Monetary reform

Last updated

Monetary reform is any movement or theory that proposes a system of supplying money and financing the economy that is different from the current system.

Contents

Monetary reformers may advocate any of the following, among other proposals:

Common targets for reform

Of all the aspects of monetary policy, certain topics reoccur as targets for reform:

Reserve requirements

Banks typically make loans to customers by crediting new demand deposits to the account of the customer. This practice, which is known as fractional reserve banking, permits the total supply of credit to exceed the liquid legal reserves of the bank. The amount of this excess is expressed as the "reserve ratio" and is limited by government regulators not to exceed a level which they deem adequate to ensure the ability of banks to meet their payment obligations. Under this system, which is currently practiced throughout the world, the money supply varies with the quantity of legal reserves and the amount of credit issuance by banks.[ citation needed ]

Several major historical examples of financial regulatory reform occurred in the 20th century relating to fractional-reserve banking, made in response to the Great Depression and the many bank runs following the crash of 1929. These reforms included the creation of deposit insurance (such as the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation) to mitigate against the danger of bank runs. [15] Countries have also implemented legal reserve requirements which impose minimum reserve requirements on banks. [16] Mainstream economists believe [15] that these monetary reforms have made sudden disruptions in the banking system less frequent.

Walter Block argued fractional reserve banking inherently artificially lowers real interest rates and leads to business cycles propagated by excessive capital investment and subsequent contraction. [17] [18] A small number of critics, such as Michael Rowbotham, equate the practice to counterfeiting, because banks are granted the legal right to issue new loans while charging interest on the money thus created. Rowbotham argues that this concentrates wealth in the banking sector with various pernicious effects. [12]


Money creation by the central bank

Wright Patman objected to governments paying interest for the use of money which the central bank creates "out of nothing". [19] [20] These critics claim that this system causes economic activity to depend on the actions of privately owned banks, which are motivated by self-interest rather than by any explicit social purpose or obligation.

International organizations and developing nations

Some monetary reformers[ who? ] criticise existing global financial institutions such as the World Bank, International Monetary Fund, Bank of International Settlements and their policies regarding money supply, banks and debt in developing nations, in that they appear to these writers to be "forcing" a regime of extortionate or unpayable debt on weak Third World governments that do not have the capacity to pay the interest on these loans without severely affecting the well-being or even the viability of the local population. The attempt by weak Third World governments to service external debt with the sale of valuable hard and soft commodities on world markets is seen by some to be destructive of local cultures, destroying local communities and their environment. [9] [12] [21]

Arguments for reform

Among the arguments for a transition to full-reserve banking or sovereign money are as follows:

Arguments against reform

Among the arguments for keeping the current system of money creation based on the credit theory of money or fractional reserve banking are as follows:

Alternative money systems

Government Control vs Central Bank independence

To regulate credit creation, some countries have created a currency board, or granted independence to their central bank. The Reserve Bank of New Zealand, the Reserve Bank of Australia, the Federal Reserve, and the Bank of England are examples where the central bank is explicitly given the power to set interest rates and conduct monetary policy independent of any direct political interference or direction from the central government. This may enable the setting of interest rates to be less susceptible to political interference and thereby assist in combating inflation (or debasement of the currency) by allowing the central bank to more effectively restrict the growth of M3. [39]

However, given that these policies do not address the more fundamental issues inherent in fractional reserve banking, many suggest that only more radical monetary reform such as government directly taking over central banks such as the China or Swiss models can promote positive economic or social change. Although central banks may appear to control inflation, through periodic bank rescues and other means, they may inadvertently be forced to increase the money supply (and thereby debase the currency) to save the banking system from bankruptcy or collapse during periodic bank runs, thereby inducing moral hazard in the financial system, making the system susceptible to economic bubbles. [40]

International monetary reform

Theorists such as Robert Mundell (and more radical thinkers such as James Robertson) see a role for global monetary reform as part of a system of global institutions alongside the United Nations to provide global ecological management and move towards world peace, with Robert Mundell in particular advocating the revived use of gold as a stabilising factor in the international financial system. [41] [42] Henry Liu of the Asia Times Online argues that monetary reform is an important part of a move towards post-autistic economics. [43]

While some mainstream economists[ who? ] favour monetary reforms to reduce inflation and currency risk and to increase efficiency in the allocation of financial capital, the idea of all-encompassing reform for green or peace objectives is typically espoused by those[ who? ] on the left-wing of the subject and those associated with the anti-globalization movement.[ citation needed ]

