distributions or wealth distributions. The law of conservation for income/wealth has also been a subject of criticism.

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Power law</span> Functional relationship between two quantities

In statistics, a power law is a functional relationship between two quantities, where a relative change in one quantity results in a relative change in the other quantity proportional to a power of the change, independent of the initial size of those quantities: one quantity varies as a power of another. For instance, considering the area of a square in terms of the length of its side, if the length is doubled, the area is multiplied by a factor of four. The rate of change exhibited in these relationships is said to be multiplicative.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Pareto principle</span> Statistical principle about ratio of effects to causes

The Pareto principle states that for many outcomes, roughly 80% of consequences come from 20% of causes. Other names for this principle are the 80/20 rule, the law of the vital few or the principle of factor sparsity.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Scale-free network</span> Network whose degree distribution follows a power law

A scale-free network is a network whose degree distribution follows a power law, at least asymptotically. That is, the fraction P(k) of nodes in the network having k connections to other nodes goes for large values of k as

Econophysics is a non-orthodox interdisciplinary research field, applying theories and methods originally developed by physicists in order to solve problems in economics, usually those including uncertainty or stochastic processes and nonlinear dynamics. Some of its application to the study of financial markets has also been termed statistical finance referring to its roots in statistical physics. Econophysics is closely related to social physics.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Self-organized criticality</span> Concept in physics

Self-organized criticality (SOC) is a property of dynamical systems that have a critical point as an attractor. Their macroscopic behavior thus displays the spatial or temporal scale-invariance characteristic of the critical point of a phase transition, but without the need to tune control parameters to a precise value, because the system, effectively, tunes itself as it evolves towards criticality.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">El Farol Bar problem</span>

The El Farol bar problem is a problem in game theory. Every Thursday night, a fixed population want to go have fun at the El Farol Bar, unless it's too crowded.

In physics, the Tsallis entropy is a generalization of the standard Boltzmann–Gibbs entropy. It is proportional to the expectation of the q-logarithm of a distribution.

Quantum annealing (QA) is an optimization process for finding the global minimum of a given objective function over a given set of candidate solutions, by a process using quantum fluctuations. Quantum annealing is used mainly for problems where the search space is discrete with many local minima; such as finding the ground state of a spin glass or the traveling salesman problem. The term "quantum annealing" was first proposed in 1988 by B. Apolloni, N. Cesa Bianchi and D. De Falco as a quantum-inspired classical algorithm. It was formulated in its present form by T. Kadowaki and H. Nishimori in 1998 though an imaginary-time variant without quantum coherence had been discussed by A. B. Finnila, M. A. Gomez, C. Sebenik and J. D. Doll in 1994.

Statistical finance, is the application of econophysics to financial markets. Instead of the normative roots of finance, it uses a positivist framework. It includes exemplars from statistical physics with an emphasis on emergent or collective properties of financial markets. Empirically observed stylized facts are the starting point for this approach to understanding financial markets.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Preferential attachment</span> Stochastic process formalizing cumulative advantage

A preferential attachment process is any of a class of processes in which some quantity, typically some form of wealth or credit, is distributed among a number of individuals or objects according to how much they already have, so that those who are already wealthy receive more than those who are not. "Preferential attachment" is only the most recent of many names that have been given to such processes. They are also referred to under the names Yule process, cumulative advantage, the rich get richer, and the Matthew effect. They are also related to Gibrat's law. The principal reason for scientific interest in preferential attachment is that it can, under suitable circumstances, generate power law distributions. If preferential attachment is non-linear, measured distributions may deviate from a power law. These mechanisms may generate distributions which are approximately power law over transient periods.

Superstatistics is a branch of statistical mechanics or statistical physics devoted to the study of non-linear and non-equilibrium systems. It is characterized by using the superposition of multiple differing statistical models to achieve the desired non-linearity. In terms of ordinary statistical ideas, this is equivalent to compounding the distributions of random variables and it may be considered a simple case of a doubly stochastic model.

Mark Newman is an English–American physicist and Anatol Rapoport Distinguished University Professor of Physics at the University of Michigan, as well as an external faculty member of the Santa Fe Institute. He is known for his fundamental contributions to the fields of complex networks and complex systems, for which he was awarded the 2014 Lagrange Prize.

Human dynamics refer to a branch of complex systems research in statistical physics such as the movement of crowds and queues and other systems of complex human interactions including statistical modelling of human networks, including interactions over communications networks.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Active matter</span> Matter behavior at system scale

Active matter is matter composed of large numbers of active "agents", each of which consumes energy in order to move or to exert mechanical forces. Such systems are intrinsically out of thermal equilibrium. Unlike thermal systems relaxing towards equilibrium and systems with boundary conditions imposing steady currents, active matter systems break time reversal symmetry because energy is being continually dissipated by the individual constituents. Most examples of active matter are biological in origin and span all the scales of the living, from bacteria and self-organising bio-polymers such as microtubules and actin, to schools of fish and flocks of birds. However, a great deal of current experimental work is devoted to synthetic systems such as artificial self-propelled particles. Active matter is a relatively new material classification in soft matter: the most extensively studied model, the Vicsek model, dates from 1995.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Bikas Chakrabarti</span>

Bikas Kanta Chakrabarti (born 14 December 1952 in Kolkata is an Indian physicist. At present he is INSA Senior Scientist at the Saha Institute of Nuclear Physics & Visiting Professor at the Indian Statistical Institute, Kolkata, India.