Social credit and the provision of debt-free money directly from government

Still other radical reform proposals emphasise monetary, tax and capital budget reform which empowers government to direct the economy toward sustainable solutions which are not possible if government spending can only be financed with more government debt from the private banking system. In particular, a number of monetary reformers, such as Michael Rowbotham, Stephen Zarlenga and Ellen Brown, support the restriction or banning of fractional-reserve banking (characterizing it as an illegitimate banking practice akin to embezzlement) and advocate the replacement of fractional-reserve banking with government-issued debt-free fiat currency issued directly from the Treasury rather than from the quasi-government Federal Reserve.[ citation needed ] Austrian commentator Gary North has sharply criticized these views in his writings. [44]

Alternatively, some monetary reformers such as those in the social credit movement, support the issuance of repayable interest-free credit from a government-owned central bank to fund infrastructure and sustainable social projects. This social credit movement flourished briefly in the early 20th century, but then became marginalized. In Canada, it was an important political movement that ruled Alberta through nine legislatures between 1935 and 1971, and also won many seats in Québec. It died out in the 1980s.

Both these groups (those who advocate the replacement of fractional-reserve banking with debt-free government-issued fiat, and those who support the issuance of repayable interest-free credit from a government-owned central bank) see the provision of interest-free money as a way of freeing the working populace from the bonds of "debt slavery" and facilitating a transformation of the economy away from environmentally damaging consumerism and towards sustainable economic policies and environment-friendly business practices.[ citation needed ]

Examples of government issued debt-free money

Some governments have experimented in the past with debt-free government-created money independent of a bank. The American Colonies used the "Colonial Scrip" system prior to the Revolution, much to the praise of Benjamin Franklin. The paper money of Pennsylvania maintained its value for forty years. [45]

Abraham Lincoln used interest-free money created by the government to help the Union win the American Civil War. Since greenbacks were not limited by gold, they fueled wartime prosperity among farmers and industrial growth. [46]

Local barter, local currency

Paul Hawken suggests wholesale reform of money and currency, based on ideas from green economics or Natural Capitalism, would be beneficial. [47] These include the ideas of soft currency, barter and the local service economy.

Local currency systems can operate within small communities, outside of government systems, and use specially printed notes or tokens called scrips for exchange. Barter takes this further by swapping goods and services directly; a compromise being the Local Exchange Trading Systems (LETS) scheme: a formalised system of community-based economics that records members' mutual credit in a central location.

Commodity money

Newt Gingrich called for a commission on returning to a hard currency or asset-backed currency, which is often argued to be an antidote to inflation. [48] This may involve using commodity money such as money backed by the gold, silver or both, commodities which supporters argue possess unique properties: [49] their extraordinary malleability, their strong resistance to forgery, their character as stable and impervious to decay, and their inherently limited supply. [50] [51]

Digital means are also now possible to allow trading in hard currencies such as gold, and some believe a new free market will emerge in money production and distribution, as the internet allows renewed decentralisation and competition in this area, eroding the central government's and bankers' old monopoly control of the means of exchange. [52] [53]

Free banking

Kevin Dowd favours permitting competing banks to issue private banknotes whilst also eliminating the central bank's role as lender of last resort. [54] He describes a gold standard as a "natural choice." [55]

See also

Related Research Articles

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Central bank</span> Government body that manages currency and monetary policy

A central bank, reserve bank, national bank, or monetary authority is an institution that manages the currency and monetary policy of a country or monetary union. In contrast to a commercial bank, a central bank possesses a monopoly on increasing the monetary base. Many central banks also have supervisory or regulatory powers to ensure the stability of commercial banks in their jurisdiction, to prevent bank runs, and in some cases also to enforce policies on financial consumer protection and against bank fraud, money laundering, or terrorism financing. Central banks play a crucial role in macroeconomic forecasting, which is essential for guiding monetary policy decisions, especially during times of economic turbulence.

In economics, deflation is a decrease in the general price level of goods and services. Deflation occurs when the inflation rate falls below 0%. Inflation reduces the value of currency over time, but deflation increases it. This allows more goods and services to be bought than before with the same amount of currency. Deflation is distinct from disinflation, a slowdown in the inflation rate; i.e., when inflation declines to a lower rate but is still positive.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Monetary policy of the United States</span> Political Policy

The monetary policy of the United States is the set of policies which the Federal Reserve follows to achieve its twin objectives of high employment and stable inflation.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Money supply</span> Total value of money available in an economy at a specific point in time

In macroeconomics, money supply refers to the total volume of money held by the public at a particular point in time. There are several ways to define "money", but standard measures usually include currency in circulation and demand deposits. Money supply data is recorded and published, usually by the national statistical agency or the central bank of the country. Empirical money supply measures are usually named M1, M2, M3, etc., according to how wide a definition of money they embrace. The precise definitions vary from country to country, in part depending on national financial institutional traditions.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Monetary policy</span> Policy of interest rates or money supply

Monetary policy is the policy adopted by the monetary authority of a nation to affect monetary and other financial conditions to accomplish broader objectives like high employment and price stability. Further purposes of a monetary policy may be to contribute to economic stability or to maintain predictable exchange rates with other currencies. Today most central banks in developed countries conduct their monetary policy within an inflation targeting framework, whereas the monetary policies of most developing countries' central banks target some kind of a fixed exchange rate system. A third monetary policy strategy, targeting the money supply, was widely followed during the 1980s, but has diminished in popularity since then, though it is still the official strategy in a number of emerging economies.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Fractional-reserve banking</span> System of banking

Fractional-reserve banking is the system of banking in all countries worldwide, under which banks that take deposits from the public keep only part of their deposit liabilities in liquid assets as a reserve, typically lending the remainder to borrowers. Bank reserves are held as cash in the bank or as balances in the bank's account at the central bank. Fractional-reserve banking differs from the hypothetical alternative model, full-reserve banking, in which banks would keep all depositor funds on hand as reserves.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Full-reserve banking</span> Offering of loans exclusively from time deposits

Full-reserve banking is a system of banking where banks do not lend demand deposits and instead only lend from time deposits. It differs from fractional-reserve banking, in which banks may lend funds on deposit, while fully reserved banks would be required to keep the full amount of each customer's demand deposits in cash, available for immediate withdrawal.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Monetary base</span> Measure of money supply

In economics, the monetary base in a country is the total amount of money created by the central bank. This includes:

In macroeconomics, an open market operation (OMO) is an activity by a central bank to exchange liquidity in its currency with a bank or a group of banks. The central bank can either transact government bonds and other financial assets in the open market or enter into a repurchase agreement or secured lending transaction with a commercial bank. The latter option, often preferred by central banks, involves them making fixed period deposits at commercial banks with the security of eligible assets as collateral.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Criticism of the Federal Reserve</span>

The Federal Reserve System, commonly known as "the Fed," has faced various criticisms since its establishment in 1913. Critics have questioned its effectiveness in managing inflation, regulating the banking system, and stabilizing the economy. Notable critics include Nobel laureate economist Milton Friedman and his fellow monetarist Anna Schwartz, who argued that the Fed's policies exacerbated the Great Depression. More recently, former Congressman Ron Paul has advocated for the abolition of the Fed and a return to a gold standard.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Money creation</span> Process by which the money supply of an economic region is increased

Money creation, or money issuance, is the process by which the money supply of a country, or an economic or monetary region, is increased. In most modern economies, money is created by both central banks and commercial banks. Money issued by central banks is a liability, typically called reserve deposits, and is only available for use by central bank account holders, which are generally large commercial banks and foreign central banks. Central banks can increase the quantity of reserve deposits directly, by making loans to account holders, purchasing assets from account holders, or by recording an asset, such as a deferred asset, and directly increasing liabilities. However, the majority of the money supply used by the public for conducting transactions is created by the commercial banking system in the form of commercial bank deposits. Bank loans issued by commercial banks expand the quantity of bank deposits.

The Austrian business cycle theory (ABCT) is an economic theory developed by the Austrian School of economics seeking to explain how business cycles occur. The theory views business cycles as the consequence of excessive growth in bank credit due to artificially low interest rates set by a central bank or fractional reserve banks. The Austrian business cycle theory originated in the work of Austrian School economists Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek. Hayek won the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1974 in part for his work on this theory.

Modern monetary theory or modern money theory (MMT) is a heterodox macroeconomic theory that describes currency as a public monopoly and unemployment as evidence that a currency monopolist is overly restricting the supply of the financial assets needed to pay taxes and satisfy savings desires. According to MMT, governments do not need to worry about accumulating debt since they can pay interest by printing money. MMT argues that the primary risk once the economy reaches full employment is inflation, which acts as the only constraint on spending. MMT also argues that inflation can be controlled by increasing taxes on everyone, to reduce the spending capacity of the private sector.

<span class="mw-page-title-main">Money</span> Object or record accepted as payment

Money is any item or verifiable record that is generally accepted as payment for goods and services and repayment of debts, such as taxes, in a particular country or socio-economic context. The primary functions which distinguish money are: medium of exchange, a unit of account, a store of value and sometimes, a standard of deferred payment.