<i>q</i>-exponential distribution

The q-exponential distribution is a probability distribution arising from the maximization of the Tsallis entropy under appropriate constraints, including constraining the domain to be positive. It is one example of a Tsallis distribution. The q-exponential is a generalization of the exponential distribution in the same way that Tsallis entropy is a generalization of standard Boltzmann–Gibbs entropy or Shannon entropy. The exponential distribution is recovered as

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Sznajd model</span>

The Sznajd model or United we stand, divided we fall (USDF) model is a sociophysics model introduced in 2000 to gain fundamental understanding about opinion dynamics. The Sznajd model implements a phenomenon called social validation and thus extends the Ising spin model. In simple words, the model states:

Physics of financial markets is a discipline that studies financial markets as physical systems. It seeks to understand the nature of financial processes and phenomena by employing the scientific method and avoiding beliefs, unverifiable assumptions and immeasurable notions, not uncommon to economic disciplines.

Social physics or sociophysics is a field of science which uses mathematical tools inspired by physics to understand the behavior of human crowds. In a modern commercial use, it can also refer to the analysis of social phenomena with big data.

Tiziana Di Matteo is a Professor of Econophysics at King's College London. She studies complex systems, such as financial markets, and complex materials. She serves on the council of the Complex Systems Society.

References

  1. Chatterjee, A.; Yarlagadda, S.; Chakrabarti, B.K. (2005). Econophysics of Wealth Distributions. Springer-Verlag (Milan).
  2. Saha, M.; Srivastava, B.N. (1931). A Treatise on Heat. Indian Press (Allahabad). p. 105. (the page is reproduced in Fig. 6 in Sitabhra Sinha, Bikas K Chakrabarti, Towards a physics of economics, Physics News 39(2) 33-46, April 2009)
  3. Mandelbrot, B.B. (1960). "The Pareto-Levy law and the distribution of income". International Economic Review. 1 (2): 79–106. doi:10.2307/2525289. JSTOR   2525289.
  4. Angle, J. (1986). "The surplus theory of social stratification and the size distribution of personal wealth". Social Forces. 65 (2): 293–326. doi:10.2307/2578675. JSTOR   2578675.
  5. Dragulescu, A.; Yakovenko, V. (2000). "The statistical mechanics of money". European Physical Journal B. 17 (4): 723–729. arXiv: cond-mat/0001432 . Bibcode:2000EPJB...17..723D. doi:10.1007/s100510070114. S2CID   16158313.
  6. Garibaldi, U.; Scalas, E.; Viarenga, P. (2007). "Statistical equilibrium in exchange games". European Physical Journal B. 60 (2): 241–246. Bibcode:2007EPJB...60..241G. doi:10.1140/epjb/e2007-00338-5. S2CID   119517302.
  7. 1 2 Chakraborti, A.; Chakrabarti, B.K. (2000). "Statistical mechanics of money: how savings propensity affects its distribution". European Physical Journal B. 17 (1): 167–170. arXiv: cond-mat/0004256 . Bibcode:2000EPJB...17..167C. doi:10.1007/s100510070173. S2CID   5138071.
  8. 1 2 Chatterjee, A.; Chakrabarti, B.K.; Manna, K.S.S. (2004). "Pareto law in a kinetic model of market with random saving propensity". Physica A. 335 (1–2): 155–163. arXiv: cond-mat/0301289 . Bibcode:2004PhyA..335..155C. doi:10.1016/j.physa.2003.11.014. S2CID   120904131.
  9. Guala, S. (2009). "Taxes in a simple wealth distribution model by inelastically scattering particles". Interdisciplinary Description of Complex Systems. 7 (1): 1–7. arXiv: 0807.4484 . Bibcode:2008arXiv0807.4484G.
  10. Chakraborti, A.; Patriarca, M. (2009). "Variational Principle for the Pareto Power Law". Physical Review Letters. 103 (22): 228701. arXiv: cond-mat/0605325 . Bibcode:2009PhRvL.103v8701C. doi:10.1103/PhysRevLett.103.228701. PMID   20366128. S2CID   909820.
  11. A. S. Chakrabarti; B. K. Chakrabarti (2009). "Microeconomics of the ideal gas like market models". Physica A. 388 (19): 4151–4158. arXiv: 0905.3972 . Bibcode:2009PhyA..388.4151C. doi:10.1016/j.physa.2009.06.038. S2CID   14908064.
  12. D. S. Quevedo; C. J. Quimbay (2020). "Non-conservative kinetic model of wealth exchange with saving of production". European Physical Journal B. 93 (10): 186. Bibcode:2020EPJB...93..186Q. doi:10.1140/epjb/e2020-10193-3. S2CID   224849350.
  13. During, B.; Matthes, D.; Toscani, G. (2008). "Kinetic equations modelling wealth distributions: a comparison of approaches" (PDF). Physical Review E. 78 (5): 056103. Bibcode:2008PhRvE..78e6103D. doi:10.1103/physreve.78.056103. PMID   19113186.
  14. Cordier, S.; Pareschi, L.; Toscani, G. (2005). "On a kinetic model for a simple market economy". Journal of Statistical Physics. 120 (1–2): 253–277. arXiv: math/0412429 . Bibcode:2005JSP...120..253C. doi:10.1007/s10955-005-5456-0. S2CID   10218909.
  15. Mauro Gallegati, Steve Keen, Thomas Lux and Paul Ormerod (2006). "Worrying Trends in Econophysics". Physica A. 371 (1): 1–6. Bibcode:2006PhyA..370....1G. doi:10.1016/j.physa.2006.04.029.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)

Further reading