Stephen A. Zarlenga was a researcher and author in the field of monetary theory, trader in stock and financial markets, and advocate of monetary reform.

Monetary policy in the United States is associated with interest rates and availability of credit.

The National Emergency Employment Defense Act, aka the NEED Act, was a monetary reform bill sponsored by Congressman Dennis Kucinich in 2011 in the United States House of Representatives.

The Swiss sovereign money initiative of June 2018, also known as Vollgeld, was a citizens' (popular) initiative in Switzerland intended to give the Swiss National Bank the sole authority to create money.

References

  1. Sound Money Archived 23 April 2009 at the Wayback Machine , Lew Rockwell
  2. Our Money Madness, Lew Rockwell
  3. The Case for a Gold Dollar, Murray Rothbard
  4. Glasner, David (25 August 1989). Free Banking and Monetary Reform. Cambridge University Press. ISBN   978-0-521-36175-0.
  5. What has Government done to our money?, Murray Rothbard
  6. The Case for a 100% Gold Dollar, Murray Rothbard
  7. Free Banking and the Free Bankers, Jörg Guido Hülsmann, Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics (Vol. 9, No. 1)
  8. "Sovereign Money". Archived from the original on 22 June 2019. Retrieved 13 September 2018.
  9. 1 2 Brown, Ellen H. (2007). Web of Debt. Baton Rouge, Louisiana: Third Millennium Press. ISBN   978-0-9795608-0-4 . Retrieved 15 December 2007.
  10. "Stephen A. Zarlenga, The Lost Science of Money AMI (2002)". Archived from the original on 28 August 2018. Retrieved 22 September 2008.
  11. Burkitt, Brian; Hutchinson, Frances (14 April 2006). The Political Economy of Social Credit and Guild Socialism. Routledge. ISBN   978-1-134-75582-0.
  12. 1 2 3 Rowbotham, Michael (1998). The Grip of Death: A Study of Modern Money, Debt Slavery and Destructive Economics. Jon Carpenter Publishing. ISBN   978-1-897766-40-8.
  13. Rahman, Abdurrahman Arum (21 October 2022). Reforming the International Monetary System (Report). Economics. doi:10.33774/coe-2022-1sl9n.
  14. Rahman, Abdurrahman Arum (13 December 2021). Initiating a True International Currency. Global Currency Initiative.
  15. 1 2 Mankiw, N. Gregory (2002). Macroeconomics (5th ed.). New York: Worth Publishers. p.  489. ISBN   0-7167-5237-9.
  16. Mankiw, N. Gregory (2002). Macroeconomics (5th ed.). New York: Worth Publishers. p.  487. ISBN   0-7167-5237-9.
  17. Block, Walter E.; Jankovic, Ivan (7 November 2022). Action and Choice: An Introduction to Economics. Springer Nature. p. 88. ISBN   978-981-19-3751-4.
  18. Murray Rothbard, The Mystery of Banking
  19. For an example of the public criticism of the current monetary system, see the speech of the Earl of Caithness in the British House of Lords on 5 March 1997 [ "The Economy - Wednesday 5 March 1997 - UK Parliament". Hansard. 5 March 1997. Retrieved 20 April 2021.]
  20. Jeffries, Donald (18 June 2019). Crimes and Cover-ups in American Politics: 1776-1963. Simon and Schuster. ISBN   978-1-5107-4148-5.
  21. As an example of groups critical of the World Bank, see the Whirled Bank website.
  22. 1 2 Werner, Richard A. (2016). "A Lost Century in Economics: Three Theories of Banking and the Conclusive Evidence". International Review of Financial Analysis. 46 (July): 361–79. doi: 10.1016/j.irfa.2015.08.014 . hdl: 2086/17270 .
  23. 1 2 3 4 Benes, Jaromir and Michael Kumhof (2012). "The Chicago Plan Revisited". IMF Working Paper, no. 202.
  24. 1 2 3 Zarlenga, Stephen (2002). The Lost Science of Money: The Mythology of Money – The Story of Power. American Monetary Institute. ISBN   1-930748-03-5.
  25. 1 2 3 4 5 Di Muzio, Tim; Robbins, Richard H. (2017). An Anthropology of Money: A Critical Introduction. Routledge. ISBN   978-1-138-64600-1.
  26. 1 2 3 Jackson, A. and Dyson, B. (2012). Modernising Money: Why our Monetary System is Broken and how it can be Fixed. London: Positive Money.
  27. Data sources: CIA. "The World Factbook". Central Intelligence Agency. Archived from the original on 1 June 2007. Retrieved 6 September 2018.. Desjardins, Jeff. "All of the World's Money and Markets in One Visualization". The Money Project. Retrieved 6 September 2018.
  28. 1 2 Brown, Ellen Hodgson (2012). Web of Debt: The Shocking Truth about Our Money System and How We Can Break Free. Third Millennium Press. ISBN   978-0983330851.
  29. 1 2 3 Eisenstein, Charles (2011). Sacred Economics: Money, Gift, and Society in the Age of Transition. North Atlantic Books. ISBN   978-1-58394-397-7.
  30. Bezemer, Dirk, and Michael Hudson (2016) "Finance Is Not the Economy: Reviving the Conceptual Distinction." Journal of Economic Issues , vol. 50 (3), pp. 745–768.
  31. 1 2 Korten, David C. (2010). Agenda for a New Economy: From Phantom Wealth to Real Wealth . Berrett-Koehler Publishers.
  32. Mellor, Mary (2010). The Future of Money: From Financial Crisis to Public Resource. London.
  33. 1 2 3 Thomas Jordan, "How money is created by the central bank and the banking system", Swiss National Bank, 16 January 2018
  34. 1 2 3 4 5 6 Schneider-Ammann, Johann N.; Thurnherr, Walter (2016). Botschaft zur Volksinitiative "Für krisensicheres Geld: Geldschöpfung allein durch die Nationalbank! (Vollgeld-Initiative)" (PDF). Schweizerischer Bundesrat.
  35. Birchler, Urs (1 November 2017). Vollgeld-Leitfaden (PDF). Institut für Banking und Finance, Universität Zürich. Retrieved 11 September 2018.
  36. Fontana, Giuseppe; Sawyer, Malcolm (2016). "Full Reserve Banking: More 'Cranks' than 'Brave Heretics'". Cambridge Journal of Economics. 40 (5): 1333–1350. doi:10.1093/cje/bew016. Alt URL See also Dyson, Ben; Hodgson, Graham; van Lerven, Frank (2016). "A Response to Critiques of 'Full Reserve Banking'". Cambridge Journal of Economics. 40 (5): 1351–1361. doi:10.1093/cje/bew036. and Fontana, Giuseppe; Hodgson, Graham (2017). "A Rejoinder to 'A Response to Critiques of "Full Reserve Banking"" (PDF). Cambridge Journal of Economics. 41 (6): 1741–1748. doi:10.1093/cje/bex058.
  37. Margeirsson, Olafur (2014). Financial Instability and Foreign Direct Investment (PDF). Doctoral dissertation, University of Exeter. pp. 251–264.
  38. Dittmer, Kristofer (2015). "100 percent reserve banking: A critical review of green perspectives". Ecological Economics. 109: 9–16. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2014.11.006.
  39. Manipulating the Interest Rate: a Recipe for Disaster, by Thorsten Polliet, December 2007
  40. Moral Hazard Effects of Central Bank Intervention Archived 24 March 2008 at the Wayback Machine , by Nouriel Roubini
  41. Uses and Abuses of Gresham's Law, by Robert Mundell
  42. The Role of Money, James Robertson
  43. The Road to Hyperinflation Archived 29 June 2012 at archive.today , Henry C.K. Liu
  44. Gertrude Coogan's Bluff, Greenback Populism as Conservative Economics
  45. Carey, Lewis James (1928). Franklin's Economic Views. Doubleday, Doran & Company.
  46. Arnold, James R.; Wiener, Roberta (19 July 2011). American Civil War: The Essential Reference Guide. Bloomsbury Publishing USA. ISBN   978-1-59884-906-6.
  47. Berghoff, Hartmut; Rome, Adam (2 May 2017). Green Capitalism?: Business and the Environment in the Twentieth Century. University of Pennsylvania Press. ISBN   978-0-8122-4901-9.
  48. Isidore, Chris. "Gingrich: U.S. should reconsider gold standard". CNNMoney.
  49. Westerfield, Ray Bert (1921). Elements of money, credit, and banking. Ronald Press Company.
  50. Theory of Money and Credit, Ludwig von Mises 1953
  51. Prada, Luis (21 August 2024). "Gold Bars Are Worth $1 Million for the First Time". VICE.
  52. Not Losing Your Head Archived 16 April 2009 at the Wayback Machine , Speech by Lew Rockwell
  53. Free Market Money System by F.A. Hayek
  54. "What You Should Know about Free Banking History". www.cato.org.
  55. "Easy Money and the Decapitalization of America". www.cato.org.

Further reading